Warming up to water markets: will global warming force us to adopt sensible resource policies?
Adler, Jonathan H.
Ensuring access to quality water supplies is among the most
pressing environmental policy challenges of the 21st century, and not
just in the developing world. In the United States, demographic changes
and existing water use patterns have placed tremendous pressure on water
supplies, particularly in the West. Most states anticipate water
shortages in coming years, even in the absence of drought conditions. It
is no wonder water policy experts contend, without exaggeration, that
the United States is heading toward a water scarcity crisis. Yet as bad
as the current water situation is, global climate change is likely to
make things much worse.
If current projections are accurate, global climate change will
exacerbate pressures on water resources, increasing the urgency with
which managers and policymakers must address water supply concerns. Even
a modest greenhouse warming over the next several decades will increase
the stress on freshwater supplies. Unless adaptive measures are taken
now, the consequences could be quite severe. In particular, the threat
of climate change requires the development of water supply institutions
and policies that are sufficiently flexible, adaptive, and robust to
deal with an uncertain and changing water future. Water markets fit the
bill. A gradual shift toward water marketing and market pricing will
improve the management of water supplies, ensure more efficient
allocation of available supplies, and encourage cost-effective
conservation measures, thereby blunting the impact of climate change on
supplies and availability. Failure to take such steps, on the other
hand, could allow a bad water situation to get much worse.
WARMING AND WATER
Global climate change will affect freshwater supplies in many ways.
Shifts in the timing, location, and amount of precipitation are likely
to accompany any increase in temperatures. Different amounts of rain and
snow at different times in different places could prove disruptive for
many communities, particularly those that depend on snow melt for
irrigation and seasonal water supplies. A projected warming of the
climate is likely to produce changes in evaporation rates and soil
moisture, with additional effects on stream flows and groundwater
supplies.
Global warming's effects on water resources will be compounded
by changes in water demand for various uses as communities adapt to
changing temperatures and precipitation patterns. Water use for
irrigation, for example, is likely to increase along with global
temperatures, even if there is a net increase in precipitation. More
rain or snow, if not at the right time or in a different place, may not
satisfy increased water needs. Existing water institutions may be unable
to cope with such changes, particularly if natural water supplies shift
significantly.
Climatic effects on water supplies will occur against a background
of increasing water scarcity throughout much of the nation, and
particularly in the West where urban growth is fueling dramatic
increases in water demand. Domestic water use in western states more
than doubled from 1960 to 1990, from 6.5 million acre-feet to 14 million
acre-feet, and continues to climb. Per-capita water consumption
increased throughout the 20th century, despite increased awareness of
pressures on water supplies. As populations continue to grow in western
states, demand for water will only increase. Further, demand for
in-stream flows and other water uses is also increasing, while
traditional means of augmenting water supply through dams, reservoirs,
and the like have reached their limits. Without substantial reforms,
existing water institutions will have difficulty meeting current
demands, let alone the increased demands brought about by climate
change.
Climate change presents a particularly thorny dilemma for water
management. The gradual warming of the atmosphere is certain to change
the distribution and availability of water supplies. Yet the precise
nature, magnitude, timing, and distribution of such changes are
unknowable. This uncertainty complicates the task of water managers who
are already faced with escalating demands as past hydrological conditions are no longer a reliable predictor of future conditions.
Without institutions capable of accommodating such uncertainty and
shifting water supplies to where they are needed most, climate change
will impose significant costs on water users and water-dependent
communities.
[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
The challenge created by uncertainty requires the creation of
institutional arrangements that can foster greater resilience and
adaptability in water management. Effective institutions must be robust
enough to accommodate changes in water availability by facilitating
reallocation of water supplies. At the same time, the institutions must
encourage cost-effective conservation measures and efficiency
enhancements, and remain sufficiently flexible and adaptable to account
for the uncertain climate forecast. In short, the threat of climate
change calls for greater reliance upon water markets.
THE WISDOM OF WATER MARKETS
The demands of current and projected water management challenges
can best be met through a greater reliance on water markets for water
management. Specifically, water management must shift toward recognition
of transferable rights in water that facilitate voluntary exchanges and
the market pricing of water resources. While such reforms may be
difficult and there are no panaceas for the water management challenges
faced by the western United States, greater use of markets offers the
best opportunity to adapt to climate change and its impacts on water
supplies. Even the United Nations Intergovernmental Panel on Climate
Change acknowledges that "improving the functioning of water
markets could help create the kind of flexibility needed to respond to
uncertain changes in future water availability."
Markets are powerful institutions for resource allocation. They
facilitate the allocation of resources to their highest-valued use
through voluntary exchange and the generation of information about
relative scarcity and demand. Markets take advantage of localized and
dispersed information about resource supplies and demands, including
subjective valuations and individualized uses for different resources in
different places. Such information is virtually impossible to centralize in an administrative agency.
Market institutions are easily adapted to water management. Water
markets have been used in many parts of the world for the allocation and
distribution of rights in water. In the United States, for instance,
water markets emerged in many western states as an outgrowth of the
prior appropriation doctrine, which recognized property rights in water.
Those rights are usufructary rights--that is, rights to use water rather
than rights to the water itself--but they still facilitate the voluntary
transfer of water in the marketplace. As elsewhere, recognition of water
rights and water markets has encouraged efficient conservation of and
investment in water resources.
Property rights in water are the foundation for water markets and
can provide substantial incentives for increased efficiency and
allocation of rights to their highest-valued use. To be most effective,
water rights must be well-defined, enforceable, and transferable. The
precise contours and content of the rights can be quite variable,
however. Water rights can be defined in terms of actual water volume, a
share of a given water body or water flow, or in terms of the
availability of water of a particular quantity at a given place. Water
rights can also be consumptive or non-consumptive, and may or may not be
held subject to the rights of third parties or other water right
holders.
Where an individual is using a transferable resource in an
inefficient or wasteful manner, there is an opportunity for an
entrepreneur to gain from acquiring the resource and putting it to
better use. Where rights to water are transferable, water prices will
reflect the value of alternative uses. That gives the rights holder an
incentive to allocate the water to its highest-valued use.
Transferability also creates substantial incentives for conservation,
particularly insofar as rights holders can sell the water they conserve
to other users. Such incentives can be quite powerful, particularly
given the wide disparity between the prices agricultural users and
others pay for water in the United States.
Many agricultural users pay little for the water they use,
sometimes nothing more than the cost of pumping the water from a federal
irrigation project to the land where the water will be used. The U.S.
government has subsidized agricultural water use for decades,
encouraging profligate and wasteful water use in irrigation. Simply
allowing farmers to sell their water rights to "thirsty
cities" would provide substantial incentives to increase water use
efficiency in the agricultural sector. The result is a win-win
situation: the farmer receives payment for giving up water rights that
he no longer needs and the city gets water that it would otherwise not
have (or need to pay even more to obtain). The possibility of this type
of voluntary transaction resulting from the creation of a water market
increases efficiency and produces gains for buyer and seller alike.
THE POWER OF PRICES
Prices are an essential component of any well-functioning market,
and water markets are no exception. Price signals provide powerful
incentives for conservation while simultaneously communicating
information about collective judgments about the relative scarcity of
resources across time and space. As market conditions fluctuate, market
prices change accordingly. As environmental economist Richard Stroup
explains, "market prices adjust constantly to all of the supply and
demand variables, providing each buyer and each seller with up-to-date
information on changes in relative values in the world around
them." A market system in which users simply pay for the resource
that they use enables individual water users to weigh the tradeoff
between the cost of obtaining additional water, the cost of reducing or
conserving water use, and other relevant factors.
Through the price system, markets incorporate and account for far
more information than centralized administrative entities, and at far
less cost. This is important because information is both extremely
valuable and quite costly to uncover and accumulate. Accumulating and
processing the same volume of information through an administrative
process would be exceedingly costly and would be difficult (if not
impossible) to achieve in as timely a fashion.
A regulatory system that seeks to limit the amount of water used
for various purposes to "appropriate" amounts would require
the collection and consideration of myriad amounts of information
concerning the relevant information about how water is and could be used
within various industries in different places and at different times.
Such efforts rarely succeed as planned because centralized
decision-makers are not able to collect and process a sufficient volume
of information. An adaptive system, such as is required to respond
adequately to the threat of climate change, is even more information
intensive.
Market pricing for water will encourage consumers to use water more
efficiently. Given that most consumers pay artificially low water prices
(if they pay for water at all), few have much incentive to economize on
their water use. As economists Terry Anderson and Pamela Snyder explain
in their book Water Markets, "What is seen as a waste or
inefficient water use in rural or urban areas is simply the users'
rational response to low water prices."
It is often assumed that residential water demand is relatively
price inelastic and therefore price changes will not produce dramatic
changes in water use patterns. Yet actual experience shows that many
water users will reduce water consumption when faced with higher prices.
The responsiveness of different water users at different times and
places will vary, but users will respond. "If the price of water
rose, people would carefully examine how they use water, for what
purposes, and in what quantity," claims University of Arizona law
professor Robert Glennon. For example, per-capita water use is
approximately 300 gallons per day in Fresno, Calif., where water use is
not metered. In the neighboring community of Clovis, however, water is
metered and per-capita water use is 50 percent lower. Simply requiring
users to pay for what they use can produce significant change in water
use patterns.
Regretfully, public water authorities are reluctant to subject
consumers to higher prices, even during drought conditions. Increasing
water rates imposes visible costs on their constituents and risks
political unpopularity. Public officials would rather impose moratoria
on "wasteful" water uses than subject water use to the
discipline of price changes that reflect market conditions.
ACCOUNTING FOR UNCERTAINTY
One of the greatest challenges posed by climate change is the
uncertainty it magnifies, if not creates, of where and when we will have
water. Unfortunately, traditional planning tools are poorly equipped to
address climatic effects on water supplies. As Kenneth Frederick of
Resources for the Future explains, "planning and justifying
expensive new projects are difficult when the magnitude, timing, and
even the direction of the climate-induced changes are uncertain.
Building for changes that never materialize or failing to build
facilities to deal with changes that do occur are both potentially
costly." The high costs created by such uncertainty highlight the
need for flexible and adaptive water management institutions.
Water markets can both reduce uncertainty for water users and
provide security against the harms that uncertainty can produce. If
water users are able to purchase additional water rights from other
users, this can reduce the impact of droughts and other local or
temporal supply disruptions. While all water users in a given region may
suffer from drought conditions, the costs to some water users may be
greater than others. Transferable water rights enable water users to
shift those costs to those who are best able to bear them, thereby
reducing the overall costs of such unforeseen supply disruptions. In
case of drought, for instance, transferable rights ensure that water
supplies will go to the highest-valued uses, reducing the economic and
ecological costs of such events.
The ability to transfer water rights in advance of potential supply
changes further enables water users to reallocate the risk of
uncertainty. Water users can acquire options that will enable them to
obtain water necessary to address unanticipated changes in future
supply. As in commodity markets, such options are an important risk
management instrument and help reduce the costs of negative events.
THE MOVE TO MARKETS
There is an urgent need to develop more extensive market
institutions to manage water supplies. However, it may well be that the
most efficient systems of water markets evolve over time and cannot
simply be imposed by government fiat. Yet there are several steps
government agencies can take to facilitate the development of water
markets and greater reliance upon market institutions in the allocation
and management of water resources. These include:
* defining and recognizing the security and transferability of
property rights in water resources;
* eliminating government subsidies for water use and distribution;
* moving toward market-based prices for water; and
* identifying and reducing legal and regulatory barriers to water
transfers, particularly inter-basin and interstate water transfers.
The single most important step administrative agencies and
lawmaking bodies can take is to recognize and protect water rights so as
to provide the institutional foundation upon which water markets may be
built or evolve. As Stanford law professor Barton "Buzz"
Thompson observes, "By providing the legal infrastructure for water
markets and actively encouraging such markets, the government can help
reduce the harm from uncertainty in water rights and deliveries."
The University of Colorado's Charles Howe argues that
so-called "salvage legislation" would dramatically increase
the efficiency of water use, particularly in agriculture. In many
states, farmers and other rights owners operate under a "use it or
lose it" regime that only recognizes the validity of water rights
for certain uses that are considered "beneficial." A
consequence of such rules is that there is little incentive to improve
water use efficiency. Under "salvage legislation," however,
those who conserve water would acquire a valuable commodity: a
transferable water right that could be sold or put to other uses. By
ensuring those who manage to reduce their consumptive use of water do
not suffer reductions in their water rights, "salvage
legislation" would provide a substantial incentive to discover and
implement water efficiency improvements.
Legal and administrative barriers are not the only obstacles to
greater water marketing. In some cases, water transfers are simply too
costly to complete because of transportation or other transaction costs.
Where there are no legal or institutional barriers to such trades,
however, the potential for a wealth-maximizing trade creates incentives
for would-be entrepreneurs to uncover ways of lowering such transaction
costs so as to make a deal. This does not mean other concerns should be
ignored, however. Special accommodations may have to be made for water
markets to adequately take account of in-stream flows and sensitive
biological resources. But such accommodations should be made in the
context of water markets and such concerns should not be an excuse to
forestall market reforms. Indeed, water markets have substantial
environmental benefits, including increasing opportunities for
conservation organizations to, as market participants, directly
influence water allocation decisions by purchasing water for in-stream
flows and other ecologically valuable uses.
While much ink is spilled over concerns that allowing water
transfers could harm those communities from which water is transferred,
water markets provide a more equitable means of water transfer than the
administrative alternatives. In water markets, water is transferred as a
result of voluntary transactions between a willing buyer and a willing
seller. Those who had rights to water are compensated for giving up
their rights. While there still may be third parties who suffer indirect
effects from the water transfer, this is true under any water transfer
scenario. Only in the absence of water markets are such losses
compounded by the public harms resulting from inefficient water
allocation and waste.
CONCLUSION
Climate change presents many challenges, but it also presents
opportunities. In the case of water, the need to prepare for the impact
of climatic warming creates an opportunity to improve on existing
institutions. In particular, the threat of climate change could provide
the long-needed impetus to shift away from centralized political
management of water resources, toward market-based institutions. Such a
shift holds the potential to increase the efficiency and environmental
soundness of water use in the United States. So as the world warms,
policymakers should warm to water markets.
Readings
* "Climate Change and Freshwater Resources," by Noah D.
Hall, Bret B. Stuntz, and Robert H. Abrams. Natural Resources and
Environment, Vol. 22 (2008).
* "Real People, Real Resources, and Real Choices: The Case for
Market Valuation of Water," by Andrew P. Morriss. Texas Tech Law
Review, Vol. 38 (2006).
* "The Effects of Climate Change on Water Resources in the
West: Introduction and Overview," by Tim Barnett, et al. Climatic
Change, Vol. 62, No. 1 (2004).
* "Uncertainty and Markets in Water Resources," by Barton
H. Thompson, Jr. McGeorge Law Review, Vol. 36 (2005).
* "Water Markets as an Adaptive Response to the Threat of
Climate Change," by Jonathan H. Adler. Hamline Law Review, 2008.
* Water Marleets: Priming the Invisible Pump, by Terry L Anderson
and Pamela Snyder. Cato Institute, 1997
BY JONATHAN H. ADLER
Case Western Reserve University Law School
Jonathan H. Adler is professor of law and director of the Center
for Business Law and Regulation at Case Western Reserve University Law
School. Portions of this article are adapted from "Water Markets as
an Adaptive Response to the Threat of Climate Change, "forthcoming
in the Hamline Law Review.