Remembering the man behind rational expectations: John Muth (1930-2005).
Brannon, Ike
FEW IDEAS HAVE HAD AS MUCH OF AN effect on the science of economics
as the concept of rational expectations. The idea is deceivingly simple:
Buyers and sellers who need to guess future prices do not merely assume
that they will be the same as previous prices. Instead, they use all
available information to make an educated guess as to what prices will
be--at least when it is worth their while to do so. What is more, the
educated guess will, on average, be correct. People will not
consistently make mistakes when it comes to prognosticating future
prices.
This elementary notion, first formulated by the economist John
Muth, ultimately upended four decades of economic research on
macroeconomics and monetary policy, utterly discrediting the notion that
governments can simply fiddle with the money supply and inflation rate
to achieve the desired rate of unemployment. New Fed chairman Ben
Bernanke's stated desire to target inflation to between one and two
percent, a policy that seems quite sensible today, would have sounded
foolish only 30 years ago.
Eventually, the bulk of what came to be considered as mainstream
"Keynesian" economics, with its emphasis on the need for
governments to play an active role in the economy, was jettisoned.
Robert Lucas, the economist who popularized the idea of rational
expectations, received the Nobel Prize for his efforts.
Despite the impact of Muth's idea, the honor and glory
ultimately accorded by the profession for this titanic idea skipped by
him with nary a nod in his direction. John Muth passed away last October
25th at the age of 75, and if the lack of honor and glory bothered him,
he never let on. Muth, a shy and socially awkward man, would have found
the attention and fuss that goes with a Nobel Prize pure torture.
THE LIFE OF JOHN MUTH
Muth grew up in the Midwest, with his family eventually settling in
St. Louis. He attended Washington University in St. Louis, where he
studied industrial engineering, and in 1952 he went to Carnegie Tech in
Pittsburgh to study mathematical economics. At the time, Carnegie Tech
was the place to be for young academics studying quantitative economics.
Future Nobel laureates Herb Simon, Merton Miller, and Franco Modigliani
were on the faculty, and John Nash, the game theorist who won the prize
in 1984 and whose life story was the subject of the movie A Beautiful
Mind, had finished his undergraduate degree a couple years earlier.
Future Nobel winners Ed Prescott and Robert Lucas arrived later in
Muth's tenure there.
Muth excelled at Carnegie; Modigliani, his adviser, called him
"a very original and talented man." Modigliani, with whom Muth
did a good bit of his research, also commented upon Muth's
eccentricity, remarking that "he seemed to take pains to appear as
an oddball." Muth quickly went from graduate student to professor
before taking the Ph.D., and it was there that he conceived of and
published his research on rational expectations.
The first paper he published in this area, entitled "Rational
Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements," appeared in
Econometrica in 1961. The paper was little noted at the time of its
release, and one of the referees fought against its publication,
claiming it was of little consequence. A companion piece appeared in The
Journal of the American Statistical Association around the same time
It was not until a decade after publication that other economists
began to recognize the importance of Muth's idea, after it was
incorporated into a paper by Bob Lucas and Leonard Rapping. By that
time, Muth had left Carnegie, first to Michigan State and then to
Indiana University.
Much like Nash, who abandoned his work on game theory shortly after
graduation after its lack of acclaim forced him to "settle"
for a job at MIT, Muth soon abandoned work on rational expectations. He
once confided that after his Econometrica article came out, he had
assumed that he would be able to go anywhere he wanted, but no one paid
it much attention. He could not persuade any journal to publish a third
article on the subject and his colleagues at the time did not muster a
lot of enthusiasm for the idea. Herb Simon proffered an alternative to
Muth's thesis that Simon called "bounded rationality,"
which holds that people generally have to sort through too much
information to make a "perfect" choice in the marketplace.
Instead, they wait until they see a deal that they believe is good
enough. Simon's work won him the Nobel in 1978, just as rational
expectations was beginning to catch on.
While Simon got the award, Muth got nothing. As Lucas commented in
Arjo Klamer's 1984 book Conversations with Economists, "It
must be quite an experience to write papers that radical and have people
just pat you on the head and say 'That's interesting' and
nothing happens."
THE RATIONAL EXPECTATIONS REVOLUTION
Economics as a discipline experienced a crisis during the Great
Depression, as few economists could come up with a decent explanation
for why the Depression occurred. Then in 1936 John Maynard Keynes, in
The General Theory of Income and Employment, took a radical approach
that eventually swept the profession. Keynes said that one key reason
why the Depression lingered was that people are not smart enough to
figure out price changes, and hence they make all kinds of irrational
decisions. For instance, prices fell precipitously during the 1930s;
Keynes hypothesized that because people did not recognize that prices
fell, they were unwilling to take wage cuts that would have preserved
their jobs and left them just as materially well off as they were
before. As a result, wages would not fall and there would be
unemployment.
Keynes's ideas were acclaimed not only as the answer to the
cause of the Great Depression but also as a justifica-tion for
government action to fix the economy. Soon, his ideas swept the
profession and the bulk of research in macroeconomics hewed to his
framework. However, the Keynesian model was fraught with problems:
First, there is the minor flaw that wages were not that rigid downward.
In fact, wages fell by nearly a third in the early 1930s. (Facts were
never Keynes' strong suit.)
Second, and ultimately more important, Keynes's ideas
represented a significant break with the past by essentially throwing
out the central tenet of economic rationality. The notion that
individuals might consistently make mistakes in the marketplace goes
against one of the main principles of the modern neoclassical model. It
was his theories that essentially cleaved the discipline into
microeconomics and macroeconomics.
But the most important problem with the Keynesian model is that it
eventually ceased to explain the economic world. For instance, the high
inflation and high unemployment that characterized much of the 1970s
simply could not exist concomitantly in Keynes's framework.
Keynesian economists believed that increases in inflation had to be
accompanied by decreases in unemployment, an idea enshrined in the
Phillips Curve.
Muth, in his seminal articles, questioned the assumptions behind
the Keynesian model well before it stopped working. In his papers, he
argued that people did not consistently make economic mistakes in the
market, and that they used all information available to understand the
economic situation at hand. In other words, he defended the idea of
rationality when it needed a defender.
The context in which he explained his idea was the hog market: For
years, people thought the hog market was rife with wild fluctuations in
price and quantity as people reacted poorly to price changes. For
instance, if hog prices were low in a given year, people would react by
not raising as many hogs the next year, pushing prices higher. Then,
seeing the higher prices, farmers would raise a lot of hogs, pushing
prices lower the following year. The idea was that farmers would never
catch on to such a cycle because they were too busy looking only at the
current prices.
Rational expectations said this was nonsense; farmers cannot
consistently make such mistakes or they would be out of business. If hog
prices are low this year, farmers will not automatically cut back on
production today; they will look at the factors that led to low hog
prices today and determine whether it is likely to happen next season as
well. No farmer in his right mind will assume that if hog prices are low
today, they will be low tomorrow as well. Using data on hog markets,
Muth found no evidence of prices oscillating from year to year. Rational
expectations explained this market quite well.
SLOW ACCEPTANCE Donald McCloskey, in his path-breaking book The
Rhetoric of Economics, argues that Muth's idea did not become
popular earlier because his paper was inaccessible. The first problem
was simply that the paper was poorly written, McCloskey contends. To
demonstrate this fact, McCloskey "translates" paragraphs of
Muth's verbiage into a more sensible prose. There is no denying
that the paper is a difficult read; the writing is very dense in places
and, combined with its unorthodox ideas, only a dedicated reader can
hope to get the thrust of the argument.
The other point made by McCloskey and others is that the technical
aspects of the paper were simply too far ahead of the rest of the
profession. A non-economist picking up an academic journal of economics
today is invariably struck by the sophisticated math contained within.
Back in 1960, however, Muth was one of the few economists comfortable
with such a technical approach. In fact, it can be suggested that the
paper contributed to the science not only with its ideas but also with
its mathematical sophistication.
But perhaps the main reason for the paper not catching on was
merely because of had timing. When the idea came out, Muth was thinking
about microeconomic markets, like the infamous hog market. The idea of
rational expectations really took off when the Keynesian model failed
and a vacuum arose in macroeconomics. Muth probably would never have
come up with applying rational expectations to macroeconomics; he never
considered himself a true economist and scarcely thought about
macroeconomic problems. In fact, when Robert Lucas first suggested the
idea to him, Muth confessed that he was skeptical and told Lucas as
much, although he did work with him on the idea. When Muth did his
research in rational expectations, no one was questioning the Keynesian
model that seemed to be working so well.
GLORY AND POLITICS
One argument for giving the Nobel Prize for the development of
rational expectations to Robert Lucas rather than John Muth is that
while Muth came up with the idea, Lucas was the one who popularized it
and brought it to the forefront of economic research. Notre Dame
economist Chris Waller echoes the sentiments of many macroeconomists by
insisting that because Lucas made it popular, he deserves the award. In
other words, quoting Principal Skinner from The Simpsons, a good
scientist is half B.F. Skinner and half ET. Barnum.
The other argument on behalf of Lucas receiving the award is that
it was he who thought to apply the idea to macroeconomics, where it is
currently all the rage. As the Nobel committee stated when they made the
award to Lucas,
John Muth (1961) was the first to formulate the rational
expectations hypothesis in a precise way. He used it in a study of
the classic cobweb phenomenon. Muth's analysis was restricted to a
single market in partial equilibrium. The importance of the
rational expectations hypothesis became apparent when Lucas
extended the hypothesis to macroeconomic models and to the
analysis of economic policy.
The problem with this explanation is that despite its popularity in
macroeconomics, the rational expectations model performs rather poorly
when used to explain the overall economy. Most of the macroeconomic
models used by top economists and forecasting firms are still based on a
Keynesian perspective of the economy. Wall Street, too, is to some
degree still under the Keynesian sway; the mere fact that the latest Fed
increase in interest rates was perceived by the markets as a threat to
economic growth is symptomatic of a Keynesian mindset. Markets are not
wedded to philosophies; they merely stick with what is reliable. Thus
far, we are still not sure why changes in the money supply matter in a
world where everyone in the market fully anticipates every action by the
Federal Reserve.
While it is not as revolutionary in the context of microeconomics,
the concept of rational expectations reigns supreme when trying to
understand individual markets like financial or commodities markets,
which is where Muth originally applied the notion.
Being ahead of the curve has been the defining characteristic of
Muth's career. For instance, he did seminal work in the field of
operations management and spent much of the 1970s pondering artificial
intelligence, another topic he abandoned before it became a
"hot" area of research. Muth's work on non-convex cost
curves at the end of his career generated some attention from economists
as well. His goal with this research, he once confided to a friend, was
to undermine microeconomic theory just as thoroughly as rational
expectations undermined macroeconomic theory.
HOOSIER COUNTRY
Muth taught at Indiana University's Kelley School of Business while I was earning a Ph.D. in economics across campus at the College of
Arts and Sciences. When I arrived at Indiana in the late 1980s, the idea
of rational expectations was in full bloom, and my year studying
macroeconomics was virtually a paean to him and his radical idea. We
spent weeks digesting his papers and asking ourselves
"WWMT?"--"What would Muth think?" about this idea or
that. Despite the primacy of his work, not a single student in the class
knew that Muth was on our campus until the semester was over. By that
time, he had drifted away from his flirtation with economic theory and
taught operations management.
After that first year, my roommate, Mike Gorman (now a professor at
the University of Dayton and an occasional contributor to these pages)
decided to take a class from Muth, in part because he had an interest in
Muth's research area and in part because he wanted to meet this
mythic figure. Muth did not disappoint; his lectures touched on a wide
variety of topics, and for each one he was able to hold forth on an
astounding amount of the literature and recent work. The seemingly
chaotic, research-oriented approach of his class infuriated his MBA
students--who once delivered a petition demanding his removal from the
classroom--but captivated his doctoral students, who were uncommonly
loyal to him. Muth was not the guy who had tons of contacts and could
help his students on the job market, but he would read anyone's
research and give copious feedback.
Shortly after Muth's former student (and subsequent colleague)
Ed Prescott was awarded the Nobel Prize in 2004, I chatted with him
after a talk Prescott gave in Washington, D.C. I asked him about Muth
and he reminisced about his first year at Carnegie, when he took a
two-semester sequence in dynamic analysis--the first semester taught by
a newly arrived Lucas, the second semester taught by Muth. Prescott
recalled that Lucas wasn't quite comfortable with the subject
material and that he was able to catch Lucas on a couple of errors. When
the second semester began and Muth showed up, he told me he realized
from day one that neither he nor anyone else on the planet was in a
position to correct anything Muth did on the subject.
Muth seemed content at Bloomington, ensconced in a small but
sophisticated, urbane community with ample diversions that afforded him
his privacy. He was a familiar face at the local watering holes (his
choice of haunt determined by the various weekly specials of his
favorite bars) and was happy to talk shop with any of his students who
encountered him on his barstool. If being at a "second-tier"
school rather than at an Ivy League institution bothered him, he never
let on. The mere fact that he helped begin more than one vitally
important research area but moved on before the field came to fruition
speaks volumes about the man; he was intellectually curious and was more
interested in staving off boredom than in professional or academic
glory.
Muth's colleagues generally liked him, although the
administration, always keen to please the MBA students, sometimes
slighted him. One year a friend of mine, a hotshot assistant professor,
received a larger raise than Muth, who was told that the new kid's
work seemed more relevant than what Muth had been doing of late. Muth
went to the Social Science Citation Index and returned to the dean,
handing him a list showing that Muth's work was cited more times
than any other economist for the most recent year available, numbering
in the thousands. (My friend looked himself up in the same index: he had
been cited all of 12 times, and a majority of those were times that he
was citing his own work.)
To be fair, the administrator who awarded the low raise was the
same one who received the aforementioned petition from MBA students
demanding Muth's removal from the classroom, which he vigorously
ripped up in front of them. "All of you should be giving him your
signing bonus for your first job for what he's done for this
school's reputation," he admonished them. A friend of mine who
happened to be part of the petition delegation asked me what the dean
was referring to. After I had explained to him Muth's
contributions, my friend asked plaintively, "Why on earth
don't they let us know about this?" A good question indeed.
It is understandable how Muth could have gotten under the skin of a
dean--he did not play politics. He once told me about showing up for a
ceremony for the opening of a new building on campus. Asked to say a few
words, he merely remarked that having a nice campus is undoubtedly
socially unproductive, as it encourages students to spend more time in
school rather than working. He laughed at his remembrance of the
administrator in charge turning beet red from his remarks.
MY DATE WITH JACK
Five years after I finished my Ph.D., I returned to Indiana on a
sabbatical and found myself teaching a summer finance course to make a
few dollars. The capstone of the class was a complex case study that was
amazingly elegant and instructive, and its author was none other than
John Muth, who had by that time retired to Key West, but spent summers
in Bloomington to avoid the worst of the Florida weather. He did the
case studies as a favor to a close friend and former student, Jim
Patterson, who was in charge of the department. As the semester
progressed and I got to see snippets of his handiwork, I asked the
department chair to arrange for me to meet Muth, ostensibly to talk
about the case study. Muth readily agreed and we met for lunch at a
nearby bar.
By the time I arrived at the restaurant, Muth had taken a table and
was working on his second beer. He was friendly but plainly unused to
talking about himself or revisiting his past jobs. He was a shy,
self-conscious man, short, balding, and heavyset with a bit of a
hunchback, and he rarely made eye contact. After a few minutes of
awkwardness, I retreated into prodding him to talk about the idea that
captivated him at the time, nonconvex cost curves. The notion is, like
rational expectations, deceivingly simple: Standard economic theory
holds that, in the short run, firms cannot add plant and equipment,
i.e., capital, to expand output, and thus must hire more workers to
produce more. Muth argued that firms can actually do very little of
this; most production lines, he reasoned, required a certain number of
workers to be present before the lines could produce anything, and that
any workers added above the minimum number contributed very little in
terms of extra output. In other words, decreasing marginal cost curves,
a staple of micro theory, do not apply to most industries.
After a few minutes our lunch arrived, and Muth's responses to
my questions began to seem a bit bizarre. I was not sure if he was
drunk, or just irritated with me, or not in a good mood. He had barely
touched his barbeque sandwich, so I relented and kept quiet for a couple
of minutes while Muth stared silently at his food. Embarrassed by the
silence, I asked him a question about rational expectations, to which he
looked straight at me, opened his mouth, and passed out face-first into
his barbeque sandwich.
I reached across the table and pulled up his head and yelled for
the bartender to call an ambulance. His breath was shallow and rapid,
and the color had left his face. In short order, a nurse who happened to
be dining in the restaurant came over and managed to revive him. As soon
as he could process what had happened, he became very embarrassed at
having become a spectacle in the restaurant. I walked along the
stretcher as they carried him to the ambulance, and he apologized to me
for the incident and promised to buy me lunch when he got out of the
hospital.
Muth was discharged the next day, his fainting spell attributed to
a change in blood pressure medication, and he soon made good on his
promise. We met at my office and walked to Nick's, a legendary bar
in Bloomington. As we walked in the door, a chorus of "Jack"
(his preferred moniker) came from the regulars at the bar--it was his
favorite haunt and he was not above holding office hours there in his
teaching days. As soon as we sat down, a waitress plopped down a
Budweiser--in a can--in front of him, to which he merely replied,
"Don't let me get empty, Carol."
After we had a few beers, he began to warm up a bit, and we talked
about his career. He dismissed my suggestion that he still had a chance
to win the Nobel, and applauded Bob Lucas's award. He said he did
not regret giving up on the topic of rational expectations--he had other
fish to fry, he said. He was uncommonly modest for an academic,
dismissing the rumor circulating among graduate students in the business
school that he had a host of unpublished papers in his files, and he
told some stories about his days at Carnegie Tech. Muth may have been a
socially awkward person but he enjoyed life--in his younger days, he
liked to ski and sail, and played the cello as well.
After an hour or so, a couple of graduate students from the
computer science department came by to introduce themselves and buy him
a beer, telling him they found his work in whatever was their arcane
field to be brilliant. Muth blushed with pride and invited them to join
our table. The four of us shared a pitcher of beer while the three of
them talked about new programming languages, to which I could only
listen dumbfounded. For the only time in our acquaintance, I saw John
Muth at ease in the world.
Ike Brannon
Office of Sen. Orrin Hatch
Ike Brannon is an economist who works for the U.S. Congress.