Debt risk: the real problem is the dangerous use of semantics.
DeLong, J. Bradford
A government that does not tax sufficiently to cover its spending
will eventually run into all manner of debt-generated trouble. Its
nominal interest rates will rise as bondholders fear inflation. Its
business leaders will hunker down and try to move their wealth out of
the companies they run for fear of high future corporate taxes.
Moreover, real interest rates will rise, owing to policy
uncertainty, rendering many investments that are truly socially
productive unprofitable. And, when inflation takes hold, the division of
labor will shrink. What once was a large web held together by thin
monetary ties will fragment into very small networks solidified by thick
bonds of personal trust and social obligation. And a small division of
labor means low productivity.
All of this is bound to happen---eventually--if a government does
not tax sufficiently to cover its spending. But can it happen as long as
interest rates remain low, stock prices remain buoyant, and inflation
remains subdued? I and other economists--including Larry Summers, Laura
Tyson, Paul Krugman, and many more--believe that it cannot.
As long as stock prices are buoyant, business leaders are not
scared of future taxes or of policy uncertainty. As long as interest
rates remain low, there is no downward pressure on public investment.
And as long as inflation remains low, the extra debt that a government
issues is highly prized as a store of value, helps savers sleep more
easily at night, and provides a boost to the economy, because it assists
deleveraging and raises the velocity of spending.
Economists, in short, do not watch only quantities-the amount of
debt that a government has issued--but prices as well. And, because
people trade bonds for commodities, cash, and stocks, the prices of
government debt are the rate of inflation, the nominal interest rate,
and the level of the stock market. And all three of these prices are
flashing green, signaling that markets would prefer government debt to
grow at a faster pace than current forecasts indicate.
When Carmen Reinhart and Ken Rogoff wrote their influential study
"Growth in a Time of Debt," they asked the following question:
"Outsized deficits and epic bank bailouts may be useful in fighting
a downturn, but what is the long-run macroeconomic impact of higher
levels of government debt, especially against the backdrop of graying
populations and rising social insurance costs?" Reinhart and Rogoff
saw a public-debt "threshold of 90 percent of [annual] GDP,"
beyond which "growth rates fall.... in [both] advanced and emerging
economies."
The principal mistake that Reinhart and Rogoff made in their
analysis--indeed, the only significant mistake--was their use of the
word "threshold." That semantic choice, together with the
graph that they included, has led many astray. The Washington Post
editorial board, for example, recently condemned what it called the
"Don't worry, be happy" approach to the U.S. budget
deficit and government debt, on the grounds that there is a "90
percent mark that economists regard as a threat to sustainable economic
growth."
To be sure, the Washington Post editorial board has shown since the
start of the millennium that it requires little empirical support for
its claims. But the phrasing in "Growth in a Time of Debt"
also misled European Commissioner Olli Rehn and many others to argue
that "when [government] debt reaches 80-90 percent of GDP, it
starts to crowd out activity." Reinhart and Rogoff, it is widely
believed, showed that if the debt/GDP ratio is below 90 percent, an
economy is safe, and that only if the debt burden is above 90 percent is
growth placed in jeopardy.
Yet the threshold is not there. It is an artifact of Reinhart and
Rogoff's non-parametric method: throw the data into four bins, with
90 percent serving as the bottom of the top bin. In fact, there is a
gradual and smooth decline in growth rates as debt/GDP ratios
increase--80 percent looks only trivially better than 100 percent.
And, as Reinhart and Rogoff say, a correlation between high debt
and low growth is a sign that one should investigate whether debt is a
risk. Sometimes it is: a good deal of the relationship comes from
countries where interest rates are higher and the stock market is lower,
and where a higher debt/GDP ratio does indeed mean slower growth.
Still more of the relationship comes from countries where inflation
rates are higher when government debt is higher. But some of it comes
from countries where growth was already slow, and thus where high
debt/GDP ratios, as Larry Summers constantly says, result from the
denominator, not the numerator.
So, how much room is left in the relationship between debt and
economic performance for a country with low interest rates, low
inflation, buoyant stock prices, and healthy prior growth?
Not much, if any. In the United States, at least, we have learned
that there is little risk to accumulating more government debt until
interest and inflation rates begin to rise above normal levels, or the
stock market tanks. And there are large potential benefits to be gained
from solving America's real problems--low employment and slack
capacity--right now.
J. Bradford DeLong, a former deputy assistant secretary of the U.S.
Treasury, is Professor of Economics at the University of California at
Berkeley and a research associate at the National Bureau for Economic
Research.