The perverse effects of predatory pricing law: even if predation is possible, does intense price competition harm consumers?
Crane, Daniel A.
THE THEORY OF PREDATORY PRICING IS as old as the Sherman Act. Among
the evils attributed to John D. Rockefeller and Standard Oil was
underpricing rivals to maintain a monopoly in oil production. In the
early years of the Sherman Act, courts frequently used conclusory epithets such as "ruinous competition," "predatory
intent," and "below-cost pricing" to condemn
price-cutting by dominant firms without undertaking any meaningful
inquiry into whether the challenged behavior was beneficial or harmful
to consumers.
During the 1970s, the law-and-economics movement revolutionized
antitrust law, showing that many practices once condemned were in fact
socially beneficial. Predatory pricing law received a thorough
scrubbing, first at the hands of prominent academics and then in the
federal courts. During the mid-1980s and early 1990s, the Supreme Court
cast doubt on the viability of most predatory pricing claims, opining
that predatory pricing happens rarely, if at all, and that recognizing a
claim based on price-cutting threatens to chill vigorous competitive
behavior by large firms.
Despite this attitudinal reversal in the academy and the courts,
hundreds of predatory pricing cases have been filed in the past decade.
Most of the cases are brought by competitors alleging that a
rival's low prices threaten to put the plaintiff out of business.
Although very few plaintiffs succeed in winning a favorable
judgment given the strict rules imposed by the Supreme Court, the tone
in the academy is beginning to change. Drawing on advances in game
theory and behavioral economics, recent scholarship argues that
predatory pricing may be more common than the Supreme Court believed.
Prominent economists and law professors have proposed new, more
restrictive rules on price competition by dominant firms.
The new learning is finding its way into the courts as well. In a
2003 predatory pricing case, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Tenth
Circuit declared that, in light of the recent scholarship, it would no
longer approach predation claims with the skepticism that once
prevailed. Predatory pricing theories, once discredited, are regaining
respectability.
Whether or not the new scholarship has made a convincing case that
predatory pricing is a real monopolistic threat, one insight from the
law-and-economics literature of the 1970s and 1980s remains unrebutted:
punishing excessively low prices is paradoxical because the very
objective of the antitrust laws is to secure low prices for consumers.
As more and more cases of alleged predatory pricing are filed and new
theories of liability based on price discounting gain popularity, the
risk grows that predatory pricing law will result in higher prices to
consumers--the very antithesis of what antitrust law is supposed to
achieve.
WHY ALL OF THE PREDATION CLAIMS?
As noted, the Supreme Court has made it very difficult for
plaintiffs to win predatory pricing claims. Yet hundreds of such claims
have been filed since the restrictive Supreme Court decisions. Why would
plaintiffs spend the significant time and money it takes to file
predatory pricing claims if such claims are usually futile? A
substantial part of the answer is that predatory pricing plaintiffs can
"win without winning" if the mere fact of the lawsuit coerces
the defendant to soften its price competition.
The predatory pricing cause of action is a most suggestive tool for
an inefficient firm to forestall price cuts by a more efficient rival.
For several reasons, a plaintiff can strategically misuse a predatory
pricing lawsuit to force price increases by the defendant even if the
lawsuit has very little chance of succeeding on the merits.
For instance, the plaintiff can raise the defendant's costs
just by initiating expensive litigation. Defending against a predatory
pricing lawsuit is often an extremely costly proposition. Frank
Easterbrook once reported that, during the 1980s, AT&T spent $100
million per year just to defend against predation claims. It is not
uncommon for a single predation lawsuit to cost the defendant tens of
millions of dollars to litigate.
Of course, the litigation will cost the plaintiff something as
well, but it will almost always be much more expensive for the
defendant. The plaintiff may be able to hire lawyers on contingency,
whereas the defendant must pay its lawyers on an hourly basis. The
defendant will often be required to produce more documents to the
plaintiff than vice versa because the focus of the lawsuit will be on
the defendant's pricing practices. Defendants will feel compelled
to hire the most expensive lawyers and invest heavily in the defense of
even an unmeritorious case because the effects of an adverse treble
damages award on the defendant's stock price would he disastrous.
Plaintiffs, by contrast, face few such pressures.
In addition to raising rivals' costs through litigation
expenses, inefficient firms can use the threat of predatory pricing
litigation to coerce price increases from competitors because the
expected cost to the defendant of an adverse judgment is so large.
Although plaintiffs rarely win predatory pricing judgments, when they
do, the numbers are often staggering.
To illustrate, MCI won a jury verdict against AT&T that, with
trebling, would have amounted to a $1.8 billion judgment in 1980
dollars. In 2003, Kinetic Concepts won a jury verdict against
Hillenbrand Industries in a case that involved predatory pricing claims.
The jury awarded $173.6 million in damages, which would have been
automatically trebled to $520.8 million pursuant to the Clayton Act. To
put that in perspective, Hillenbrand's net income in the year
preceding the judgment was $153 million--less than a third of the amount
of the judgment. Largely from the $250 million settlement resulting from
the judgment, Hillenbrand's net income fell to $44 million the
following year.
Further, prevailing plaintiffs are automatically entitled to
recover their attorney fees from the defendant, which can add tens of
millions of dollars to the price tag of an adverse judgment. (There is
no similar provision for defendants to recover attorney fees from
unsuccessful plaintiffs).
It is not hard to see that the threat of a predatory pricing
lawsuit could cause a firm to forgo a perfectly innocent price-cut.
Litigation is an inherently unpredictable activity and there is always a
chance that the lawsuit will survive summary judgment and the jury will
award an erroneous verdict. Suppose that the chance that a frivolous
predation claim will succeed on the merits is 10 percent, that the
defendant firm would have to incur $50 million to litigate it, and that
an adverse judgment (including trebling and attorney fees) would amount
to $500 million. From the ex ante perspective, the expected cost of the
price-cut is $100 million (the expected cost of an adverse judgment is
$50 million and it will cost $50 million to defend the lawsuit
regardless of the outcome). If the expected profit increase from the
price cut is less than $100 million, the firm would forgo it and stick
with higher prices. By threatening predatory pricing litigation, a less
efficient firm may be able to prevent price cuts by a more efficient
rival.
DAVID V. GOLIATH
Even in a world in which the rate of error in adjudication was low,
firms might sometimes decide to forgo price cuts because the cost of
even an improbable finding of liability was so high. The chilling
effects of predatory pricing law are compounded by the fact that the
error rate is probably not only high but directionally tilted toward
false-positive errors.
The chief cause of this directional bias is the fact that juries
are the ultimate fact-finders in any case that makes it to trial. It
would be surprising to find that jurors actually understand the
substance of predatory pricing law when the very definition of predation
and its dements have long been, and continue to be, debated by the
brightest economic and legal minds.
A study by Case Western law professor Arthur Austin is telling.
Austin interviewed jurors in four antitrust trials, including Brooke
Group v. Brown & Williamson, the latest predatory pricing case
decided by the Supreme Court. Austin's interviews revealed that
"the jurors were overwhelmed, frustrated, and confused by testimony
well beyond their comprehension.... [A]t no time did any juror grasp--even at the margins--the law, the economics, or any other
testimony related to the allegations or defense." Austin reports,
At no time have I encountered a juror who had the foggiest
notion of what oligopoly, market power, or average
variable cost meant, much less how they applied to the
case.... Typical is the response I received when I asked a
juror whether he remembered average variable cost. The
juror replied, "Yes, explain it to me. I still don't know what
it means."
Mind you, the jury found that Brown & Williamson engaged in
predatory pricing, which required a finding that it had priced below
average variable cost. If the jury did not understand the legal test, on
what basis did it award a $148.8 judgment against Brown &
Williamson? Based on his study of the Brooke Group jury, Austin
concluded that its verdict for Liggett was based upon populist
sentiments inflamed by "smoking gun" documents from Brown
& Williamson's files "in which B&W executives made
comments like 'bury them' and 'put a lid on
Liggett.'"
If jurors are unable to understand the legal-economic requirements
of predatory pricing law, then they are largely left with a morality
play between a dominant firm, often with superior resources and files
full of "smoking gun" documents that Judge Richard Posner
calls "compelling evidence of predatory intent to the naive,"
and a smaller, often younger firm that has been damaged by the dominant
firm's behavior. Although the "damage" may have resulted
from socially beneficial price competition or the new entrant's
comparative inefficiency, all the jurors may understand or care about is
that the defendant was a large corporation that damaged a smaller
corporation through a series of tactical price cuts. In the jury box, it
is David v. Goliath.
This systematic jury bias against price-cutting by dominant firms
contributes to the chilling effect on price competition of predatory
pricing law. A firm considering a price cut in the face of a
rival's litigation threat must take into account not just the
possibility of expensive litigation, but the prospect of facing a jury
that may not understand the relevant law or the economics, but will
decide the case nonetheless.
TACIT COLLUSION
The strategic misuse of predatory pricing law is not limited to
inefficient firms seeking to create a protective pricing floor.
Efficient firms can partake of the opportunity afforded by predatory
pricing law to sustain higher prices in the market. In particular,
rent-seeking sellers can use claims of predatory pricing to facilitate
tacit collusion schemes in concentrated markets.
To see how this can happen, imagine a seller operating in an
oligopoly with four dominant firms. Suppose that the market is
characterized by fungible goods and high barriers to entry. Sellers in
such a market will often be able to price above competitive levels, but
achieving the maximum price requires some coordination, tacit or
explicit, among the firms. From the perspective of the oligopolists, the
ideal solution would be an explicit agreement on prices and output, and
elaborate policing mechanisms to ensure compliance. That, of course, is
illegal, so sellers in such markets often try to coordinate prices in
less explicit ways using tools such as information exchange programs and
subtle policing mechanisms to ensure compliance with the tacit
agreement. Antitrust cases have condemned such cooperation as unlawful
price-fixing, even though the firms never explicitly agreed on price.
Now imagine how a predatory pricing lawsuit could be used to help
organize the tacit collusion scheme in a legally privileged way. The
plaintiff firm, unhappy with price cuts by a rival, files a complaint
detailing exactly what is wrong with the defendant's price cuts and
what reasonable prices would be. Then follows a prolonged period of
discovery--often years--in which the parties exchange reams of sensitive
competitive documents and senior executives testify about their pricing
strategies, business plans, productive capacity, costs, and many more
pieces of business information that will come very handy to both sides
when considering future pricing and output decisions. While discovery
and trial takes place, a judge will be closely scrutinizing the
parties' pricing behavior and perhaps even enjoining the defendant
from lowering its prices during the pendency of the lawsuit. Several
judges have issued injunctions against defendants, prohibiting them from
lowering their prices until a final adjudication of the case. So there
we have several ingredients of a successful tacit collusion scheme:
price signaling, information exchange, policing mechanisms, and even
sanctions for deviating from supracompetitive prices.
PIE IN THE SKIES Do firms actually use predatory pricing lawsuits
to raise each other's costs or facilitate tacit collusion schemes?
It is hard to answer that question categorically because antitrust
litigation tends to be quite complex and a plaintiff's motivations
are rarely reducible to a single category. It is not difficult, however,
to find examples of predatory pricing lawsuits that were rejected on the
merits and yet apparently contributed to higher prices.
Consider the airline industry. Since deregulation in 1978, the
airline industry has seen several high-profile charges of oligopolistic
collusion. A well-known episode of attempted price-fixing involved a
1982 price-war between American Airlines and Braniff in which the
Justice Department obtained a tape recording of a conversation between
Robert Crandall, CEO of American, and Howard Putnam, CEO of Braniff, in
which Crandall encouraged Putnam to raise prices by 20 percent. In 1992,
the Justice Department sued American, Continental, Northwest, TWA,
United, and US Air, alleging that they had engaged in price signaling by
disseminating future price information in a variety of ways. The case
ended in a consent decree in which the airlines agreed to cease a number
of the challenged practices. In 2004, the Justice Department flied a
show cause petition alleging that American had violated the consent
decree by publishing future first travel dates, apparently in order to
signal price increases to competitors.
During the same period that the airline industry has ostensibly been a hotbed of oligopolistic cooperation to price at supracompetitive
levels, different airlines have allegedly been engaged in predatory
pricing. American has faced predatory pricing claims by Continental and
Northwest in 1992 and the Justice Department in 1999. Virgin Atlantic
sued British Airways on what amounted to predatory pricing charges in
1993. Other post-deregulation predation suits include Laker against
Sabena and KLM in 1983 and Laker against PanAm in 1985. Further, several
low-cost carriers have reportedly complained to the Department of
Transportation about predatory pricing by larger airlines, including
ValuJet against Delta, Frontier against United, and Reno Air against
Northwest.
What is interesting about the airline cases is that at least one of
the alleged dates of predatory pricing corresponded with periods in
which the predator and prey were supposedly engaged in oligopolistic
collusion. The government's 1992 price signaling case against
American, Continental, and Northwest (and others) concerned the same
time period as American's alleged predatory pricing campaign
against Continental and Northwest. For both of those allegations to be
true, American would have to be predating against Contintental and
Northwest at the same time as it was colluding with them. Although a
predatory pricing campaign to discipline rivals into collusion may be
plausible, the Justice Department charged that American, Continental,
and Northwest were already colluding at the time that Continental and
Northwest alleged that American launched its new, allegedly predatory,
pricing scheme. American cannot have been both predating against, and
colluding with, the same competitors at the same moment because
predation involves pricing below cost and collusion involves pricing at
supracompetitive levels.
It is possible that one or both of the claims were
mistaken--indeed, the jury found that American was not predating. It is
also possible that the allegations of collusion were correct and that
the predatory pricing case itself reinforced a tacit collusive scheme.
Northwest and Continental may have facilitated a resumption of
consciously parallel, lockstep pricing by using the predatory pricing
lawsuit as a price signal and information exchange device, combined with
a punitive raising of American's costs through expensive
litigation.
If so, the strategy seems to have worked. American announced the
challenged pricing plan on April 9, 1992, and other major carriers
quickly matched or beat American's price cut. Between April and
June, fares remained relatively fiat. Then Continental filed its
predatory pricing lawsuit in early June of 1992 and Northwest filed its
parallel suit a few days later. A few days after filing suit, Northwest
announced a 10 percent price increase. American and Continental soon
followed with price increases of their own. Between July and the end of
the year, while the predatory pricing case progressed, the major
airlines reportedly raised prices seven times, albeit with many false
starts, retreats, and delays as the oligopolistic discipline frayed by
American's April price cuts was restored. In December, while
announcing another round of price increases, Continental reported
publicly that its "objective is to get back to the fare levels that
prevailed in early April, which are fair, market-based competitive
fares." Such overt price-signaling through media comments
frequently accompanied the upward pricing movements following the filing
of the predatory pricing suits. A headline about the September fare
increases in Tour and Travel News reported (apparently without conscious
irony), "Airlines Agree on Fare-Increase Date."
There is little doubt that the airline fare war that began with
American's price cuts in April ended within weeks after Northwest
and Continental filed their predatory pricing suits. How significant a
role the predatory pricing suit played in deterring aggressive price
competition and restoring lockstep price increases is uncertain. The
predatory pricing lawsuit was not the only strategic tool available or
utilized by competitor airlines. The competitors also took their
complaint to the Senate Transportation Committee and engaged in
unabashed price signaling through the media. The predatory pricing
lawsuit, however, may have offered a unique combination of coercive
opportunities to complement other strategic tools, including raising a
rival's costs through litigation expense, the threat of a
substantial adverse judgment, and detailed information exchange in
discovery.
And the predatory pricing case may have taught American a lesson.
After the jury returned a verdict for American in the predatory pricing
case in the summer of 1993, American CEO Robert Crandall--the same CEO
caught on tape encouraging Braniff to raise its prices--stated publicly
that American "probably won't be attempting that type of
leadership again."
MULTIPRODUCT DISCOUNTING: THE NEXT FRONTIER
Just as conventional predatory pricing theories are being
rehabilitated, a new theory of anticompetitive exclusion through price
discounting is becoming popular in antitrust circles. A number of recent
lawsuits and academic papers have explored the possibility that a
diversified firm could offer customers discounts contingent upon the
purchase of goods in multiple markets and thereby exclude a
single-product firm that sold only one of the products covered by the
package discount.
The case that defines this theory for the moment is LePage's
v. 3M. 3M is a diversified manufacturer of various household and
industrial products. LePage's competes with 3M for sales of
private-label transparent tape--a generic equivalent of 3M's
well-known Scotch tape brand. In 1995, 3M began a rebate program called
the Partnership Growth Fund (PFG) that incentivized 3M's customers,
large retailers like Staples, Wal-Mart, and Target, to purchase minimum
quantities from six 3M divisions. In order to receive the maximum 2
percent rebate, a customer needed to increase its overall purchases from
3M as well as its purchases in a minimum number of specified product
categories.
LePage's alleged that, as a result of the 3M program, it lost
private-label transparent tape sales (even though it still had a 67
percent market share in the private-label side of the transparent tape
market) and was in danger of being forced out of business. In 2002, a
Philadelphia jury found that 3M had used the program unlawfully to
maintain a monopoly in the transparent tape market, and awarded
LePage's $22,828,899 in damages (before trebling).
In an initial three-judge decision in 2002, the U.S. Court of
Appeals for the Third Circuit reversed, finding that LePage's had
not shown that 3M's bundled rebates were anticompetitive. Among
other things, the two-judge majority noted that LePage's had not
shown that it would have had to price below cost in order to compensate
customers for the 3M rebates they would lose if they purchased private
label transparent tape from LePage's instead of 3M.
The original panel's way of assessing the bundled discount
program was quite reasonable. Under ordinary predatory pricing rules,
the plaintiff must show that the defendant priced below its cost in
order to establish liability. If the plaintiff is as efficient as the
defendant, then if the defendant prices above cost, the plaintiff cannot
be driven out of business because the plaintiff could profitably match
the defendant's prices. The same logic should follow in a case
involving discounts spread across multiple product lines.
Suppose that, for litigation purposes, the following exercise was
undertaken: Calculate the total discounts that a customer would forgo
from the defendant on all product lines if it bought from the plaintiff.
Reallocate those discounts to the single market in which the plaintiff
operates. Finally, inquire whether, after deducting all of the forgone
discounts, the effective price in the competitive market was below cost.
If the answer is no--if the effective price in the competitive market
was still above cost--then there is no reason to impose liability for
the bundled discount any more than there would be to impose liability
for an above-cost price cut in a single market. An equally efficient
competitor should still be able to compete.
Regrettably, in a 2003 en banc decision, the full Third Circuit saw
it differently. In a 7-3 decision, the court affirmed the jury verdict.
Critically, the court found it irrelevant that the exercise described in
the preceding paragraph had been undertaken and it was shown that 3M had
not priced below cost even if all of the discounts on other product
lines were reallocated to the transparent tape market. According to the
court, multiproduct bundling is completely different from single-market
predatory pricing and the cost/revenue comparisons required in predatory
pricing cases are not required in cases involving discounts across
multiple markets.
So what is the standard of illegality for bundled discounts? In the
Third Circuit, at least, the answer is completely murky. As the
Solicitor General pointed out in an amicus curiae Supreme Court brief,
"the court of appeals failed to explain precisely why the evidence
supported a jury verdict of liability in this case, including what
precisely rendered 3M's conduct unlawful."
The LePage's decision has caused well-founded alarm in the
business community. Bundled discounting--what economists call mixed
bundling--is ubiquitous and generally beneficial to consumers. If
liability can be imposed on dominant firms that offer bundled discounts
without any clear rules for when such discounts will be found
exclusionary, sellers will need to be concerned about potential exposure
from offering such discounts.
Not surprisingly, given the allure of treble damages awards,
LePage's has created a cottage industry of lawsuits in the Third
Circuit involving claims of bundled discounts, including AMD's
heavily publicized monopolization lawsuit against Intel and
Broadcom's lawsuit against Qualcomm. A number of other mixed
bundling cases, some of which predate the LePage's decision, are
pending. Bundled discounting, it is fair to say, is under heavy attack
as a commercial practice.
So not only is single-market predatory pricing being revitalized as
an antitrust theory, but new theories of ill-defined liability are being
opened for price discounting. And, just as with single-market predation
claims, there is evidence that at least some of the recent bundled
discounting claims are strategic efforts to prevent aggressive price
competition by larger rivals. Tellingly, in virtually none of the recent
bundled discounting cases was the plaintiff actually excluded from the
market. Many of the plaintiffs had very significant market shares in the
relevant markets or had experienced growth and profitability despite the
existence of the bundled discount program. Unfortunately, the symptoms
of strategic misuse of antitrust law to prevent price-discounting are
spreading to new frontiers.
RESOLVING THE PARADOX
Over 25 years ago, Frank Easterbrook advocated abolishing the right
of action for predatory pricing on the view that, even if predatory
pricing sometimes occurs, allowing the legal claim to be asserted does
more harm than good. Time has vindicated Easterbrook's claim, yet
predatory pricing remains as popular--and strategically misused--a
theory as ever. What can be done about this?
Apart from simply disallowing any claim based on excessively low
prices, a number of steps could be taken to minimize the abuse of
predatory pricing law. One step would be to eliminate competitor
standing to assert such claims. Most predatory pricing claims are
brought not by injured consumers, but by competitors. Competitors have
unique incentives to misuse predatory pricing law to chill price
competition. They want to see higher prices both in the short run and in
the long run.
The law tolerates a competitor's complaint that the
defendant's prices were too low because of the further allegation
that the low prices would eventually lead to higher prices. But the law
does not require proof of actual higher prices. In an attempted
monopolization through predatory pricing case, it is sufficient to prove
that a defendant's low prices created a dangerous probability of
subsequent higher prices. Thus, a competitor-plaintiff is often in the
position of asserting that a defendant's prices were
anticompetitively low merely based on the speculation that, left
unchecked, the defendant would have driven the plaintiff from the market
and raised its prices--even though that never actually happened.
Giving firms standing to challenge their rivals' prices as too
low on the theory that higher prices might eventually emerge is like
asking the fox to guard the henhouse. Consumers--the intended
beneficiaries of antitrust law--have exactly the opposite incentives as
competitors. They prefer sustainably low prices and therefore make far
better-intentioned predation enforcers than business rivals of the
"predator." If predatory pricing were a frequent and
successful enterprise, one would expect to see many class-action
lawsuits by overcharged consumers. Such lawsuits are rare, which is
probably more a testament to the absence of successful predation schemes
than to consumers' deficiencies as enforcers.
If competitors are allowed to continue asserting predatory pricing
claims, then two simple changes in the law would help deter strategic
misuse. First, attorney fee shifting could become bilateral. If
unsuccessful plaintiffs were required to pay defendants' attorney
fees, filing unmeritorious predatory pricing lawsuits in order to coerce
the defendant to raise its prices would become significantly less
attractive.
Second, treble damages could be disallowed in predatory pricing
cases. The economic rationale for treble damages in antitrust cases is
that because many antitrust violations will go undetected, the magnitude
of the penalty must be increased in order to deter violations. While
that rationale may be sensible with respect to price-fixing cartels, it
has no application to predatory pricing. Low prices are easy to spot.
Indeed, most of the recent theories that have attempted to rehabilitate
the status of predatory pricing as a serious threat have relied on
reputational effects from prior acts of predation to discourage new
entry in the future. If predatory pricing is supposedly effective
because everyone knows that it is not worth entering a price war with
the predator, there is little reason to allow treble damages on the
theory that the predation might go undetected. Detrebling damages in
predatory pricing cases would eliminate some of the potency of predatory
pricing claims as means to chill price competition.
CONCLUSION
Frank Easterbrook once remarked that the reason that there are so
many theories about what predatory pricing schemes look like is much the
same as the reason there were once so many theories about what dragons
look like. One need not believe, with Easterbrook, that predatory
pricing never occurs to believe that legal efforts to stop predation
often do more harm than good.
To be sure, there are market failures that allow firms to obtain
monopoly power through undesirable means. But there are also legal
failures that allow firms to abuse well-intentioned liability rules to
stymie the very competitive forces the rules were intended to support.
Much of one's view about the appropriateness of penalties for
excessively low prices depends on whether one believes that market
failures or legal failures will generally be more harmful. The history
of predatory pricing law suggests that, when it comes to price
discounts, legal failures have done far more harm than market failures.
READINGS
* "3M's Bundled Rebates: An Economic Perspective,"
by Daniel L. Rubinfeld. University of Chicago Law Review, Vol. 72
(2005).
* The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself, 2nd ed., by
Robert H. Bork. New York, N.Y.: The Free Press, 1993.
* "Misuses of the Antitrust Laws: The Competitor
Plaintiff," by Edward A. Synder and Thomas E. Kauper. Michigan Law
Review, Vol. 90 (1991).
* "Mixed Bundling, Profit Sacrifice. and Consumer
Welfare." by Daniel A. Crane. Forthcoming (2006).
* "Multiproduct Discounting: A Myth of Nonprice
Predation." by Daniel A. Crane. University of Chicago Law Review.
Vol. 72 (2005).
* "The Paradox of Predatory Pricing," by Daniel A. Crane.
Cornell Law Review. Vol. 91 (2005).
* "Predatory Strategies and Counterstrategies," by Frank
H. Easterbrook. University of Chicago Law Review. Vol. 48 (1981).
* "Use of Antitrust to Subvert Competition," by William
1. Baumol and Janusz A. Ordover. Journal of Law and Economics. Vol. 28
(1985).
This article is condensed from Crane's "The Paradox of
Predatory Pricing," Cornell Law Review, 2005, and his other recent
work on bundled discounts.
BY DANIEL A. CRANE
Benjamin N. Cardozo School of Law
Daniel A. Crane is assistant professor of law at the Benjamin N.
Cardozo School of Law, Yeshiva University. He may he contacted by e-mail
at dcrane@yu.edu.