Net neutrality: a radical form of non-discrimination: regulators should not interfere with the "coming exoflood.".
Singer, Hal J.
Despite the fact that the current net neutrality debate has drawn
the attention of many academics and consultants, it is hard to find a
precise definition in the literature of what "net neutrality"
means. In layman's terms, net neutrality is about the politics of
envy: if a website cannot afford certain bells and whistles, then its
rivals should not be allowed to acquire such enhancements. In economic
terms, net neutrality represents the prohibition of any contracting for
enhanced service or guaranteed quality of service (QoS) between a
broadband service provider and an Internet content provider.
Such a prohibition would unwind existing contracts for QoS between
broadband service providers and content providers. The anticompetitive harms that would be allegedly spared from such a prohibition pale in
comparison to the efficiencies made possible by such contracting.
Accordingly, net neutrality legislation should be rejected.
CURRENT FORMS OF TIERED QoS
There are two types of customers who are already purchasing
enhanced QoS offerings from broadband service providers: end-users
(primarily enterprise customers) and content providers. Not all content
providers demand enhanced QoS. This option is demanded only by those
content providers that supply QoS-needy content. Real-time applications
represent an important type of QoS-needy content. Real-time video, Voice
over Internet Protocol, and online video game traffic cannot be
experienced properly by the end-user if it is subjected to jitter (unevenness in the rate of data packet delivery). Accordingly, real-time
content providers demand enhanced QoS. The QoS offerings aimed at
content providers are the target of net neutrality proponents.
Net neutrality proponents speak of "access tiering"--that
is, offering tiered levels of QoS at different prices--as if it is some
hypothetical strategy that will be employed at some future date to
foreclose unaffiliated content providers. In reality, tiered QoS
offerings are already here at different layers of a broadband service provider's network, and for legitimate technical and economic
reasons. Content providers are voluntarily entering into contracts with
broadband service providers presumably because content providers (and
their customers) value the service enhancements more than the prices for
the enhancements.
Enhanced QoS is not forced upon content providers as part of some
bundle of services that the providers otherwise do not want, or because
the broadband service provider has monopoly power over the supply of one
of the products in the bundle. Furthermore, broadband service providers
offer enhanced QoS at a surcharge to content providers, not because they
are trying to foreclose potential rivals in an upstream market or to
degrade the quality for content providers that decline the QoS option,
but because it is costly to offer such enhancements and because a
managed network ultimately generates benefits for Internet users.
Broadband service providers currently may offer enhanced QoS to
content providers in the form of managed hosting, local caching of
content in nearby data centers, and prioritization of traffic at the IP
packet layer. By purchasing hosting services from a broadband service
provider, a content provider can gain immediate access to the
provider's network. A content provider can also take advantage of
the provider's service level agreements (SLAS), under which the
broadband service provider is required to provide proof of a promised
level of service. Each SLA contains a technical component, which offers
several classes of service. A content provider can request that a
broadband service provider offer a fully managed hosting solution or it
can manage its own applications hosted in an Internet Data Center (IDC)
owned by a broadband service provider. For example, Qwest offers the
following commitment to customers that outsource their Web presence:
"You receive industry-leading SLAS. Many data centers are built
with high degrees of redundancy in critical systems such as power, HVAC,
fire detection and suppression and security."
Online video game providers may purchase enhanced QoS as an option
with hosting services from broadband service providers. For example,
Sony produces EverQuest, a three-dimensional, fantasy, massive
multiplayer online role-playing game (MMORPG) that requires users to pay
a recurring monthly fee. For a time, EverQuest was the most popular MM
QoS in the industry. Blizzard Entertainment produces World of Warcraft,
another MMORPG set in a fantasy environment. As of September 2006, World
of Warcraft had almost 7 million active subscriptions worldwide. In both
games, online subscribers control a character avatar "exploring the
landscape, fighting monsters and performing quests on behalf of computer
controlled characters." In addition to cash incentives for good
performance, a player is rewarded with experience that allows her
character to improve in skill and power. MMORPG games have hundreds of
thousands of users playing simultaneously. To achieve the best possible
fantasy environment for their online gaming websites, Sony and Blizzard place their servers in IDCs owned by broadband service providers around
the world. They simply cannot afford for the players of their games to
experience jitter.
AT&T hosts many of the largest online games. AT&T's
hosting service spans 30 IDCs across four continents, including
locations in Paris, Shanghai, California, and Singapore. A content
provider that purchases managed hosting service can obtain SLAs relating
to network response time, application response time, and application
performance.
As part of an enterprise hosting service, a content provider can
place its content on the broadband service provider's servers to
reach end-users faster and more reliably than from the content
provider's servers alone. For example, Verizon markets a service
called "Application Acceleration" on its website, which offers
content providers "a high-performance web application delivery
platform so [their] distant end-users get the same level of performance
[their[ local users enjoy." AT&T markets a similar service
under the name "Intelligent Content Distribution Service." It
bears emphasis that this form of QoS (along with other forms) may be
supplied by third parties in addition to broadband service providers.
For example, Akamai Technologies provides a similar content-acceleration
service by caching content closer to the end-user for over 2,000
customers. One measure of the size of the market for acceleration
services is Akamai's revenues, which reached $100 million in the
second quarter of 2006. The fact that Akamai offers enhanced QoS at a
surcharge to content providers suggests that the same conduct by a
broadband service provider is based on justifiable business practices
that could be found in what net neutrality proponents believe are
otherwise competitive markets.
NET NEUTRALITY LEGISLATION
The current legislative proposals, if adopted, would impose all
sorts of "duties" on broadband providers. One duty of a
broadband service provider would be a non-discrimination requirement to
offer the same quality of service to all content providers. Effectively,
a broadband service provider would be able to offer enhanced QoS to a
given content provider, but flit did so, it would have to offer the same
level of quality to all content providers free of charge. The apparent
motivation for such a restriction is to stymie efforts by any content
provider to secure enhanced QoS from broadband providers, and instead to
force all contracting for QoS to occur between broadband providers and
end-users. (To appreciate the potential administrative costs associated
with such contracting, imagine the nightmare that credit card companies
would face if the fees were negotiated individually with millions of
diners rather than with thousands of restaurants!) These bills generally
do not distinguish between broadband services offered by broadband
service providers versus those offered by backbone networks, and they
would presumably impose their net neutrality restrictions on both types
of networks.
What do these duties mean in practical terms? Suppose that AT&T
enters into a contract with Sony (which it has at certain levels of its
network) in which Sony pays AT&T a fee to guarantee that Sony's
online gaming customers can enjoy their online games in real time
without any disruptions. Now suppose that Congress passes this version
of net neutrality. AT&T must offer the same level of quality to all
of Sony's online gaming rivals free of charge. At that moment, Sony
would insist that its contract with AT&T be nullified. Why should
Sony have to pay for something that all its online gaming rivals get for
free?
BORROWING FROM CABLE In the words of Professor Jon Peha of Carnegie
Mellon, a more "balanced" non-discrimination provision would
allow a broadband service provider to enter into a contract with a
content provider for enhanced QoS at some surcharge, but that broadband
service provider would then be forced to offer that same contract to all
content providers. Assuming such regulation is necessary (and that is a
critical assumption), this is much closer to the idea of
nondiscrimination that is embodied in the program carriage rules in the
Cable Act. In particular, the Cable Act seeks to protect unaffiliated
video programmers or content providers by prohibiting a cable operator
from
* discriminating against video programmers on the basis of
affiliation in the selection, terms, or conditions for carriage of
video,
* conditioning carriage on equity, and
* conditioning carriage on exclusivity.
The Cable Act's non-discrimination template should not be
applied to the Internet for several reasons. First, those
non-discrimination provisions and the program access rules were crafted
when, for most households, cable television was the only provider of
multi-channel video programming, and slightly more than half of all
cable programming services were vertically integrated with cable
operators. This does not accurately characterize the current state of
competition in the broadband market. According to the Federal
Communications Commission, as of June 2006, 95.6 percent of U.S. ZIP
codes were served by two or more broadband service providers (including
satellite broadband), and 87.4 percent of U.S. ZIP codes were served by
three or more broadband service providers (including satellite
broadband). The second statistic implies that residents living in 87.4
percent of U.S. ZIP codes have a choice between a cable modern provider
and a DSL provider.
Second, the unique relationship between an unaffiliated Internet
content provider and a broadband service provider is not conducive to
foreclosure strategies. With a few exceptions, Internet content is not
acquired by broadband service providers at a certain cost per subscriber
per month, as is the case with traditional video programming. Setting
aside the seldom-used leased access rules, unaffiliated video content
providers cannot reach a video distributor's customers unless the
distributor has acquired the content from the provider. By contrast,
unaffiliated Internet content providers do not need to reach an
agreement with a broadband service provider to reach that
provider's broadband customers. Hence, broadband service providers
and unaffiliated content providers are not likely to get into a carriage
dispute arising over price or affiliation. Although such disputes are
common in the video programming industry and Congress has given the FCC powers to prevent discriminatory practices, because Internet content
providers do not depend on broadband service providers to reach
end-users in the same way that video programmers depend on cable or
Direct Broadcast Satellite (DBS) providers, video programming is the
wrong framework for analyzing discriminatory strategies in Internet
content markets.
Third, the program carriage and access rules were adopted to
address an actual proven pattern of historic discrimination by cable
operators. Given the limited record here, the program access template is
really the opposite of what net neutrality advocates want--namely,
protections against possible abuses that have yet to materialize.
Fourth, there are technological issues relating to some services,
such as high-definition television (HDTV), that could constrain a
broadband service provider's ability to offer enhanced QoS on the
same terms to a second or third content provider. In particular, the
current bandwidth of today's broadband networks may not be capable
of accommodating multiple HDTV signals.
With these four caveats in mind, even a sensible non-discrimination
rule of the kind advocated by Professor Peha may not be needed and may
not be feasible.
It seems that net neutrality advocates like the idea of using the
cable non-discrimination rules as a template for net neutrality. In a
November 16, 2006 blog post, Art Brodsky of Public Knowledge wrote:
"In the past, we have said that a model for Net Neutrality
regulation could be the program-access rules, which guarantee access to
most of the content on cable systems." Unfortunately, Mr. Brodsky
focused on the protections for rival video distributors like DBS
providers, while the net neutrality debate focuses on trying to find
protections for unaffiliated content providers. That is, a DBS provider
is a downstream rival of a cable television provider, while an Internet
content provider is an upstream supplier for a broadband service
provider. But his intentions were pure. Thus, notwithstanding the four
caveats listed above, the non-discrimination protections for upstream
suppliers--carriage conditions cannot be based on affiliation, and
carriage cannot be conditioned on equity or exclusivity--are more
relevant to the net neutrality debate.
How would the program carriage rules from the Cable Act be
rewritten for the Internet? The first challenge is that broadband
service providers, unlike cable television providers in the early 1990s,
are not trying to withhold "carriage" or access to their
customers from content providers--instead, they want compensation for
offering enhanced QoS to a select group of content providers (namely,
those who offer real-time applications). Access to the broadband service
provider's customers is already granted. Note that the protections
for unaffiliated programmers in the Cable Act would not prevent a cable
operator and a video programmer from striking a carriage deal at a
positive price. Rather, they prevent a cable provider from demanding
exclusivity or equity as a condition of carriage, or conditioning
carriage on the basis of affiliation. Applied to Internet content, the
non-discrimination provisions--if necessary in the first place--would
read something like this: "A broadband access provider cannot
condition the price of enhanced QoS on the affiliation of the content
provider. Nor can it condition the price of enhanced QoS on exclusivity
or equity."
Given the lack of monopoly power in all but a handful of local
access markets, the lack of leverage a broadband service provider wields
over a content provider, the lack of a proven record of discrimination,
and given certain technological constraints relating to HDTV, it is
unlikely that the major broadband service providers would be willing to
embrace the nondiscrimination conditions from the Cable Act. They simply
want compensation for providing a service (enhanced QoS) that has a
positive marginal cost. In addition, they want to avoid having to use
only expanded physical infrastructure to meet what Bret Swanson in the
Wall Street Journal recently called the "coming exaflood" of
bandwidth-intensive applications, including video sharing, medical
imaging, and digital surveillance. Because of this dilemma, broadband
service providers, and the analysts who cover them, are genuinely
worried about avoiding a traffic jam on the Internet that threatens to
undermine everyone's Internet experience.
As Richard Clarke, the director of economic analysis at AT&T,
has demonstrated, meeting that demand with a fully neutral network would
be simply unaffordable to customers. In particular, he estimates that to
provide sufficient capacity to accommodate the current typical Internet
usage pattern in an unmanaged network, the cost per customer could reach
$47 per month. To provide sufficient capacity to accommodate expected
growth in traditional Internet data services as well as use of Internet
connections for bandwidth-intensive applications equivalent to just two
simultaneous standard definition television channels per home, Clarke
estimates that the cost per customer of an unmanaged network could reach
$140 per month for Internet service only (not including the cost for
video content). Finally, if customers use the equivalent of viewing two
simultaneous HDTV channels, Clarke estimates that the cost per customer
of an unmanaged network could reach $466 per month.
What can be said is that the net neutrality proposals, if amended
along the lines described here, would not be rejected out of hand by
economists from every corner of the political spectrum. There are
several papers in the economic literature that examine the conditions
under which a firm should be compelled to treat unaffiliated upstream
providers the same as they treat their affiliated upstream providers.
However, there does not appear to be one economic paper that examines
the conditions under which two parties should be prevented from
voluntarily contracting for a service at a positive price.
UNINTENDED CONSEQUENCES In an article in the Journal on
Telecommunications and High Technology Law that I co-authored with
Robert Litan of the Brookings Institution, I examined several possible
outcomes that can emerge given this draconian "non-discrimination" provision embodied in the current net
neutrality legislation. Two of the most likely outcomes are:
* no contracting for QoS will occur at the regulated price of zero,
or
* broadband service providers would offer a blended quality of
service offering that is "too high" for some applications and
"too low" for others.
Concerning the first outcome, the classic shut-down decision in
economics is to withdraw from supplying a service if the price is less
than the average variable cost of supplying that service. As explained
above, the average variable cost of providing QoS is the opportunity
cost of carrying a given traffic stream and thus exceeds zero. Hence, it
is reasonable to assume that a broadband service provider would withdraw
its QoS offering from the market entirely to comply with the
non-discrimination provision. In the other scenario, garners and other
users who need very high QoS might not have the QoS necessary to make
paying for a gaming site worthwhile. This in turn could cause content
providers to reduce their investment in new QoS-needy content. In
addition, content providers who do not require higher QoS, which is the
majority of sites out there right now, would then be forced to pay the
increased price for blended quality of service.
To make this point concrete, consider a content provider that
currently purchases hosting service from a broadband service provider
for $100 per month but declines the QoS option, which is priced at an
additional $50 per month. Assume that 10 percent of the broadband
service provider's customers chose the bundled hosting offering
(hosting plus QoS) for $150 before the imposition of net neutrality. The
average price per customer is thus $105. Under a net neutrality regime,
the price of the QoS option would be set to zero (by law) and the price
of hosting service would increase to $105 if the broadband service
provider sought to preserve the average revenue per customer. Hence, the
content provider that originally opted against QoS now incurs an
additional charge of $5 per month for blended QoS. Faced with this
higher incremental cost, the content provider would likely try to pass
on a portion of this cost increase to its customers. These outcomes
would be harmful to Internet users, as they would force everyone to pay
a price that does not correspond with the value he attaches to the
services, which will reduce output and reduce surplus overall.
THE ANTICOMPETITIVE ARGUMENTS
The merits of the anticompetitive arguments advanced by proponents
of net neutrality go something like this: Ira broadband service provider
is allowed to charge a fee to Sony or Blizzard for providing enhanced
QoS, then upstart gaming providers who lack the resources of Sony would
not be able to compete effectively in the market for online gaming.
Consumers would be worse off given the barriers to entry created by the
surcharge. This argument appears to fall under the "Covet Thy
Neighbor" ethic (which likely explains the vast majority of
regulatory proposals in Washington)--my rival should be prohibited from
investing $2 billion in developing a major product innovation because I
cannot do likewise.
DEFINING THE MARKET While that example may not evoke much sympathy,
try this one, which is admittedly harder: Suppose that Comcast creates
its own gaming website. If Comcast is allowed to charge a fee for
enhanced QoS to unaffiliated gamers, then Comcast will set that fee
excessively high so as to prevent rival garners from competing with its
own gaming website. Could such a strategy "foreclose" the
upstart content provider--that is, could it cause the upstart content
provider to lose out on some economies of scale or, in the worst case,
exit the industry entirely? To answer that question, one must first
define what antitrust economics calls the "relevant geographic
market."
Vertical foreclosure theories depend critically on the relevant
geographic market. A local downstream broadband service
provider--whether it is a cable television operator or a cable modern
provider--lacks the ability to foreclose an upstream content provider
that generates content with nationwide appeal. Proponents of net
neutrality like to cite the combined share of all DSL and cable modern
providers nationwide (98 percent) to suggest incorrectly that the market
share is extremely high--that is, to suggest that upstart content
providers are somehow beholden to DSL and cable modern providers. But
this statistic has no meaning in this context. A content provider is not
wing for the eyeballs in one particular locality that is served by both
a cable modern provider and a DSL provider (whose shares sum to 98
percent). Thus, summing their shares is nonsensical.
The oft-repeated 98 percent figure assumes incorrectly that the
relevant geographic market to assess the alleged anticompetitive effects
from an access tiering is the local market- that is, it assumes that a
content provider is offering content that is particular to a given
locality and therefore requires access to a broadband service
provider's subscribers in a given locality. But Internet content is
not local. At a minimum, it is national, and more likely it is
international. The vast majority of Internet content appeals to all U.S.
residents, not just the residents of a particular locality. There is
next to nothing on YouTube.com or Google.com or ESPN.com that is
specific to a particular U.S. city. That is precisely why
anticompetitive refusals to deal are possible in video markets, where
some content such as local broadcast television news and regional sports
are in fact local (and those content providers depend on a single cable
provider), but impossible in Internet markets.
Will the unaffiliated garner be prevented from getting its legs
underneath it as a result of Comcast's demand for a QoS surcharge?
Stated differently, does Comcast have the ability to foreclose upstart
garners? The answer is an unequivocal no. First, the garner will still
have access to Comcast's subscribers, albeit without enhanced QoS.
Second, the gamer still can strike deals for enhanced QoS with other
broadband service providers. Because Comcast, the largest broadband
service provider in the United States, controls access to only about 23
percent of all broadband subscribers, it lacks the ability to induce the
upstart gamer from exiting the industry or even operating at an
inefficient scale. As Table 1 shows, the next largest providers are
AT&T and Verizon, each with roughly 14 percent of the U.S. market.
Even if Comcast refuses to sell its enhanced QoS, the upstart gamer
is free to enter into contracts for enhanced QoS with other broadband
service providers that collectively control access to the remaining 77
percent of all U.S. broadband subscribers. To the extent that the
Internet content market is international, Comcast's foreclosure
share (assuming hypothetically that Comcast decided to prevent access to
the content provider entirely) is even smaller.
In a recent Journal of Telecommunications and High Technology
article, Barbara van Schewick cites my 2001 Journal of Industrial
Economics article with Dan Rubinfeld in support for her call to prohibit
access tiering. But this application of the theory of vertical
foreclosure assumes incorrectly that a content provider is offering
content that is particular to a given locality and there fore requires
access to a single broadband provider's subscribers. As I explained
above, the vast majority of Internet content appeals to all U.S.
residents, not just the residents of a particular locality. This is
precisely why anticompetitive refusals to deal are possible in video
markets, where some content (e.g., local broadcast television news,
regional sports) is local, but are unlikely in Internet markets.
Finally, most vertical foreclosure theories require the existence
of economies of scale. Without economies of scale, the rival cannot be
harmed as a result of its being foreclosed from a certain segment of the
market. The minimum efficient scale of an Internet content provider is
likely very low, and whatever foreclosure there is would not be enough
to prevent the content provider from reaching its minimum efficient
scale. Thus, the anticompetitive arguments in support of net neutrality
do not have merit.
CONCLUSION
Net neutrality in its current form will jeopardize very large
consumer benefits made possible by contracting for enhanced QoS, but it
will spare us no anticompetitive harm. For that reason, net neutrality
regulation should be rejected. Assuming one could demonstrate monopoly
power in the access market, a more sensible nondiscrimination rule would
be to require that carriers charge different content providers the same
rate for any given enhancement of QoS, not to prevent any charges for
enhanced QoS whatsoever. But it is not clear that even a reasonable
nondiscrimination rule is required for Internet services, given the fact
that broadband service providers acting unilaterally lack the ability to
foreclose content providers.
With the advent of streaming video and other bandwidth-intensive
applications, the demand for bandwidth is projected to overtake the
existing supply quickly. Regulators and legislators should not interfere
with a broadband service provider's ability to manage this
"coming exaflood" with intelligent networks. At best, the
price of Internet service will skyrocket if broadband service providers
can meet the coming traffic using only expanded infrastructure. At
worst, the Internet experience for all users will deteriorate. Given the
tremendous uncertainty over the future of the Internet and the need to
encourage innovation and investment, it seems dangerous to interfere
with heavy-handed regulation at this juncture.
Readings
* "A Consumer-Welfare Approach to Network Neutrality Regulation of the Internet," by J. Gregory Sidak. Journal of
Competition Law & Economics, Vol. 2, No. 3 (2006).
* "Costs of Neutral/Unmanaged IP Networks," by Richard N.
Clarke. Downloaded from SSRN, Sept. 8, 2006.
* "The Benefits and Risks of Mandating Network Neutrality, and
the Quest for a Balanced Policy," by Jon M. Peha.
Telecommunications Policy Research Conference, Sept. 2006.
* "The Economics of Product-Line Restrictions with an
Application to the Network Neutrality Debate," by Benjamin E.
Hermalin and Michael L. Katz. Working paper, Sept. 2006.
* "The Myth of Network Neutrality and What We Should Do About
It," by Robert W. Hahn and Robert E. Litan. AEI-Brookings Joint
Center Working Paper No. RP06-33 (Nov. 2006).
"The Economics of 'Wireless Net Neutrality',"
by Robert W. Hahn, Robert E. Litan, and Hal J. Singer. Journal of
Competition, Law and Economics, forthcoming 2007.
* "Towards an Economic Framework for Network Neutrality
Regulation," by Barbara van Schewick. Journal on Telecommunications
and High Technology Law, Vol. 5 (2007).
* "Unintended Consequences of Net Neutrality Regulation,"
by Robert E. Litan and Hal J. Singer. Journal on Telecommunications and
High Technology Law, forthcoming.
* "Wireless Net Neutrality: Cellular Carterfone on Mobile
Networks," by Tim Wu. New America Foundation Wireless Future
Program Working Paper No. 17 (Feb. 2005).
Hal J. Singer is cofounder and president of Criterion Economics.
Table 1
The Broadband Market
2006 year-end broadband subscriber numbers and
nationwide market share
Provider Subscribers (millions) Market Share
Comcast Cable 10.954 22%
Verizon 7.000 14%
AT&T 6.900 14%
Time Warner Cable 6.312 13%
Cox Cable 3.357 7%
Charter Cable 2.530 5%
Cablevision 2.064 4%
Qwest 2.000 4%
Insight Cable 0.613 1%
Others 8.718 NA
Total 50.448
SOURCES: FCC, "High-Speed Services for Interned Access Status as
of June 30, 2006" at tbl.2 (2007); company websites.