The value of knowing: did mandatory disclosure requirements enhance stock prices?
Greenstone, Michael ; Oyer, Paul ; Vissing-Jorgensen, Annette 等
Since the passage of the Securities Act of 1933 and the Securities
Exchange Act of 1934, the federal government has actively regulated U.S.
equity markets. The centerpiece of those efforts is the mandated
disclosure of financial information.
Previous research provides mixed evidence on the impact of
mandatory disclosure. Theoretical models suggest that those laws can be
beneficial when the costs of writing or enforcing private contracts that
bind managers to maximize shareholder value are sufficiently high.
Although the first empirical evaluations of mandatory disclosure laws
were published four decades ago, the extensive subsequent literature has
failed to reach a consensus. The absence of convincing evidence has led
some legal scholars to recommend significant modification or repeal of
the statutes that regulate U.S. securities markets, including the
mandatory disclosure requirements.
This article presents new evidence on the impacts of mandatory
disclosure laws by analyzing the effect of the 1964 Securities Acts
Amendments on stock returns and operating performance of firms newly
affected by this legislation. With the exception of the Sarbanes-Oxley
Act of 2002, the 1964 Amendments are the last major mandatory disclosure
regulations applied to U.S. equity markets. They extended the disclosure
requirements that have applied to firms traded on exchanges, such as the
New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) and the American Stock Exchange (AMEX),
since 1934 to firms traded "over-the-counter" (OTC) that
exceeded asset and shareholder floors.
Specifically, covered OTC firms were required to: (1) register with
the Securities and Exchange Commission; (2) provide regular updates on
their financial position, such as audited balance sheets and income
statements; (3) issue detailed proxy statements to shareholders; and (4)
report on insider holdings and trades. Some OTC firms were already
fulfilling requirements (1) and (2) and only had to begin complying with
(3) and (4), while others had to begin complying with all four
provisions.
We compare the stock returns and operating performance of affected
OTC firms with NYSE and AMEX firms. We also contrast those outcomes
among OTC firms that are differentially affected by the 1964 Amendments.
We consider the period between January 1, 1963 and November 15, 1965
(Period 1), when the amendments were proposed and passed into
legislation and firms registered with the SEC, and the period from
November 15, 1965 to the end of 1966 (Period 2), when no new information
about the law was revealed.
During Period 1, OTC firms that were newly required to begin
complying with all four forms of mandatory disclosure had statistically
significant positive abnormal excess returns ranging between 11.5 and
22.1 percent, relative to matched NYSE and AMEX firms. The estimates
imply that the 1964 Amendments created $3.2 to $6.2 billion (in 2005
dollars) of value for shareholders of the OTC firms in our sample.
Overall, the results suggest that the benefits of the 1964
Amendments as measured by stock returns substantially outweighed the
cost of complying with the law. This implies that the affected firms
were not managed to maximize shareholder value prior to 1964. We cannot
determine whether this was because managers made negative net present
value "empire building" acquisitions, lavished excessive
salaries or perks on themselves, engaged in insider trading that reduced
the liquidity of the firm's shares, or some other mechanism.
Regardless of the exact channel, our findings are consistent with the
notion that mandatory disclosure laws can cause managers to focus on
improving shareholder value. This finding is a necessary condition for a
positive welfare effect, but it is not sufficient because we cannot rule
out the possibility that managers lost an amount equal to that gained by
shareholders.
THEORETICAL PERSPECTIVES
For decades, some economists (led by the late Nobel Prize winner
George Stigler) have argued that additional legislation in the
securities market is not nearly as efficient as private contracts
combined with the possibility of litigation. In this framework, if firms
do not provide information about their inner workings, then the value
that shareholders place on the information must not be high enough to
offset the costs of provision. Lawsuits are a costly way to obtain
information from a company, however, and an unregulated market could
suffer from a free rider problem if no individual shareholder has a
sufficient stake in the company to pursue litigation on his or her own.
An alternative view was offered in a 2002 paper by Andrei Shleifer and Daniel Wolfenzon. They derive a model of financial markets where
private contracts cannot set the expected penalties for diversion high
enough to deter it completely. The term "diversion" should be
interpreted broadly to include any activity that does not maximize
shareholder value.
Shleifer and Wolfenzon's model considers an entrepreneur who
needs outside funding to bring her ideas to market. In exchange for
those investments, she promises the outside shareholders a fraction of
the future cash flow. The entrepreneur retains control of the firm, but
she cannot credibly commit to zero diversion before paying out
dividends.
The price that outside shareholders will pay for a given fraction
of shares depends on their expectation of the degree of diversion, which
depends on the magnitude of the contracting problem. Outsiders invest
contingent upon an expected return at least as great as on alternative
investments. In equilibrium, entrepreneurs divert firm resources and
outside shareholders receive the market return on their investment. The
key insight is that stock returns do not depend on the level of
diversion, but stock prices do; they must be low enough to still provide
a competitive return even though diversion occurs.
In this setting, consider the introduction of a regulatory policy
that increases the expected penalties for diversion, either by
increasing the probability of detection or raising the penalty. This
policy will reduce the equilibrium level of diversion and, in turn,
affect insiders' total payoff and firms' share prices.
Consider firms that sold shares to the public before the policy was
in force. The introduction of the policy causes a onetime increase in
the value of those firms. However, after this jump in the stock price,
the expected return to holding shares in the firm will again equal that
of other firms with similar risk.
The increased stock price does not necessarily indicate an increase
in welfare. Social welfare is unaffected when the abnormal returns are
due solely to a transfer of a fixed set of resources from one party (the
entrepreneur) to another (outside investors). However, when diversion is
costly (e.g., if the total cost of a lavish office exceeds the
entrepreneur's private valuation), the reduced diversion will
generate welfare improvements.
REGULATION BEFORE 1964
Prior to 1933, there was little federal regulation of securities
markets. The 1933 Securities Act and the 1934 Securities Exchange Act
created four mandatory disclosure requirements that applied to some, but
not all, existing firms. Here, we describe those disclosure requirements
and detail which categories of firms were required to comply with each
of them:
(1) Registration Firms listed on exchanges (such as the NYSE or
AMEX) and OTC firms that issued securities of sufficient market value
after May 1936 were required to register those securities with the SEC.
The registration statements had to contain detailed financial
information at the time of registration, including: balance sheet and
profit and loss statements from the previous three years; the terms and
position of each class of outstanding securities; the organization,
financial structure, and nature of the business; and the identity and
remuneration of directors, officers, and shareholders with more than a
10 percent stake.
(2) Periodic Reporting Firms listed on exchanges (such as the NYSE
or AMEX) and OTC firms that issued securities of sufficient market value
after May 1936 were required to file annual reports (Form 10-K) and
semiannual reports (Form 9-K) with the SEC. They were also required to
report material events as they occurred (Form 8-K).
(3) Proxy Statements Firms listed on exchanges were required to
provide proxy statements in advance of shareholder meetings or votes.
Those statements must contain information on the qualifications of
directors and nominees for directors, executive compensation, and
transactions between the company and its officers or directors. All OTC
firms were exempted from this requirement.
(4) Insider Trading Firms listed on exchanges were required to
report the identities of officers, directors, and large shareholders.
They also had to report those individuals' holdings of any equity
security of the company and provide monthly statements of any changes.
Firms could recover any profits that an insider realized from the
purchase and sale of the firm's stock in any period of less than
six months. All OTC firms were exempted from this requirement.
Thus, the 1933 and 1934 acts created a system of regulation that
imposed different requirements on firms, based on where their shares
were traded and whether they had made substantial public offerings after
1936.
To summarize, all listed firms were subject to all four disclosure
requirements, OTC firms that had made substantial public offerings since
1936 were subject to requirements (1) and (2) above, and OTC firms that
had not made a public offering since 1936 were free from all disclosure
requirements no matter their size or how widely distributed their
securities.
RESEARCH DESIGN
The 1964 Securities Acts Amendments required that any OTC firm with
at least 750 shareholders and $1 million of assets as of the last day of
its first fiscal year to end after July 1, 1964 (or any year after that)
must register with the SEC within 120 days of the end of the fiscal year
and begin to comply with the other three types of disclosure. The
compliance date for firms that met the asset test and had between 500
and 750 shareholders was the last day of its first fiscal year to end
after July 1, 1966. (Based on 1961 asset and shareholder data, roughly
32 percent of OTC firms exceeded both the asset and shareholder floors.)
OTC firms with fewer than 500 shareholders and/or $1 million in assets
were unaffected by the 1964 Amendments.
The structure and timing of the 1964 Securities Acts Amendments
provide a compelling setting to evaluate the impacts of mandatory
disclosure laws on stock returns. This section explains how we exploit
the structure of the legislation to create multiple groups of OTC firms
that were likely to be affected by the legislation to varying degrees
and compare them to NYSE and AMEX firms that were unaffected. It also
explains how the legislation provides a natural way to divide 1963-1966
into two periods to examine the law's effects and perform
validation exercises of our approach.
FIRM VARIATION We use pre-legislation characteristics of OTC firms
to assign them to one of four OTC groups. Those assignments are based on
two categories. First, each OTC firm is labeled either "high
compliance probability" or "low compliance probability."
We assume that firms have a high probability of compliance if their
measured assets in 1962 exceeded $1 million and they had 500 or more
shareholders or their measured assets exceeded $5 million but
shareholder data were unavailable. All other firms are placed in the
"low compliance probability" category.
We place each OTC firm into either a "high diversion
reduction" or "low diversion reduction" group depending
on whether the firm was engaged in periodic reporting under the 1934
legislation by the end of 1962. Firms that were not filing annual
reports with the SEC by the end of 1962 faced the possibility of four
new types of disclosure. In contrast, firms that were filing with the
SEC by 1962 were potentially subject to just two new forms of
disclosure.
The interaction of those two categorizations divides the OTC firms
into four groups. The first OTC group consists of firms that are in the
"high compliance probability" and "high diversion
reduction" groups. Henceforth, they are referred to as the 0-4
group. The first number indicates the number of forms of disclosure with
which the firm was required to comply prior to the 1964 Amendments,
while the second number indicates the number of forms of disclosure with
which we expect the firm to have complied after the 1964 Amendments were
in force.
We use this same naming convention to denote the other groups. For
example, the second group consists of firms that by 1963 were above the
1964 Amendments' size cutoffs and filing annual reports with the
SEC. Those firms are in the "high compliance probability" and
"low diversion reduction" groups. They are labeled 2-4. The
other two are the 0-0 and 2-2 groups. Table 1 summarizes how we assigned
OTC firms to the four groups.
If the mandatory disclosure requirements were valued by outside
shareholders, then we expect the four OTC groups' treatment effects
to differ. In particular, our prediction is that the 0-4s'
treatment effect will be the largest, because those firms have a
relatively high probability of compliance and, conditional on
compliance, will have a relatively large change in the amount of
information they must disclose. By analogous reasoning, we expect the
2-2s' treatment effect to be the smallest. Their expected
probability of compliance is relatively low and, among compliers, the
change in disclosure requirements is relatively small.
We predict that the 2-4s' and 0-0s' treatment effects are
between the 0-4s' and 2-2s' effects. The ordering of the
treatment effect for the 2-4s relative to that of the 0-0s is ambiguous.
Firms in the 2-4 group have a high probability of complying with two new
disclosure requirements, while firms in the 0-0 group have a low
probability of complying with four new requirements.
We also create groups of NYSE and AMEX firms and use them to
mitigate the possibility of confounding the effects of the 1964
Amendments with shocks to stock returns common to OTC and NYSE/AMEX
firms. Those groups of firms are labeled 4-4 and are constructed so that
the distributions of the underlying firms' market capitalizations
and the ratio of book value of equity to market capitalizations are
similar to the distributions in the corresponding OTC group.
TIME VARIATION From January 1, 1963 through November 15, 1965, the
1964 Amendments were initially proposed and passed into legislation, and
we learned which individual firms registered under the 1964 Amendments
with the Securities and Exchange Commission. We assume that the full
impact of the 1964 Amendments on stock returns occurred in this 149-week
period. Data from this period are used to test the null hypotheses that
the OTC groups had zero abnormal excess returns relative to their
corresponding size and book-to-market matched NYSE/AMEX (4-4) groups. A
failure to reject the null would suggest that the disclosure
requirements did not produce information that was valued by outside
shareholders (after accounting for compliance costs).
Period 2 runs from November 15, 1965 through the end of 1966.
During those 58 weeks, virtually no new information about the law or
which firms would comply with its requirements was revealed and thus no
abnormal returns should occur. If excess returns for affected OTC groups
also existed in this period, our research design and any findings from
Period I would be suspect.
DATA AND SUMMARY STATISTICS
We use the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) database
to calculate returns of NYSE and AMEX firms for the 1963-1966 period. We
restrict the sample to those firms present in the first week of January
1963. A corresponding electronic dataset of OTC firms did not exist for
the period we study; OTC firms are not available in CRSP until December
1972.
We therefore created the equivalent of the CRSP database for 1,196
OTC securities for the 1963-1966 period. The sample is comprised of
securities that appeared in the January 7, 1963 issue of Barron's
and were potentially affected by the 1964 Amendments. We also use data
from 1,915 NYSE and AMEX firms available in CRSP.
Table 2 provides a few summary statistics. The 0-4 group has 240
firms in the beginning of 1963. This group is considerably smaller than
the 2-4 group, which initially has 738 firms because many 1963 OTC firms
had made a public offering in the previous 27 years. The samples of 0-0
and 2-2 firms are substantially smaller because Barron's selected
the largest and most actively traded OTC firms for inclusion in their
stock tables.
Survival rates vary across the different groups. The rates are
roughly comparable among the 0-4, 2-4, and 4-4 groups and are even
closer after matching on total market capitalization. This similarity in
survival rates suggests that the OTC groups' attrition rates are
due to genuine attrition, not insufficient data collection efforts on
our part. The 0-0 and 2-2 groups have lower survival rates because the
1964 Amendments' size cutoffs ensure that they are comprised of
small firms. Those groups' small starting size and high attrition
rates make meaningful inference about the groups difficult.
The mean (median) market capitalization in 1963 dollars for the 0-4
and 2-4 groups are $44.6 million ($9.1 million) and $26.5 million ($10.4
million), respectively. The total market capitalizations of those two
groups in 2005 dollars are $66 billion and $122 billion, respectively.
This information is available for a small fraction of the 0-0 and 2-2
firms.
RESULTS
This section presents four tests of the impacts of the mandatory
disclosure requirements.
TEST #1: WERE FIRMS REWARDED FOR COMPLIANCE? The analysis begins
with a firm-level event study of the effect of the announcement that OTC
firms were officially in compliance with the 1964 Amendments' new
mandatory disclosure requirements on stock returns. We obtained the
precise dates that the SEC announced that pre-legislation, non-filing
firms had fulfilled the registration requirement and pre-legislation
filers had fulfilled the proxy and insider holdings/trades requirements
for the first time. Those official filing dates were collected from the
daily issues of the SEC News Digest, which as a matter of policy
published them 60 days after the SEC received the filings. Henceforth,
we refer to those firms as "new filers" and the dates of the
announcement in the SEC News Digest as the "filing dates."
We use those filing dates as the basis of a firm-level event study
of the effect of choosing to become a new filer. Roughly two-thirds of
0-4 and 2-4 firms chose to comply in this period. Importantly, the
filing dates were determined by firms' fiscal year ends and varied
from firm to firm. Thus, any estimated effect will not be confounded by
shocks that affect all OTC firm returns.
Specifically, we estimate regressions during the 64-week period
between August 24, 1964 (when the legislation was signed into law) and
November 15, 1965 (the last compliance date for most firms). The
dependent variable is a firm's weekly return minus that week's
average return for the firms in the size and book-to-market cell of
NYSE/AMEX to which the OTC firm would have belonged had it been listed
on NYSE or AMEX at the beginning of 1963. The regression equation controls for the difference between market and risk-free returns, the
size and book-to-market factors, and a momentum factor.
We add an indicator variable that equals 1 during the event window
and its associated coefficient is the focus of the regressions. Because
of uncertainty surrounding the exact date that the market learned that a
firm had become a new filer, we define the event window as the period
from eight weeks prior to the SEC filing date through one week
subsequent to the date. The event window is extended one week beyond the
filing date to allow the information to disseminate. Thus, the parameter
on the event window indicator tests for abnormal excess returns in the
10-week period when news of a firm's decision to file became known
to the market. This model is estimated with data from the 64-week period
from August 24, 1964 through November 15, 1964.
On average, the 145 0-4 and 417 2-4 filers had abnormal excess
returns of approximately 3.5 percent in the narrow period when news that
they had filed was released to the market. Statistical analyses confirm
this finding and show that the excess returns are statistically
significant.
Figure 1 presents the 0-4 and 2-4 results graphically. The
relatively flat 0-4 and 2-4 lines between Week -20 and Week -9 suggest
no abnormal excess returns during those weeks. During the event window,
the cumulative abnormal excess return lines turn upward dramatically.
Then the lines are flat from Week 1 through Week 10, which is after news
that those firms were new filers had become public.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Figure 1 provides strong evidence that the market rewarded firms
that complied with the mandatory disclosure requirements specified by
the 1964 Amendments. However, because of the forward-looking nature of
asset markets, it is possible that OTC firms had abnormal excess returns
in the period that the legislation was debated and ultimately passed. To
estimate the full effect of the 1964 Amendments on stock returns, the
next section tests for abnormal excess returns among the OTC groups over
the entire Period 1.
TEST #2: PERIOD 1 ABNORMAL EXCESS RETURNS? We
estimate the above regression again, this time focusing on the mean
abnormal excess weekly return ([alpha]) for the different OTC groups
over their matched NYSE/AMEX group of firms during the full Period 1.
This estimated mean abnormal excess weekly return and its estimated
standard error from six different versions of this regression are
reported in columns 1-6 of Table 3. In the first five columns, the 4-4
groups are constructed, as described above, so that the distributions of
the underlying firms' market capitalizations and ratio of
book-to-market are similar to the distribution of those variables in the
corresponding OTC groups. In Column 6, we use an industry-matched 4-4
group as the comparison but do not do any size or book-to-market
matching because of sample size issues.
The table also explores the sensitivity of the results to
alternative portfolio construction rules and sets of controls. In all
columns except 4 and 5, we assume that investors in our constructed
portfolios rebalance their holdings every week to keep them equally
weighted across all securities. Column 4 reports the results from a
buy-and-hold strategy with equal initial weighting. In Column 5, the
portfolios are based on a value-weighted buy-and-hold strategy. In
Column 1, the estimates are unadjusted for any factors, while the Column
2 estimate is adjusted for the market excess return, which is the
canonical Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM). In the remaining columns,
we add controls for the three other standard factors.
For the 0-4 group, the five adjusted models in columns 2 through 6
imply cumulative returns ranging between 11.5 percent and 22.1 percent.
Two of the five models estimated are significant at the one percent
level, another at the four percent level, and the last two at the 11
percent level. In a separate analysis reported in the full paper, we
found that the majority of the 0-4s' positive abnormal excess
returns occurred during the period when the law was debated and signed
into law (i.e., January 1, 1963 through August 24, 1964).
The 0-4s' unadjusted estimate in Column 1 is not statistically
significant at conventional levels. It is evident that the validity of
ascribing the difference in returns between the 0-4 group and its
matched 4-4 group to the 1964 Amendments therefore rests on the validity
of the standard model for stock returns. This contrasts with the
findings from the event study, which do not hinge on whether we control
for the four factors.
For the 2-4 group, the adjusted models imply a cumulative abnormal
excess return of between 1.9 and 8.4 percent, but none of the results
differ statistically from zero at the 10 percent level. Overall, the
2-4s' findings provide modest support for the view that investors
valued the introduction of proxy and insider trading disclosure
requirements for firms that were already registered with the SEC and
filing periodic reports. The imprecision of those estimates, however,
tempers the strength of any conclusions.
Because of space constraints, the results for the 0-0 and 2-2
groups are not reported in the table, but we summarize them here. All of
the estimated abnormal excess weekly returns for the groups are negative
and are thus smaller than the 0-4 and 2-4 groups' estimated
abnormal excess returns. Because of the small sample sizes for those
groups, the 0-0s' and 2-2s' standard errors are generally more
than twice as large as in the first two panels. This imprecision is
evidenced by the fact that only three of the 12 estimates have an
associated t-statistic greater than one and none exceeds 1.3. We
conclude that the 1964 Amendments did not have a statistically
meaningful effect on those groups' returns in Period 1.
Overall, the Period 1 results suggest that the mandatory disclosure
requirements introduced by the 1964 Amendments increased market
participants' valuations of the 0-4 firms by between 11.5 and 22.1
percent relative to their matched NYSE/AMEX comparison group. There is
little evidence that the 1964 Amendments affected the stock returns of
the other OTC groups in this period.
TEST #3: PERIOD 2 ABNORMAL EXCESS RETURNS? Period 2 begins after
the law has passed and the vast majority of complying firms have begun
to file with the SEC. Consequently, our expectation is that the OTC
groups will have no abnormal excess returns in this period. A rejection
of this null hypothesis would raise the possibility that our research
design or the four-factor modal is invalid here.
We performed analyses similar to those in Table 3, but using data
from Period 2. We found little evidence of abnormal excess returns for
any of the OTC groups and none of the estimates would be judged to be
statistically different from zero at the 10 percent level. Overall, the
findings from this 58-week period support the validity of our approach
and lend credibility to the hypothesis that the estimated effects in
Period 1 are due to the 1964 Amendments.
TEST #4: OPERATING PERFORMANCE Our hypothesis is that mandatory
disclosure laws bind managers to focus more on maximizing shareholder
value. The evidence of positive abnormal excess returns for the 0-4
group in this period is consistent with this hypothesis but fails to
shed light on exactly why market participants were willing to pay more
for an ownership stake. This section explores one possibility by testing
whether OTC firms experienced improvements in operating performance
relative to 4-4 firms between 1962 and 1966.
We estimated two firm-level operating performance regressions for
each of two dependent variables: net income (profit) growth from 1962 to
1966 normalized by 1962 market capitalization, and sales growth from
1962 to 1966 normalized by 1962 sales. Both net income and sales growth
are considered important measures of operating performance, although net
income is more closely related to stock returns. The regressions were
first run only for firms for which comparable 1966 information was avail
able and then on the complete data set with missing growth information
assigned based on the 10th or 50th percentile of firms in the group
according to an assignment rule.
Controlling for initial asset size and industry, the 0-4
firms' change in net income relative to initial market value was
about 0.030-0.038 larger than the 4-4s'. The mean change for 4-4
firms is 0.086, so the 0-4s' increase in this measure of income
growth was 35-44 percent larger than the 4-4s'. This result is
statistically significant. The 2-4 firms' point estimates are
roughly a third as large as the 0-4s' and would not be judged to be
statistically significant by conventional criteria.
The sales growth results, again controlling for initial asset size
and industry, indicate that 0-4 firms' total sales increased by a
statistically significant 84-109 percent more than the unaffected 4-4
firms. The 2-4 firms had smaller relative increases in sales growth
(16-17 percent) and the estimates border on statistical significance at
the five percent level. The mean sales growth of 4-4 firms, by contrast,
was roughly 70 percent, so the 0-4 firms' sales increases are quite
large.
Overall, the results provide evidence that as quickly as one year
after most firms' compliance deadlines, the operating performance
of 0-4 (and, to a lesser degree, 2-4) firms had improved, relative to
4-4 firms. Our findings are consistent with the hypothesis that the
mandatory disclosure requirements caused managers to focus on
shareholder value.
INTERPRETATION
Based on the varied evidence presented in this paper, we conclude
that investors valued the mandatory disclosure requirements imposed on
0-4 firms by the 1964 Amendments. We now try to put the numbers in some
context. The estimates of the cumulative abnormal excess returns in
Period 1 for the 0-4 firms ranged from 11.5 to 22.1 percent. Those
results imply that the 1964 Amendments created $0.5 billion to $1.0
billion (1963 dollars) or $3.2 billion to $6.2 billion (2005 dollars) of
value for stockholders.
Those numbers understate the total increase in market
capitalization associated with the legislation because our sample only
includes a quarter of the nearly 900 firms that filed with the SEC for
the first time after passage of the 1964 Amendments (although it
probably has many of the largest ones). As the conceptual framework highlighted, our numbers are an upper bound on the welfare gain
associated with the mandatory disclosure regulations because at least
part of the gain in market capitalization reflects a transfer of
insiders' resources to outside shareholders.
In light of the magnitude of the increases in market
capitalization, it is natural to wonder why shareholders had not
previously organized to attempt to capture the $3.2-$6.2 billion by
forcing insiders to move the companies to the NYSE or AMEX. There are
several possible reasons. First, it is likely that some of the 0-4 firms
did not meet the listing requirements for the NYSE or AMEX (at the start
of 1963, 48 percent of OTC firms in group 0-4 had market capitalizations
below the 25th percentile of the market capitalization of
exchange-traded firms). Second, insiders may have owned more than half
of the shares, making it impossible for outside shareholders to force a
move to the NYSE or AMEX. Third, it is probable that the $3.2-$6.2
billion figure overstates the resources that could be captured by
shareholders. It is likely that at least part of this figure reflects a
transfer from insiders via reduced diversion and/or increased effort. To
make this effective transfer, it seems reasonable to assume that
insiders would have required increased compensation. Fourth, the
coordination of efforts to induce a firm to move to the NYSE or AMEX has
the features of a classic public goods problem because the activist
shareholder(s) cannot capture the full benefits of their efforts.
CONCLUSION
We analyzed the last major imposition of mandatory disclosure
requirements in U.S. equity markets. The 1964 Securities Acts Amendments
extended several disclosure requirements to large firms traded
over-the-counter that had applied to listed firms since 1934. We
presented four pieces of evidence that investors valued the new
disclosure requirements.
The results are consistent with the hypothesis that mandatory
disclosure laws can cause managers to focus more narrowly on the
maximization of shareholder value. The precise benefits to the American
economy are unknown, however, because we cannot determine how much of
shareholders' gains were a transfer from insiders of the same
companies. If diversion of firm resources by managers entails some waste
(rather than just transferring the resources from one group to another),
then our study implies that mandatory disclosure can lead to net
benefits to the economy.
Our results have several policy implications. First, some legal
scholars have called for the significant modification or repeal of the
mandatory disclosure requirements studied here. Our analysis suggests
that such a weakening of federal oversight is unlikely to be beneficial
for U.S. equity markets.
Second, the disclosure requirements studied here are less stringent
than those specified in the recent Sarbanes-Oxley Act, so the results
are not directly informative about the effects of that legislation.
Thus, our study fails to indicate whether some of the recent corporate
scandals would have been averted if Sarbanes-Oxley had been on the
books. However, it does suggest that those scandals might have been
worse if the 1964 Amendments had not been in place.
Third, the study may be most relevant for the regulators who
oversee the numerous developed- and developing-country equity markets
where the disclosures outlined in the 1964 Amendments are not mandatory.
Specifically, the results indicate that the introduction of regulations
that mandate such disclosures is unlikely to be harmful and, in fact, is
likely to be beneficial in those markets.
READINGS
* "Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities
Regulation," by Roberta Romano. Yale Law Journal, Vol. 107 (1998).
* "The Exchange as Regulator," by Paul G. Mahoney.
Virginia Law Review, Vol. 83 (1997).
* "Information Asymmetry, Corporate Disclosure, and the
Capital Markets: a Review of the Empirical Disclosure Literature,"
by Paul M. Healy and Krishna G. Palepu. Journal of Accounting and
Economics, Vol. 31 (2001).
* "Investor Protection and Equity Markets," by Andrei
Shleifer and Daniel Wolfenzon. Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 66
(2002).
* "Market Failure and the Economic Case for a Mandatory
Disclosure System," by John C. Coffee. Virginia Law Review, Vol. 70
(1984).
* "Public Regulation of the Securities Markets," by
George Stigler. Journal of Business, Vol. 37 (1964).
* "Readying for More Reform," by Edmund Kitch.
Regulation, Vol. 25, No. 1 (Fall 2002).
* "Required Disclosure and the Stock Market: An Evaluation of
the Securities Exchange Act of 1934," by George J. Benston.
American Economic Review, Vol. 63 (1973).
* "Toward Disclosure Choice in Securities Offerings," by
Alan R. Palmiter. Columbia Business Law Review, 1999.
TABLE 1
Assignment of OTC Firms into Four Groups
Divisions created by the 1964 Securities Acts Amendments
OTC Diversion Reduction Compliance Probability
Group Was there periodic Did the stock exceed shareholder
reporting by 1962? and asset floors by 1962?
0-4 No [right arrow] High Yes [right arrow] High
Diversion Reduction Compliance Probability
2-4 Yes [right arrow] Low Yes [right arrow] High
Diversion Reduction Compliance Probability
0-0 No [right arrow] High No [right arrow] Low
Diversion Reduction Compliance Probability
2-2 Yes [right arrow] Low No [right arrow] Low
Diversion Reduction Compliance Probability
TABLE 2
1962 Firm Characteristics by
Mandatory Disclosure Groups
0-4 2-4 0-0 2-2 4-4
NUMBER OF FIRMS
Week 1 (1963) 240 738 124 94 1,915
Week 52 (1966) 186 610 67 63 1,668
Survival Rate (%) 77.5 82.7 54.0 67.0 87.1
MARKET CAPITALIZATION
Non-missing 237 734 23 39 1,915
Mean $44.6 $26.5 $4.4 $2.5 $189.1
Median $9.1 $10.4 $1.9 $2.3 $28.5
NOTE: All dollar figures are in millions of 1963 dollars.
TABLE 3
Average Abnormal Weekly Returns
January 1963-November 15, 1965 (Period 1)
(1) (2) (3)
(0-4)-(4-4)
0-4 OTC Group 0.053 0.078 0.097
(0.048) (0.048) (0.046)
R-squared -- 0.028 0.191
(2-4)-(4-4)
2-4 OTC Group -0.010 0.013 0.024
(0.045) (0.043) (0.040)
R-squared -- 0.026 0.133
Factor Model None CAPM 4F
Buy and Hold No No No
Value Weighted No No No
Industry Matched No No No
(4) (5) (6)
(0-4)-(4-4)
0-4 OTC Group 0.129 0.083 0.149
(0.048) (0.048) (0.047)
R-squared 0.195 0.213 0.160
(2-4)-(4-4)
2-4 OTC Group 0.057 0.035 0.056
(0.043) (0.048) (0.039)
R-squared 0.120 0.166 0.079
Factor Model 4F 4F 4F
Buy and Hold Yes Yes No
Value Weighted No Yes No
Industry Matched No No Yes
NOTES: The dependent variable is the relevant OTC group's
weekly return minus the weekly return of the matched 4-4
group. In the "Factor Model" row, "CAPM" indicates that
the regression controls for the return on the market.
"4F" indicates controls for the market, size, book-to-
market, and momentum factors.
Why Did the 1964 Act Raise Securities Prices?
A COMMENT ON GREENSTONE, OYER, AND VISSING-JORGENSEN
BY EDMUND KITCH
University of Virginia
In 1964, Congress extended the coverage of the Securities and
Exchange Act of 1934 to include much of the over-the-counter (OTC)
market. This change has long awaited an event study to discern the
impact of the expanded coverage on the previously uncovered securities.
The preceding article by Michael Greenstone, Paul Oyer, and Annette
Vissing-Jorgensen offers an elegant event study that reveals that the
effect of the regulation was to significantly increase the market price
of the newly regulated securities.
Previous event studies had focused on the passage of the original
securities laws in 1933 and 1934, but their results were inconclusive.
They suffered from a lack of an obvious comparison group for the newly
regulated securities--all securities were unregulated before the event,
and almost all securities were regulated after the event. In 1964, on
the other hand, it is possible to compare the newly regulated securities
to securities regulated both before and after the 1964 changes.
WHY THE HIGHER PRICES?
Why did the statute and the implementing regulation cause the newly
regulated securities to trade at higher prices? The authors offer an
answer to this question that draws on an earlier published model by
Andrei Schleifer and Daniel Wofenzon. Their model indicates that a
market that provides better protection of outside shareholders as
against managers or controlling shareholders leads to a more valuable
stock market. Greenstone, Oyer, and Vissing-Jorgensen present the
results of their event study as evidence supporting the
Schleifer--Wofenzon model, but Greenstone and his coauthors do not
attempt to explain how the legislation achieves its result. They argue,
however, that regulation that reduces diversion by managers or
controlling shareholders will increase the share of the firm value
captured by the outside shareholders. The increased value, in turn, is
reflected in share price. Greenstone, Oyer, and Vissing-Jorgensen assume
that the legislation reduces diversion.
There is an alternative explanation for the result that can be
found in the legal literature: The 1934 Act and the 1964 Amendments
reduce the cost of buying securities, and that savings translates into
higher prices. The cost of buying a security has two principal elements:
the cost of analyzing its value to determine whether the price is
attractive, and the cost of finding and closing a transaction to buy the
security. The theory is that the legislation reduces the cost of the
first by centralizing the provision of much of the relevant information
with the issuer, the lowest-cost provider. This lowers the cost of
buying a security, and thus increases the amount buyers are willing to
pay. This explanation was put forth by Ronald Gilson and Reinier
Kraakman in 1984 (see "MOME in Hindsight," Winter 2004-2005)
and is widely repeated in the legal literature on securities regulation.
The Greenstone, Oyer, and Vissing-Jorgensen event study was not
structured to answer the causation question. However, it is suggestive
of an answer to this question. They study two groups of OTC firms,
comparing each to a group of similar firms that were fully subject to
the Exchange Act before the 1964 Amendments. The first of the test
groups (which they call the 0-4 group) contained firms that were not
subject to the Exchange Act at all prior to 1964. The second test group
(which they call the 2-4 group) contained firms that were required to
file financial disclosure statements in accordance with the 1934 Act
before 1964, and after 1964 had to comply in addition with the proxy and
short-swing profit rules. That is, the second group of companies simply
added the proxy rules and the short-swing profit rules.
The difference between the groups is suggestive on the causation
question because the financial statements are consistent with the
"reduced cost of buying" explanation. The proxy rules and
short-swing profit rules are concerned with areas that are the
traditional concern of diversion control: capture of firm value through
conflicts of interest and insider market trading. Greenstone, Oyer, and
Vissing-Jorgensen get their most striking results when they compare the
0-4 group with the matched market group. When they compare the 2-4 group
with the matched market group, their results are not statistically
significant and the results, if any, are substantially less. This
suggests to me that the reduced cost of purchasing explanation is a
plausible candidate, based on their results.
WHY NOT OPT IN?
A second question that the Greenstone, Oyer, and Vissing-Jorgensen
event study suggests is why did the 0-4 group of firms choose not to
become subject to the 1934 Act before 1964? If they made themselves
subject to the act (as they could have done, either by listing on an
exchange or making a public offering of securities for $2 million or
more), this study suggests that they would have increased the value of
their publicly traded shares. As Greenstone, Oyer, and Vissing-Jorgensen
state, "Overall, the results suggest that the benefits of the 1964
Amendments substantially outweighed the cost of complying with this law
as measured by stock returns. This implies that the affected firms were
not managed to maximize shareholder value prior to 1964." Why?
Greenstone, Oyer, and Vissing-Jorgensen use the diversion story to
provide an explanation. By processes such as empire-building
acquisitions, excessive compensation and perks, or insider trading, the
managers or controlling shareholders were able to capture a
disproportionate share of firm value. They had a good deal, and they
were not about to give it up by making the firm subject to any
requirement of the 1934 Act.
But there are other possible explanations. Putting aside the
possibility that the OTC companies simply made a mistake and thus
remained behind in the OTC market, other explanations include:
EXPENSE The 1964 Amendments reduced the cost of entering the
Exchange Act regulation. Prior to 1964, the OTC firms that were not
subject to the 1934 Act had two ways to obtain coverage of the
regulation: First, they could make a public offering of a security in
excess of $2 million. If they did so, they were thereafter required to
file annual and quarterly reports, including audited financial
statements, just like companies subject to the Exchange Act. If an
issuer did not need the capital or had less expensive sources of
capital, the expenses of the public offering would have to be born by
the company. The alternative way to enter the regulation was to list on
an exchange, which would have made the company subject to all provisions
of the 1934 Act. But then the company had to incur the cost of exchange
fees and requirements. The 1964 Amendments made it possible for the
companies to be regulated without incurring either of those expenses.
Thus, the 1964 Amendments may have made the benefits of the regulation
available at lower cost, and the higher net benefits were reflected in
stock prices.
LONG-TERM STRATEGY Another explanation is that the issuers were
controlled by a block of controlling shareholders who planned to hold
their shares for some significant future period of time. Given their
long-term investment horizon, they had no wish to sell their shares.
Thus, the enhanced share price in the trading market that would be
produced by the 1934 Securities Exchange Act had no value for them. From
their point of view, it would simply be a waste of company resources to
comply with the act. They wanted minority shareholders to invest with a
similar holding period in mind, and to suffer a cost if they insisted on
terminating their investment early. In this scenario, the controlling
shareholders do not divert value from the company. They simply operate
the company in a way that maximizes value for themselves and other
long-term investors, but not for the shareholders that sell
"early." When they are ready to sell, then they will prepare
the market for their shares (and the shares of the minority investors)
by causing the issuer to comply with the securities acts. In this
scenario, the minority shareholders enjoyed a windfall when the rules of
the game were changed in the middle of the investment period by the
intervention of Congress in 1964.
FUTURE REGULATION?
Finally, the study considers possible improvements of the
securities laws. The fact that the 1934 Act has positive effects does
not mean that there might be alternatives with even larger positive net
benefits. This brief article does not allow mention of all of the
proposals that have been made over the years. However, it is important
to note that the most prominent proposal of recent years, put forth by
Roberta Romano, is not a proposal to abolish the securities laws; it is
a proposal to make compliance with the securities laws optional rather
than mandatory. If, as the event study suggests, compliance increases
the value of a company, firms will choose to comply. But if it turns out
that the regulation does not, issuers will be able--with the consent of
their shareholders--to drop out of the regulation. The regulation may
have been value enhancing in 1964--indeed, may have always been value
enhancing--but that does not mean that at some point Congress and the
regulators will not make choices that are value destructive. Making the
regulation optional puts the regulatory system into competition with the
unregulated market and creates an incentive for the regulators to ensure
that their decisions are value enhancing.
In recent years, a consensus has emerged that event studies show
that issuers can increase their firm value by moving their state of
incorporation to Delaware. No one that I know of has ever suggested
that, because of those findings, Congress should require that all public
companies, or indeed any group of public companies, incorporate in
Delaware. The state remains an optional choice that many, but not all,
companies use. And Delaware knows that firms can choose to move out of
state, a fact that incentivizes Diamond State politicians, judges, and
lawyers to make sure that changes in state law are well advised. Why
does Congress have to require that issuers comply with the securities
acts if, as the Greenstone, Oyer, and Vissing-Jorgensen study suggests,
it is in the interest of the issuers to comply?
READINGS
* The Economic Structure of Corporate Law, by Frank H. Easterbrook and Daniel R. Fischel. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1991.
* "Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities
Regulation," by Roberta Romano. Yale Law Journal, Vol. 107 (1998).
* "Event Studies and the Law: Part II: Empirical Studies of
Corporate Law," by Sanjai Bhagat and Roberta Romano. American Law
and Economic Review, Vol. 4 (2002).
* "The Mechanisms of Market Efficiency," by Ronald J.
Gilson and Reinier H. Kraakman. Virginia Lave Review, Vol. 70 (1984).
Edmund Kitch is the Mary and Daniel Loughran Professor of Law and
the E. James Kelly, Jr.--Class of 1965 Research Professor of Law at the
University of Virginia. He may be contacted by e-mail at
ewk@virginia.edu.
RESPONSE TO KITCH
Data Supports Mandatory Disclosure
Edmund Kitch has provided a thoughtful commentary on our article in
this issue and the full version of our study published in the May 2006
Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Before we respond to his specific comments, we note that Prof.
Kitch has not challenged our study's finding that the 1964
Amendments created value for shareholders by leading to higher share
prices of the newly regulated firms. Nor does he question the result
that the newly regulated firms' profits and sales increased after
the law went into force.
Instead, Professor Kitch's commentary focuses on what channel
led to the increase in share prices. He also suggests that it is
possible to design regulations even more beneficial than the ones
specified in the 1964 Amendments.
In our study, we suggest that mandatory disclosure regulations
limit opportunities for diversion by managers or insiders. In his
commentary, Prof. Kitch suggests two alternative channels of wealth
creation. First, Kitch argues that the value of the 1964 Amendments (and
the securities acts in general) may simply be to reduce investors'
costs of gathering information. The finding that affected firms'
operating performance improved after the legislation went into force
implies that it is unlikely that this is the entire story.
Furthermore, this explanation fits our definition of diversion as
any activity that does not maximize shareholder value. That is, if
insiders could have lowered the cost of gathering information in a way
that would have increased the firm's value, but they chose not to,
then they were diverting value away from other shareholders. For holders
of the firm's equity, the effect is to depress the stock price and
in that sense it is similar to the purchase of unnecessary corporate
jets.
Second, Professor Kitch suggests that the 1964 Amendments may have
created value by reducing the costs of entering the SEC mandatory
disclosure system. The issuance of securities can be expensive and it is
possible that the costs of joining an exchange were prohibitive for many
firms. More to the point, this explanation is not rejected by the data
and could be an important complement to our proposed mechanism of
reduced diversion by insiders.
Professor Kitch suggests one mechanism through which the 1964
Amendments could raise stock prices of affected firms, yet be value
irrelevant or possibly even value destroying for long-term shareholders.
The idea seems to be that nondisclosure keeps share prices artificially
low, thereby making it costly to sell shares. This in turn induces
decision-making that maximizes share prices in the long run.
We see a logical problem with this argument. If long-horizon
shareholders were able to prevent compliance with the securities acts
pre-1964, this suggests that they owned the majority of the (voting)
shares. In that case, why would they not have sufficient power to
out-vote short-sighted shareholders on other company issues, even if the
firm were to comply with the 1964 Amendments? Furthermore, we are
unaware of any empirical support for this story.
In his final remarks, Professor Kitch lends his support to the
recent proposal by Roberta Romano and others to make compliance with the
disclosure regulations voluntary. There surely is heterogeneity in costs
and benefits of regulation across firms. Thus, it is possible that
compliance with the regulations is a negative for some subgroups of
firms.
On the other hand, it does not seem farfetched to suppose that
company insiders, who benefit from diversion, will try to manipulate the
compliance decision in companies where compliance would add value for
shareholders (by manipulating the information provided to shareholders
about the costs and benefits of compliance). Furthermore, disperse shareholders will face free-rider problems in coordinating their efforts
to uncover the true costs and benefits and to mobilize enough votes to
force compliance in cases where it is deemed beneficial. An additional
problem with voluntary compliance is that in the presence of information
externalities, voluntary compliance can lead to inefficient (too little)
information provision. Anat Admati and Paul Pfleiderer, in a 2000 Review
of Financial Studies article, formalize this insight in a setting where
firms' values are correlated and the disclosures by one firm are
used by investors in valuing other firms.
In summary, it is ambiguous as to which theoretical behavior will
dominate and, in turn, whether voluntary compliance would be beneficial
for shareholders of most of the companies that would choose to opt out
of the mandatory disclosure regime. In the face of our finding that the
imposition of mandatory disclosure regulations led to a substantial
increase in the value of the average shareholder's holdings of
affected firms, we think the burden of proof lies with advocates of
change. Specifically, the advocates of change must do two things: First,
before looking at the data, they must identify the subset of firms whose
shareholders likely would have been better off from not complying with
the 1964 Amendments (or the securities acts more generally). For
example, it might be reasonable to expect that the costs outweigh the
benefits for small firms. Second, they must demonstrate empirically that
the introduction of mandatory disclosure requirements reduced the value
of those firms. (Alternatively, they could find an example of
deregulation and test whether shareholders of firms who stopped
complying with previously mandatory disclosure requirements gained as a
result of the decision to stop complying).
Our bottom line is that the data, not theoretical reasoning, must
be the ultimate arbiter of the optimal form of disclosure regulations.
BY MICHAEL GREENSTONE, PAUL OYER, AND ANNETTE VISSING-JORGENSEN
BY MICHAEL GREENSTONE,
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
PAUL OYER,
Stanford University
AND ANNETTE VISSING-JORGENSEN
Northwestern University
Michael Greenstone is the 3M Professor of Economics at the
Massachusetts Institute of Technology. He may be contacted by e-mail at
mgreenst@mit.edu.
Paul Oyer is associate professor of economics at Stanford
University's Graduate School of Business. He may be contacted by
e-mail at oyer_paul@gsb.stanford.edu.
Annette Vissing-Jorgensen is associate professor of finance at
Northwestern University's Kellogg School of Management. She may be
contacted by e-mail at a-vissing@northwestern.edu. This article is
condensed from the authors' "Mandated Disclosure, Stock
Returns, and the 1964 Securities Acts Amendments," Quarterly
Journal of Economics, Vol. 121, No. 2 (May 2006).