A call for an "Asian Plaza": introducing an action plan for a new "G5"--China, Saudi Arabia, Euroland, Japan, and the United States.
Bergsten, C. Fred
From 1995 to early 2002, the dollar rose by a trade-weighted
average of about 40 percent. Largely as a result, the U.S. current
account deficit grew by an average of about $70 billion annually for ten
years. It exceeded $800 billion and 6 percent of GDP in 2006. This
posed, and continues to pose, two major consequences for the world
economy.
The first was the risk of international financial instability and
economic turndown. To finance both its current account deficit and its
own large foreign investments, the United States had to attract about $7
billion of foreign capital every working day. Any significant shortfall
from that level of foreign demand for dollars would drive the exchange
rate down, and U.S. inflation and interest rates up. With the U.S.
economy near full employment but already having slowed, the result would
be stagflation at best and perhaps a nasty recession.
The current travails of the U.S. economy are clearly related to
these imbalances. The huge inflow of foreign capital to fund the
external deficits held interest rates down and contributed significantly
to the housing bubble that triggered the financial crisis and economic
turndown. The sizeable slide of the dollar has indeed added to price
increases, notably of oil as the producing countries seek to counter the
losses it causes for their purchasing power, and thus greatly
complicates the management of monetary policy as it tries to prevent a
recession. The world economy is also adversely affected through the
impact on other countries, as their currencies rise and they experience
significant reductions in the trade surpluses on which their growth had
come to depend.
Second is the domestic political risk of trade restrictions in the
United States and thus disruption of the global trading system. Dollar
overvaluation and the resulting external deficits are historically the
most accurate leading indicators of U.S. protectionism because they
drastically alter the domestic politics of the issue, adding to the
pressures to enact new distortions and weakening pro-trade forces. These
traditional factors are particularly toxic in the current context of
strong anti-globalization sentiments and economic weakness. The spate of
administrative actions against China over the past several years, and
the numerous anti-China bills now under active consideration by the
Congress, demonstrate the point graphically since China is by far the
largest surplus country and its currency is so dramatically undervalued.
The U.S. current account deficit does not have to be eliminated. It
needed to be cut roughly in half, however, to stabilize the ratio of
U.S. foreign debt to GDP. That ratio was on an explosive path, which
would have exceeded 50 percent within the next few years and an
unprecedented 80 percent or so in ten. Avoiding such outcomes required
improvement of about $400 billion from the levels reached by 2006.
I and colleagues at our Peterson Institute for International
Economics have been pointing to these dangers since the end of the
1990s, and calling for corrective action that would include a very large
decline in the exchange rate of the dollar. We were confident that such
a decline would, as in the past, produce a substantial turnaround in the
U.S. external position and it is now doing so. The current account
deficit has fallen by more than $100 billion and is likely to drop by
another $100 billion or so over the next couple of years. The fall of
the dollar by 25-35 percent over the past six years, depending on which
index is used, has sharply increased the international competitiveness
of the U.S. economy. Exports have been growing at more than 8 percent
annually for the past tour years and by about 12 percent for the last
two. Especially with the recent slowdown in U.S. growth, they are now
expanding four times as fast as imports.
The internal corollary is of course that U.S. domestic demand,
initially residential investment but now also consumption, is rising
more slowly than output. This inevitable reversal, after a decade in
which internal demand climbed more sharply than production, means that
the improving trade balance is cushioning the aggregate U.S. slowdown to
an important extent. We are in fact experiencing the first episode of
"reverse coupling," through which the rest of the world
continues to expand and pulls up the United States rather than being
devastated by its turndown. This is an early indication of the shift in
global economic weights, with the rapidly growing emerging markets now
accounting for almost half of world output, as well as a timely
unwinding of the chief global imbalance of the early twenty-first
century.
THE CURRENT AGENDA
Even on this modestly optimistic prognosis, however, the U.S.
deficit will remain too large. The dollar needs to fall by another 5-10
percent to cut the imbalance to a sustainable 3 percent of GDP. This is
one of the three key factors that underlie the current set of imbalances
that should now be addressed by global economic policy.
The second factor is the continuing surge of China's global
current account surplus. That imbalance reached about $400 billion in
2007 and, while growing more slowly in the future, is likely to reach
$500 billion by next year. It will thus be almost as large as
America's global current account deficit in absolute terms in an
economy about one-third the size of the United States. The surplus
exceeds 10 percent of China's GDP, an unprecedented level for the
world's largest exporting nation. The Chinese authorities have let
their currency rise more rapidly against the dollar over the past few
months, and continued appreciation at that pace for another two or three
years could cut their surplus to a manageable level, but the renminbi
has still not climbed at all against a trade-weighted average of the
currencies of its main trading partners since the dollar peaked in early
2002 and its own surpluses started to climb.
The third factor is the creation of the euro, which provides a real
international monetary rival for the dollar for the first time in almost
a century. The dollar has been the world's dominant currency since
the abdication of sterling, around the time of the First World War,
primarily because it had no competition. No other currency was based on
an economy and financial system that even approached the size of the
U.S. economy or its capital markets, and thus none could even begin to
challenge the dollar in international finance. Former German Chancellor
Helmut Schmidt used to assert correctly that the deutschemark, the
world's second leading currency for most of the postwar period,
could never rival the dollar because "West Germany was the size of
Oregon."
The creation of the euro changes all that. The European Union as a
whole, and even the slightly smaller Euroland, has an economy about as
large as the United States and exceeds U.S. levels of both external
trade and monetary reserves. The euro has already outstripped the dollar
in terms of currency holdings around the world and denomination of
private bond flotations.
The dollar will obviously remain a major international currency and
it may be some time before the euro overtakes it, if it ever does so.
But we should expect a steady and sizable portfolio diversification from
dollars into euros as private investors, central banks, and sovereign
wealth funds seek to align the currency composition of their assets with
the new structure of the world economy and global finance. One result
will be steady upward pressure on the euro, and downward pressure on the
dollar, in the exchange markets over the longer run. A somewhat similar
portfolio adjustment took place from yen into dollars during the early
1980s, after Japan finally lifted its controls on capital outflows,
adding substantially to the upward pressure on the dollar during that
period.
A PROPOSED RESPONSE
The result of these developments is a series of imbalances, some
old and some potentially new, that create major risks for the world
economy, international financial stability, and the trading system (due
to the protectionist impact of large currency overvaluations). They call
for urgent new policy initiatives by the G7, the International Monetary
Fund, and probably new groupings of key countries that reflect the
rapidly evolving power structure of the global economy.
First, there is now a substantial risk of a free fall of the
dollar. Its sizable depreciation over the past six years has been
gradual and orderly, and it is approaching an equilibrium level. As
often happens in the last stages of a major currency swing, however,
like the dollar's upward overshoot in 1984-85 and downward
overshoot in 1995, that decline could now accelerate.
Both growth differentials and interest rate differentials have
moved sharply against the dollar and are likely to continue doing so for
a while. As noted, the current account imbalances remain too large and
the maturation of the euro creates an additional incentive for shifts
out of the dollar. Perhaps even more importantly, the acute slowdown in
U.S. productivity growth undercuts the chief rationale for the strong
dollar of the second half of the 1990s, and the advent of stagflation
conjures up images of the 1970s, which witnessed three sharp dollar
declines--including in 1978-79 its closest approximation to date of a
"hard landing."
The G7, in conjunction with the major Asian economies, thus needs
to be ready with a contingency intervention plan to limit the pace (and
perhaps extent) of dollar decline if a free fall begins to eventuate.
They should not seek to block the further realignment of exchange rates
that is needed to complete the adjustment process, especially against
the Asian currencies as elaborated below. However, dollar depreciation
of excessive speed and magnitude could exacerbate the present economic
weaknesses in both deficit and surplus countries: raising inflation and
interest rates in the United States, perhaps sharply, and weakening
export and overall growth in Europe, Canada, Australia, and others. In
the present fragile environment, it could also ignite another round of
global financial turmoil. The results could be sufficiently severe to
tip the current global slowdown into a world recession.
It should in fact be simple for the G7 along with the key Asians,
most of whom are already intervening substantially, to agree to moderate
the pace and amplitude of the dollar's final decline. One would
indeed assume that the needed contingency plans have already been
prepared. However, the failure of these same countries to anticipate and
respond cooperatively to the current financial crisis generates little
confidence in their ability to work together even when the benefits of
doing so are blindingly obvious. A new initiative on this front,
orchestrated particularly by the United States and Euroland as the
issuers of the world's two key currencies, is likely to be
necessary.
Second, the remaining decline of the dollar needs to be steered in
geographically appropriate directions. It should take place, wholly or
very largely, against the renminbi and the currencies of other Asian
countries along with a number of oil exporters. These countries are
running most of the counterpart surpluses to the U.S. deficit, and
piling up massive foreign exchange reserves, and the International
Monetary Fund has recently certified that most of them enjoy the option
of expanding domestic demand to offset the adverse growth impact of
declining trade surpluses.
If these surplus countries continue to resist significant
appreciation of their exchange rates, the counter parties to the dollar
decline will be the currencies (mainly of Euroland, the United Kingdom,
Canada, and Australia) that have already risen substantially and whose
countries are not running substantial (if any) surpluses. The result
would be the creation of sizable new imbalances that would produce new
problems for the world economy and, due to the protectionist impact of
large currency overvaluations, for the already-beleaguered global
trading system. In the meantime, further increases in the Chinese (and
other Asian and oil producer) surpluses, coupled with the declining U.S.
deficit, will place considerable pressure on the trade positions and
growth prospects of the rest of the world.
There is no effective monetary coordination, or even cooperation,
among the Asian economies despite their Chiang Mai Initiative and the
swap agreements that they have arranged over the past few years. Hence
any individual Asian country understandably fears that permitting its
own currency to appreciate unilaterally could undercut its position
against its neighbors and chief competitors, as has in fact happened to
Korea since it let the won rise sharply. This collective action problem
can be solved only by an Asian Plaza Agreement, or some informal
equivalent, through which the main countries in the region agree to let
all their currencies rise more or less in tandem with the renminbi once
it is permitted to strengthen substantially. Such an agreement would
make an important difference: if all the major East Asian currencies
(including the yen) moved together, they would climb by trade-weighted
averages of a very manageable 12-15 percent each even if they all
appreciated by 30 percent against the dollar.
The International Monetary Fund should take the lead in forging
such an "Asian Plaza." Now that Euroland has joined the United
States in sharply criticizing China's huge surpluses and massive
intervention to limit the rise of the renminbi, and especially as Asian
and developing countries such as India and Mexico have expressed similar
alarms, the International Monetary Fund should be able to forge a
sufficient consensus to do the Asians the great favor of enabling them
to act together on this issue. A dividend for the International Monetary
Fund should be enhanced status in Asia and thus a major deterrent to any
future consideration of a rival Asian Monetary Fund.
The third needed initiative would reinforce the first two but
address as well the secular impact of the advent of the euro as a global
key currency: creation of a Substitution Account at the International
Monetary Fund to avoid some of the exchange-rate impact of dollar
diversification by providing an off-market alternative for its
realization. Such an account, which was actively negotiated and almost
came into being during an earlier bout of dollar diversification in the
late 1970s, would accept unwanted dollars from official holders in
return for Special Drawing Rights at the Fund. The investors in the
account would receive a widely diversified and highly liquid asset with
a market interest rate while protecting the value of their (very large)
remaining dollar assets. The Euroland countries would avoid additional
appreciation of their currency. The United States would avoid excessive
weakness of the dollar. The International Monetary Fund would gain a new
lease on life.
Such an initiative should thus have widespread appeal and all
parties should be willing to use part of the International Monetary
Fund's large gold holdings to protect the account against valuation
losses if the dollar were to fall further in the future, which was the
chief sticking point during the previous negotiation. Since the dollar
is probably near its lows, at least for a considerable time, a rebound
that would instead generate sizable profits for the Substitution Account
over the next decade or so is in fact more likely--as would have
occurred had it been agreed in 1980.
CONCLUSION
The partial and continuing correction of the world's
previously dominant imbalance, the U.S. current account deficit,
highlights and indeed exposes several other actual or potential
imbalances that pose major risks and must now join it at the forefront
of the global policy agenda: avoidance of a free fall of the dollar,
correction of the huge Chinese surplus (and other Asian and oil
surpluses), the related prevention of a building of new deficits in
Europe and other areas where currency appreciation may go too far, and
the exchange rate impact of the advent of the euro as a global rival to
the dollar.
Different groups should take the lead in addressing each of these
problems. The United States and Euroland should devise the contingency
plans to counter a free fall of the dollar against the euro, and spur
the initial negotiations to create a Substitution Account to limit the
market impact of diversification from dollars to euros. The Asians
should work out a coordinated realignment of their currencies against
the dollar. The International Monetary Fund is the chief institution to
implement most of these plans.
This would also be an ideal agenda for the "new G5"
recently created by the International Monetary Fund to conduct its
revived multilateral surveillance program. The new group includes China
and Saudi Arabia, for the oil exporters, as well as the United States,
Euroland, and Japan. It could seize the moment to replace the G7 as the
key steering committee for the world economy, greatly strengthening the
position of the convening International Monetary Fund in the process. A
failure to pursue all three components of the strategy will leave the
world at substantial risk in the period ahead and deepen the threats to
the world economy that are posed by the current financial crisis.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
Former German Chancellor Helmut Schmidt used to assert correctly
that the deutschemark, the world's second leading currency for most
of the postwar period, could never rival the dollar because "West
Germany was the size of Oregon."
The creation of the euro changes all that.
--F. Bergsten
C. Fred Bergsten is Director of the Peterson Institute for
International Economics.