The single-license solution: instead of federal chartering, states should compete with each other to produce efficient insurance regulation.
Butler, Henry N. ; Ribstein, Larry E.
State regulation of insurance companies has been criticized for
many years. Forcing firms to comply with regulations that differ from
state to state increases costs, limits product innovation and rate
competition, and inhibits companies from exiting jurisdictions that
impose burdensome regulation. Thus, despite its appearance of being
decentralized federalism, the current state-based regulatory system does
not capture the benefits of jurisdictional competition that are found in
other areas of the law, notably corporate law.
The problems with state regulation and concerns about the
competitiveness of U.S. insurers in global financial markets have led to
several proposals to federalize insurance regulation. The most seriously
considered proposal calls for optional federal chartering (OFC) of
multi-state insurers. Although OFC was recently endorsed by the U.S.
Department of Treasury, the insurance industry is divided in its support
of OFC.
All proposals to centralize insurance regulation in Washington fail
to recognize the potential downsides of federal regulation. A major
problem with federal chartering is that it does not take advantage of
the potential for jurisdictional competition to generate a more
efficient regulatory structure. We propose that insurers could operate
nationally with only a single license granted by one state. Unlike OFC,
which adds only the federal charter option, our single-license solution
would provide 50 new licensing options for multi-state insurers. The
single-license solution has the potential for triggering competition and
innovation on insurance products and rates while preserving a role for
meaningful state regulation.
WHY REGULATE INSURANCE?
Insurance regulation is rationalized as protecting consumers from
unfair insurance contracts and ensuring the safety and soundness of the
companies themselves. Consumer protection regulation attempts to protect
consumers from their limited ability to bargain over the terms of
insurance contracts. The contracts use arcane language that even many
lawyers have difficulty understanding. At the time they buy their
policy, consumers may be unable to evaluate their coverage for the risk
that eventually occurs. As a result, insurers have an incentive to
overcharge for coverage. Safety-and-soundness regulation arises from the
concern that the insurance company will not be able to pay when it is
called upon to do so. Insurers have an incentive to charge low prices to
attract customers in the short run, which increases the likelihood of
default when the claims come due. Thus, while consumer
protection-oriented regulators are worried about rates being too high
for the amount of coverage, safety-and-soundness regulators are
concerned about rates being too low.
State guaranty funds protect consumers when insurers default. But
the funds also may encourage excessive investment risk by insurance
companies. Thus, just as bank regulation attempts to offset the moral
hazard created by federal deposit insurance, state insurance regulation
attempts to offset the risk created by state guaranty funds.
The rationales for regulation of insurance are not universally
accepted by scholars. Even if many individual consumers do not have the
time or expertise to track solvency or figure out policies, some do, and
the size of the market justifies the entry of expert intermediaries who
help consumers to find coverage. Moreover, insurers' emphasis on
standard-form con tracts and pricing makes price discrimination
difficult. Accordingly, competition gives insurers an incentive to offer
terms acceptable to the more sophisticated buyers. Thus an important
goal of insurance regulatory reform should be to set up an institutional
framework that allows financial markets and products to evolve in
response to already-present market forces.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
THE STRUCTURE OF INSURANCE REGULATION
The tensions in the current regulatory structure have been present
for at least 140 years. When insurance companies expanded across state
lines during the middle of the 19th century, they sought federal
regulation to relieve them from the burdens of complying with
regulations in multiple jurisdictions. The U.S. Supreme Court's
decision in Paul v. Virginia halted that effort in 1869 by holding that
insurance contracts were not interstate commerce. However, the Supreme
Court reversed course in 1944 in United States v. South-Eastern
Underwriters Association where it held that insurance was interstate
commerce and thus subject to federal antitrust regulation.
Though insurers favored a single federal regulator of insurance
prior to Paul v. Virginia, they changed their tune after South-Eastern
Underwriters presented them with the specter of federal antitrust
regulation. Antitrust regulation threatens insurers' ability to
enhance actuarial projections by cooperating through rating bureaus on
the collection and dissemination of risk information. The insurance
industry was anxious to remove the potential antitrust threat but did
not have enough clout to get the federal regulation it wanted. The
industry, therefore, joined with the state regulators through the
National Association of Insurance Commissioners (NAIC) to obtain passage
of the McCarran-Ferguson Act of 1945. McCarran-Ferguson provided limited
antitrust immunity for the insurance industry and confirmed the states
as the primary regulators of the insurance industry.
The era of regulation by dispersed state regulators was made
somewhat palatable to insurers by state cooperation through the NAIC.
However, several insurer failures in the late 1980s and early 1990s cast
doubt on the adequacy of state guaranty funds and triggered renewed
interest in federal regulation of insurance. Congress considered several
proposals for federal chartering and regulation and the establishment of
a federal guaranty fund. The NAIC successfully resisted that incursion onto their turf by encouraging state regulators to enact their own
risk-based capital requirements for insurers, modeled after federal
risk-based capital requirements for banks. However, political support
may be shifting toward an increased emphasis on federal regulation.
ARGUMENTS FOR FEDERAL REGULATION
Insurance is a national business. There are obvious scale economies
in the sale of insurance, particularly the cost advantages of a large
risk pool and standard-form policies. But as long as states have the
power to bar firms from selling in their states, insurers must pay a
regulatory tax in order to enter state markets. This gives
states--particularly those like California with the most lucrative
markets--the ability and incentive to impose inefficient regulation at
the behest of local interest groups.
Current regulation of insurance creates three problems:
* States suppress rates below market levels.
* Insurers must get each state's regulatory approval for every
policy they sell. States thus impose restrictions on insurers'
standard underwriting and risk classification, which undercuts
insurers' ability to achieve economies of scale.
* States impose a variety of consumer-protection rules that
interfere with the functioning of competitive markets.
Unlike many types of contracts, insurance policies cannot
effectively designate the law of a particular state as governing the
contract. If insurers could exit insurance markets in states that impose
excessive burdens, state regulation would be of less concern. But states
bar the doors by imposing restrictions on insurer exit--and they
sometimes impose those exit barriers only after the insurer has entered
the state. And exit is already an expensive option. For example, an
insurer may spend years developing a distribution system and customer
base, only to find itself subject to burdensome rates and regulations.
Because it is so costly for insurers to exit, they are at the mercy of
rent-extracting state regulators.
Calls for federal regulation are motivated by longstanding problems
of duplication and overregulation that result from the current
state-based system. The aggressive behavior of Mississippi and Florida
regulators, who basically attempted to force insurers to renew
homeowners' policies at low rates following severe hurricane damage
in 2004 and 2005, has added urgency to the reform effort.
TREASURY PLAN The Treasury plan for optional federal chartering is
similar to the proposed National Insurance Act of 2007 and other
legislative proposals that would create an optional federal charter. The
Treasury plan would give multi-state insurance companies the option of
obtaining a federal charter that would allow them to operate throughout
the country without regard to state licensing and entry restrictions.
The plan would create a new Office of National Insurance within the
Treasury Department that would be headed by a commissioner. The plan
would also establish an Office of Insurance Oversight to address
international regulatory issues and advise the secretary on major
domestic and international policy issues. Nationally chartered insurers
would be exempt from state rate regulations.
OFC proposals are premised on the assumption that national
regulators will provide more balanced and reasonable regulation than
decentralized state regulators. Supporters of OFC argue that
establishing an optional federal charter would not supplant state
regulation or state premium taxation because OFC would allow insurers to
choose between state and federal regulation.
FALSE PROMISE The central problem with OFC is that--like the
current regulatory structure--it preserves only the mirage of
competition. The proposed National Insurance Act would let multi-state
insurers either choose a single federal charter or continue to be
subject to multiple state regulators. Given the high costs of the state
system, large national insurers would be highly likely to choose the
federal charter. Thus, OFC is likely to evolve into an all-federal
system for the large national insurers. Ultimately, insurers would gain
little from this "choice." Federal politicians would engage in
"rent extraction" up to the difference between the regulatory
costs under the federal regime and those under the state regime.
Insurers could lose the benefit of the gains associated with opting into
federal regulation plus the transaction costs of resubmitting to
licensing in each state.
Of course, the large insurers are not stupid and they likely
recognize the risk of lock-in and rent extraction. They are willing to
take the risk of federal control because of their frustration with the
current regulatory regime. State guaranty funds are part of the problem.
As Bert Ely has explained, "if government wants to be in the
business, for whatever reason, of regulating financial institutions,
then it has no choice but to provide a warranty for the service that
business supposedly provides to the general public." The problem is
that as long as consumers demand a warranty, they are likely to insist
on the stronger warranty the federal government can provide. And once
the federal guarantee exists, state funds will disappear just as
non-federal deposit insurance for banks almost completely disappeared in
the wake of federal insurance.
Reform proponents overestimate the likelihood that their favored
proposal will work as intended. The task of determining appropriate or
optimal standards under federal charters may appear simple and
straightforward. After all, state regulators and the NAIC have been
promulgating rules and regulations for a long time. Law professors and
other experts may find it difficult to believe that smart,
well-intentioned federal regulators could reach bad conclusions. But
reform of a complex system is immensely difficult to get right, even
under the highly unrealistic assumption that current conditions will not
change. If conditions do change, today's panacea will become
tomorrow's problem. Meaningful reform requires establishing a
system that will reach the right solutions today and tomorrow.
Federalism can be a dynamic regulatory regime that provides
important benefits: experimentation and regulatory evolution in response
to changes in exogenous and endogenous forces. In particular, a
state-based system facilitates reversal of inevitable policy mistakes
that can easily become permanent at the federal level. Consider, for
example, the Sarbanes-Oxley Act, a hastily adopted law that brought
increased federalization of previously state-dominated corporation law.
Almost from the moment of its enactment, Sarbanes-Oxley has caused costs
and problems for publicly traded firms and their shareholders. Yet no
serious attempt to reform the legislation exists. Similarly, federal
controls on interest rates outlasted their usefulness to the point that
they bankrupted the entire savings-and-loan industry.
The objective in reforming insurance regulation should be to fix
the problems of state law without imposing the potential costs of
federalizing insurance law. Under a federal regime, insurers would be
forced to deal with a single legislature and perhaps a single regulatory
agency. They would be vulnerable to repeated threats of additional
costly regulation and attempts to extract rents, with little ability to
respond to the threat through exit to another regime.
THE SINGLE-LICENSE SOLUTION
An alternative to the federal domination that is likely to occur
under OFC is to model federal insurance regulation after corporate
chartering, which takes advantage of jurisdictional competition. Under
the regulatory federalism of the corporate chartering system, most
internal governance is left to the chartering state, with a federal
minimum standard that takes the form of disclosure regulation. An
analogous proposal for insurance regulation would allow an insurer to be
chartered in a primary state of its choice, and sell in any state
provided the insurer met minimum federal standards.
The single-license system would not require creating new entities
or massive new federal regulatory bodies. Because the federal government
excluded itself from this regulatory area by McCarran-Ferguson, there is
no federal regulatory apparatus to dismantle in order to institute
effective state competition. The single-license approach would, however,
require federal legislation. The states have had 60 years since
McCarran-Ferguson to evolve toward jurisdictional competition and have
instead embraced a state cartel under the NAIC. Insurance is a national
market, and Congress must not allow the states to continue to disrupt
interstate commerce.
REMOVING BARRIERS The jurisdictional competition approach to
insurance regulation could, in theory, evolve through reciprocal and
multi-state agreements among states to recognize licenses granted by
other states. This has not happened, and it is not obvious that it would
ever happen with the provincial nature of current state-based insurance
regulation.
Accordingly, federal legislation mandating jurisdictional choice is
necessary. Specifically, the federal statute should clearly authorize a
state to charter insurance companies that can operate in all other
states, subject only to non-discriminatory solvency regulation that the
non-chartering state imposes on insurers chartered in that state. This
would enable consumers in every state to shop for insurance from
companies regardless of where they are chartered, based on price,
quality, and type of product.
In order for meaningful jurisdictional competition to occur,
insurers must be able to exit their licensing state at low cost. The
concern is that states might require insurers to pay a large exit fee if
they want to reincorporate in another state. Firms can protect
themselves to some extent by refusing to enter states that impose such
restrictions. The danger is that states will impose restrictions for the
first time after the insurer enters the state. To protect against that
risk, any federal choice-of-law or single-licensing enabling statute must include provisions designed to facilitate low-cost exit.
TAX INCENTIVES A robust market for insurance regulation requires
that states have an incentive to compete to provide such regulation.
That incentive can be provided by properly allocating state tax revenue
from insurance sales. However, it is unlikely that the states will agree
on their own to such a reallocation because many--perhaps most--states
will be net losers under the system. Accordingly, designing a federal
jurisdictional choice statute requires considering the appropriate
allocation of state tax revenues.
The most straightforward allocation would be for the insurance tax
revenue to go to the chartering state of the insurance company that
sells the policy. Because a substantial amount of revenue is at stake,
it seems likely that several states would be willing to invest in the
creation of a regulatory environment that makes their state an
attractive primary state. Other states would have some incentive to keep
up with regulatory changes in other states in order to avoid losing
revenues.
The problem with this straightforward proposal is that
representatives from states that expect to lose revenues from the
proposal would likely oppose it. A 50-50 allocation of the tax base
(i.e., the premium paid) between the state of the insured and the state
of the insurer accordingly might be politically more feasible. The
states would determine their own tax rates. Under this approach, states
have an incentive to compete because they lose tax revenue if their
insurers charter elsewhere or lose market share from operating under
inefficient regulation. However, even the least competitive states would
not lose all tax revenues because they would share the tax revenues
earned from firms chartered in the dominant states.
A potential problem with this approach is that a sudden shift to
the new regime could benefit the states that are in position to gear up
for competition most quickly. First-mover advantages may stunt the
development of vibrant jurisdictional competition. The problem might be
mitigated by phasing in the allocation. For example, under a six-year
phase-in, the split would go from 100-0, 90-10, 80-20, 70-30, 60-40, to
50-50 in the sixth year.
It is difficult to predict the type of interstate market for
insurance licenses that might evolve. States with smaller markets might
have a stronger incentive to specialize in the market for insurance
regulation because their potential payoff is a larger share of total tax
revenues than for larger states. On the other hand, states where major
insurance companies are headquartered may take the lead in order to
capture an incumbent advantage. The jurisdictional competition under a
single-license approach might lead to overall lower insurance rates
because dominant states have an incentive to attract firms by reducing
their chartering firms' operating costs. Also, it is likely that
jurisdictional competition will lead to the demise of rate regulation in
much the same way that jurisdictional competition increased the
availability of the corporate form in the late 1800s.
SOLVENCY A key aspect of state insurance regulation is setting
solvency standards that ensure that insurers can pay insured claims. An
alternative mechanism that would provide safety comparable to state
funds without federalization would be federal regulation that requires
insurers to issue solvency bonds that default if the state guaranty fund
fails. The bonds' yield would reflect the dispersed information
available in the market rather than investigation by individual bond
rating agencies. The information-sensitive bonds would provide a
market-based monitoring mechanism that would be independent of rating
agencies and free from political influence. A state's temptation to
regulate rates or lower solvency standards would be disciplined by the
increase in the cost of the bond for firms chartered in the state. Firms
would avoid states whose charters increase the cost of the bond, thereby
removing states' incentives to race to the bottom by
under-regulating solvency.
CONSUMER PROTECTION The single-license solution ultimately provides
consumer protection through nationwide rate competition, incentives and
ability to offer new products, and increased information in national
advertising. Our proposed statute provides that the state law designated
in the insurance policy would apply to all matters concerning the
application and validity of the insurance policy. The insurer could
designate the consumer protection law of any state, including but not
limited to the chartering (licensing) state. However, the regulation of
a state in which the policies are sold could trump the designated state
law if the regulating state explicitly prohibits enforcement of the
choice-of-law clause. That would enable companies to choose the single
law that best suits their business and to have that law govern its
policies wherever they do business. This proposal helps to ensure a
competitive interstate market that would make transparent the costs of
inefficient, rate-increasing "consumer protection" regulation.
One potential criticism of this approach is that states might seek
to attract insurers by offering unduly lax consumer protection laws. Our
proposed federal statute addresses this concern by permitting states to
override contractual choice of law. At the same time, our proposal
protects insurers from excessively burdensome multiple-state regulation
by
* requiring any state override to be by the legislature;
* making the override effective only if enacted by a state where
policies are sold and as to policies sold after the legislation is
enacted; and
* giving the insurer a clear right to exit the state.
The requirement of enactment by the legislature serves two
purposes. First, it gives insurers certainty and ex ante predictability.
Insurers will know before selling policies in a particular state whether
their chosen law will apply, rather than having to wait for a judicial
determination of the effect of the state on choice-of-law contracts
under vague choice-of-law rules. Second, it provides an implicit
political check on state incentives to override contractual choice of
law. An interest group that seeks to regulate insurance policies in the
state must bear the burden of getting political support not only for the
regulation itself, but also for invalidating attempted avoidance of the
regulation through contractual choice of law. This forces the full
effect of the law to the enactment stage rather than deferring the
validity of choice-of-law clauses to the courts.
The stipulations that state override applies only to policies sold
in the regulating state after the passage of the regulation and ensuring
insurers' right to exit maximize insurers' ability to avoid
oppressive state laws. That raises the political ante for pro-regulatory
interest groups because exit can impose costs on local consumers and
others. Legislatures would have to take into account at the time of
enactment lobbying, not only by the insurers that would be subject to
the regulation, but also by consumers and others who would be hurt if
firms left the state in order to avoid the law.
ADDRESSING CONCERNS
Critics of our single-license approach are likely to raise two
general objections. First, consumer advocates may argue that legislators
and regulators would try to attract insurers (and the tax revenues they
bring with them) by promising not to regulate strictly. This
"race-to-the-bottom" would destabilize insurance guaranty
funds and put consumers at risk. Second, insurers may fear that our
proposed qualifications on single licensing would leave the door open
for continued aggressive regulation by multiple state regulators.
RACE TO THE BOTTOM The appropriate starting point in addressing the
race-to-the-bottom argument is whether the risk of such a race is
greater for insurance regulation than for corporate law, which provides
the model for state chartering. Corporate legal scholarship has
generally supported the conclusion that the competition between the
chartering states benefits shareholders. Do the same considerations
apply to single-state licensing of insurers?
One might argue that the corporate internal affairs doctrine (IAD),
which is the basis of state competition in corporate law, is stable
precisely because it does not attempt to invade traditional areas of
state regulation. The IAD is fairly narrow and excludes controversial
aspects of regulating corporations, such as securities fraud and
disclosure, antitrust law, bankruptcy, and myriad types of corporate
conduct, for treatment by federal law or state law that is not within
the IAD. The IAD's triviality may partly explain why Congress has
not preempted the field, though it clearly has the power to do so.
Insurance regulation arguably bears a closer resemblance to
traditional consumer protection law and therefore is likely to trigger
much stronger objections to applying firms' chosen state law. We
think such concerns are unwarranted, but we have attempted to mitigate
this risk through federal market-based constraints on solvency
regulation and by allowing for limited state override of the licensing
state to protect consumers.
EXCESSIVE STATE REGULATION Insurers may object that the limitations
we propose on state competition allow aggressive state legislatures to
take advantage of their power to override the single license and impose
multiple regulatory burdens on insurers. But aggressive states
understand that insurers not only can exit their markets, but also will
respond by continuing to lobby Congress for the federal charter option.
Given the persisting pressure for federal intervention, our
single-license approach could be viewed as a kind of second coming of
state regulation. The problems of state regulation have led to loud
calls for federal regulation from both consumers and insurers. We argue
for rehabilitation of state regulation by opening regulation to
jurisdictional competition. But if the rehabilitation does not work,
state regulators understand that the calls for a federal chartering
option may become politically irresistible.
OFFICE OF NATIONAL INSURANCE
The Treasury plan's proposed Office of National Insurance
could play an important role in our single-license scheme by collecting,
disseminating, and analyzing information about the effectiveness of
state jurisdictional competition. The data would indicate if state
regulation has been too lax or if states are imposing excessive
regulatory burdens on insurers. If, after a period of several years, it
appears that the single-license approach has not improved the
functioning of insurance markets, then the Office of National Insurance
could recommend that Congress provide for a federal charter option.
The National Insurance Office would have the additional function
and benefit of better enabling U.S. insurers to enter foreign markets.
Critics of state law have suggested that U.S. insurers are at a
competitive disadvantage in attempting to enter foreign markets because
it is hard for dispersed state regulators to offer reciprocal privileges
to foreign insurers entering the United States. This problem would be
alleviated under our approach because the foreign insurer would only
have to obtain a single license. However, the problem would continue to
some extent because no one regulator would represent U.S. interests in
international negotiations. The proposed National Insurance Office could
not only be a way to clarify the state licensing alternatives available
to foreign entrants, but a mechanism for negotiating international
treaties.
TRULY OPTIONAL FEDERAL CHARTERS
Under the single-license approach, lax or aggressive state
regulators would be disciplined by jurisdictional competition from other
states. The threat of a federal charter option might offer some
discipline as well. As discussed above, the current proposal for
optional federal chartering does not offer a true option for several
reasons:
* Insurers' only other choice is continued exposure to
regulation in each state in which they sell insurance.
* The federal government is likely to be able to back up its
regulation with a better solvency guaranty fund than any state regulator
* The federal government would be able to quickly offer higher
quality regulation than any state under the weak incentives of the
current state regulatory system.
The single-license proposal would give states a competitive
incentive to offer superior regulation, thereby arguably making optional
federal chartering unnecessary.
Although optional federal chartering may be unnecessary under a
favorable view of state competition, it offers a potential alternative
for insurers or consumer groups that object to our single-license
alternative. It is important to emphasize that we are referring to truly
optional chartering, in which the federal charter competes on a level
playing field with state chartering.
Leveling the playing field would involve not only offering the
possibility of a single state license, but also giving the states the
opportunity to develop viable regulation under competition before the
federal government can enter the competition. Making the federal option
available immediately may stifle the development of jurisdictional
competition by the states. Accordingly, we suggest making the federal
charter available after a reasonable transition period of five years or
so. An alternative would be to empower the Office of National Insurance
to recommend the desirability or need for a federal charter option after
five years' experience under our single-license approach.
Truly optional federal chartering could be designed to address both
of the problems with single licensing identified above. Federal
chartering might deal with the problem of multiple state regulators
overriding chartering state law by providing that the federal charter
preempts state consumer protection regulation. Preemption is arguably
justified on the basis that the federal government has less revenue
incentive than a small state to race-to-the-bottom to attract chartering
business.
Federal chartering also could address state laxity by providing a
superior guaranty fund as a "warranty" to back solvency and
rate regulation. This would not only protect consumers, but also could
attract chartering business from insurers. Insurers could decide whether
they want the most efficient state regulation that has developed under
single-license competition, backed by market-based solvency protection,
or to offer their customers the security of a federal guaranty,
presumably at a higher price.
It is important, however, to keep in mind the caveat that the
federal option always has the potential to overwhelm even efficient
state competitors, resulting in a non-competitive system with a single
federal regulator. Because of this danger, federal chartering should be
made available only if there is a finding by an independent commission
or the National Insurance Office that there are defects in the
competitive single-license state system that are likely to be solved by
making the federal charter available
CONCLUSION
All proposals to federalize insurance regulation--whether through
mandatory or optional federal laws--create opportunities for abuse at
the hands of the federal government. Monopoly national regulation of the
insurance industry should be viewed with skepticism by both industry and
consumers. Insurance carriers could be subject to rent extraction by the
federal regulator, while consumers should be concerned about industry
capture of the centralized regulatory agency.
This article proposes a state-based regime that both protects
insurers from the worst effects of multiple regulators and creates a
real opportunity for jurisdictional competition and experimentation.
Given its strong potential benefits, state competition, under our
single-license approach, should be tried before a single federal
regulator. If the large multi-state insurers prevail in their push for
optional federal chartering, the legislation should be supplemented with
our single-license solution.
Readings
* Costly Policies: State Regulation and Antitrust Exemption in
Insurance Markets, by Jonathan R. Macey and Geoffrey P. Miller. AEI Press, 1993.
* "Federal Chartering of Insurance Companies: Options and
Alternative for Transforming Insurance Regulation," by Scott
Harrington. Policy Brief 2006-PB-02, Networks Financial Institute at
Indiana State University, March 2006.
* Optional Federal Chartering and the Regulation of Insurance
Companies, edited by Peter J. Wallison. AEI Press, 2000.
* "Optional Federal Chartering of Insurance: Design of a
Regulatory Structure," by Hal S. Scott. SSRN Paper #985579, March
2007.
* "Rent Extraction and Rent Creation in the Economic Theory of
Regulation," by Fred S. McChesney. Journal of Legal Studies, Vol.
16 (1987).
* "The Fatal Flaw of Proposals to Federalize Insurance,"
by Elizabeth F. Brown. SSRN Paper #1008993, August 2007.
* The Genius of American Corporate Law, by Roberta Romano. AEI
Press, 2000.
* The Law Market, by Erin A. O'Hara and Larry E. Ribstein.
Oxford University Press, 2008.
* The Sarbanes-Oxley Debacle, by Henry N. Butler and Larry E.
Ribstein. AEI Press, 2006.
BY HENRY N. BUTLER
Northwestern University School of law
AND
LARRY E. RIBSTEIN
University of Illinois College of Law
Henry N. Butler is executive director of the Searle Center for Law,
Regulation, and Economic Growth at the Northwestern University School of
Law.
Larry E. Ribstein is the Mildred van Voorhis Jones Chair in Law at
the University of Illinois College of Law.