Sympathy for Greenspan?
DeLong, J. Bradford
In the circles in which I travel, there is near-universal consensus
that America's monetary authorities made three serious mistakes
that contributed to and exacerbated the financial crisis. This consensus
is almost always qualified by declarations that the United States has
been well served by its Federal Reserve chairmen since at least Paul
Volcker's tenure, and that those of us who have not sat in that
seat know that we would have made worse mistakes. Nevertheless, the
consensus is that U.S. policymakers erred when:
* The decision was made to eschew principles-based regulation and
allow the shadow banking sector to grow with respect to its leverage and
its compensation schemes, in the belief that the government's
guarantee of the commercial banking system was enough to keep us out of
trouble;
* The Fed and the Treasury decided, once we were in trouble, to
nationalize AIG and pay its bills rather than to support its
counterparties, which allowed financiers to pretend that their
strategies were fundamentally sound;
* The Fed and the Treasury decided to let Lehman Brothers go into
uncontrolled bankruptcy in order to try to teach financiers that having
an ill-capitalized counterparty was not without risk, and that people
should not expect the government to come to their rescue automatically.
There is, however, a lively debate about whether there was a fourth
big mistake: Alan Greenspan's decision in 2001-04 to push and keep
nominal interest rates on U.S. Treasury securities very low in order to
try to keep the economy near full employment. In other words, should
Greenspan have kept interest rates higher and triggered a recession in
order to avert the growth of a housing bubble?
If we push interest rates up, Greenspan thought, millions of
Americans would become unemployed, to no one's benefit. If interest
rates were allowed to fall, these extra workers would be employed
building houses and making things to sell to all the people whose
incomes come from the construction sector.
Full employment is better than high unemployment if it can be
accomplished without inflation, Greenspan thought. If a bubble develops,
and if the bubble does not deflate but collapses, threatening to cause a
depression, the Fed would have the policy tools to short-circuit that
chain.
In hindsight, Greenspan was wrong. But the question is: was the bet
that Greenspan made a favorable one? Whenever in the future the United
States finds itself in a situation like 2003, should it try to keep the
economy near full employment even at some risk of a developing bubble?
I am genuinely unsure as to which side I come down on in this
debate. Central bankers have long recognized that it is imprudent to
lower interest rates in pursuit of full employment if the consequence is
an inflationary spiral. Some days I think that, in the future, central
bankers must also recognize that it is imprudent to lower interest rates
in pursuit of full employment when doing so risks causing an asset price
bubble. Other days, however, I think that, even with the extra
information we have learned about the structure of the economy,
Greenspan's decisions in 2001-04 were prudent and committed us to a
favorable and acceptable bet.
What I do know is that the way the issue is usually posed is wrong.
People claim that Greenspan's Fed "aggressively pushed
interest rates below a natural level." But what is the natural
level? In the 1920s, Swedish economist Knut Wicksell defined it as the
interest rate at which, economy-wide, desired investment equals desired
savings, implying no upward pressure on consumer prices, resource
prices, or wages as aggregate demand outruns supply, and no downward
pressure on these prices as supply exceeds demand.
On Wicksell's definition--the best, and, in fact, the only
definition I know of--the market interest rate was, if anything, above
the natural interest rate in the early 2000s: the threat was deflation,
not accelerating inflation. The natural interest rate was low because,
as the Fed's current chairman Ben Bernanke explained at the time,
the world had a global savings glut (or, rather, a global investment
deficiency).
You can argue that Greenspan's policies in the early 2000s
were wrong. But you cannot argue that he aggressively pushed the
interest rate below its natural level. Rather, Greenspan's
mistake--if it was a mistake--was his failure to overrule the market and
aggressively push the interest rate up above its natural rate, which
would have deepened and prolonged the recession that started in 2001.
But today is one of those days when I don't think that
Greenspan's failure to raise interest rates above the natural rate
to generate high unemployment and avert the growth of a mortgage-finance
bubble was a mistake. There were plenty of other mistakes that generated
the catastrophe that faces us today.
J. Bradford DeLong is Professor of Economics at the University of
California at Berkeley and a former Assistant U.S. Treasury Secretary.