Healing an ailing market.
Glied, Sherry
THE CURE: How Capitalism Can Save American Health Care By David
Gratzer 325 pages; New York, N.Y.: Encounter Books, 2006
After a hiatus of a dozen years, health care reform is back on the
U.S. policy agenda. Health care systems are enormous, technologically
and institutionally complex organizations that simultaneously pursue
multiple, conflicting goals. These fundamental characteristics guarantee
that there is no unique ideal configuration of a health care system.
The unequivocal impossibility of a perfect health care system helps
explain the wide and ever-changing variety of models that exist around
the developed world. In this context, the policymaking community is
particularly well-served by reasoned critiques that point out the
weaknesses of popular models and by innovative market-oriented ideas
that will push debate in new directions. David Gratzer's new book,
The Cure, is a welcome addition on both fronts.
Gratzer's book stands out from the current crop of health care
titles because of its strong comparative focus and its emphasis on the
role of system design in promoting medical progress. Gratzer, a Canadian
psychiatrist, has observed the practice of medicine in both Canada and
the United States. His book, well-written and replete with colorful
anecdotes, draws on his experiences in both countries, as well as on a
broad range of research in health care economics and health service
delivery.
STIFLED MARKET The book's principal thesis is that government
meddling--through the favorable tax treatment of employer-sponsored
insurance, promotion of health maintenance organizations, mandates on
the content of health insurance coverage, federal regulation of drugs,
and the Medicaid and Medicare public insurance programs--stifles the
operation of the health care market. Gratzer provides a measured
assessment of these governmental interventions, emphasizing their
weaknesses and the distortions they cause, but acknowledging their
contributions and strengths. For example, Gratzer nicely documents how
HMOs did succeed in lowering costs without diminishing quality, while
criticizing this approach for its paternalistic vision of health care
service delivery.
Gratzer's proposals for change similarly offer realistic
institutional options that promote market ideals. Like Milton Friedman and many others, he suggests moving from our current employer-based
system to an individual-based system. In the course of describing such a
system, however, he subtly moves from a purely voluntary, individual
health insurance market--a type of market that is conceptually elegant
but that has never existed for any length of time anywhere--to a
proposal similar to the very successful model now offered to federal
employees--one that could readily be implemented within today's
health care system. He extends this proposal to encompass the Medicare
program, but recognizes that the high risks manifested by this
population probably require additional government intervention in the
form of risk adjustment.
One disappointing element in the book is its failure to fully
confront the supply side of the health care market. In both Canada and
the United States, governments have handed over control of the health
care system to service providers, deferring to providers' technical
expertise. This abdication has allowed providers to collectively
determine how many physicians will be trained, the extent (quite limited
in both countries) to which non-physician providers will be able to
compete with physicians, and how scarce resources, such as hospital
beds, will be allocated. Predictably, providers have used this authority
to keep the supply of competitors as low as possible, to maintain their
own prices as high as possible, and to provide service of idiosyncratic quality. Patients, in both countries, have become accustomed to rude
service, long waits, and very limited information about product quality.
This acquiescence to standards that would be intolerable in any other
context is especially striking because, as Gratzer emphasizes, patients
have little incentive to consider the fiscal costs of medical care in
their decisionmaking. Patients not only pay the financial consequences
associated with insulation from medical prices, they do not even get to
enjoy expense account-quality health care as they do so!
MANAGE IF NOT CURE The title of Gratzer's book seems the mark
more of an overzealous publisher than of the more cautious author.
Thanks to advances in modern medicine well-documented here, many
diseases can be completely cured. The frequent mistake in health policy
making is to believe that the myriad malfunctions in the delivery and
distribution of medical services care that arise from the functioning of
the health care system similarly admit a cure. They do not. Too many
inconsistent imperatives make it impossible to erase all the symptoms
that afflict the health care system at once.
But perceptive counsel of the sort Gratzer offers can at least help
make it easier to endure this chronically distressing condition. The
book includes a long list of market-oriented, decentralizing,
consumer-oriented innovations that are being incorporated in a variety
of health care systems around the world. In content, if not in its
title, Gratzer's book suggests that this kind of incremental
progress is what we should be looking for in health care system reform.
Sherry Glied is professor of health policy and management in the
Mailman School of Public Health at Columbia University.