Treating the unserious seriously.
Brannon, Ike
IN THE DEFENSE OF THE ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF REGULATION By Robert
Hahn 128 pages; Washington, D.C.: AEI Press, 2005
ESTIMATING THE VALUE OF a statistical life (VSL) has become an
industry unto itself. Hundreds of studies have been done using different
techniques, countries, sampling methods, and methodologies. There have
also been a number of meta-analyses attempting to make some sense of the
morass.
The impetus for this research is policymakers' desire to have
a value that they can assign to life-saving regulatory changes based on
some aspect of reality so that their regulations can survive the rigors
of cost-benefit analysis. There is a real demand from government
agencies for some numbers that they can defend, and the Environmental
Protection Agency, alone, has spent millions of dollars on grants to
help researchers tackle the problem.
The debate over the issue of the appropriate VSL has been
contentious. Some people (myself included) feel that the EIA has, at
times, attempted to tilt the results of their research in favor of a
high VSL by de-emphasizing some studies and commissioning new ones when
previous ones have not given them the desired (i.e., appropriately high)
number.
Their motivation for wanting to do so is straightforward: The
higher the VSL, the easier it is for regulations to pass muster and
survive the judgment of the Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA). The people who work for agencies such as the EPA generally argue
that government ought to err on the side of too much safety even when
the required regulations may cost society greatly. They also suggest
that companies are generally quite adept at adjusting to the myriad
regulations and minimizing the costs of meeting them, and that the
estimated costs of new regulations are often overstated.
Each side in this debate (and the people somewhere along the middle
of the spectrum) offers studies to support its position, and in this
cacophony a consensus is slowly starting to emerge. Robert Hahn has
played an important role in this debate with his cogent and voluminous
writings on regulatory economics and the merits of quantifying the
results of regulation with cost-benefit analysis. The various tables
published by the Office of Management and Budget that do this have
improved tremendously since the practice began, and it has shed light on
the effectiveness of our regulatory state. The results have not always
been pretty, but they represent a solid first step toward improving the
situation.
However, a small contingent of regulators, professors, and gadflies
rejects this debate entirely, arguing against the very premise of
cost-benefit analysis. (See "The New Challenge to Cost-Benefit
Analysis," Fall 2005.) They believe that the costs and benefits of
a regulation are often difficult or impossible to quantify, that there
are vested interests trying to impede regulations (and apparently none
advocating regulations), and that the distribution of the benefits and
costs are such that it is the poor and oppressed who benefit the most
from the regulations deemed ineffective by the regulators. Given those
myriad flaws, they argue, society should allow the regulators of the
various government agencies, who are usually intimately familiar with
the industry they are regulating, to use their own best judgment to
issue the necessary regulations that would ensure the optimal amount of
environmental and physical safety.
This group coalesces around an entity called the Center for
Progressive Reform, and they have put Robert Hahn in their crosshairs,
with good reason: If anyone represents the antithesis of what the
opponents of cost-benefit analysis believe, it is he.
REGULATORY BIAS? In the Defense of the Economic Analysis of
Regulation is Hahn's rebuttal to their attacks and charges against
him. By using an entire monograph to rebut their critiques, he perhaps
gives them too much credit by addressing their work directly. There is
little doubt to the objective reader that he has landed a telling blow
with his tome.
People who have worked in the regulatory arena simply put no
credence in claims of anti-regulatory bias. In reality, stopping the
path of a regulation often takes Herculean political strength that
simply cannot be mustered for something as arcane as the design of tire
pressure monitors. The firestorm that even a slight delay in issuing a
regulation can bring can be so intense as to deter the most dogged
bureaucrat.
A coworker of mine at OIRA who opposed a mandate that all children
flying be put in safety seats was told by an FAA official the day after
a plane crash killed an infant that the child's blood was on his
hands. When told that such a mandate would result in more children
traveling long distances in less-safe automobiles, the regulator simply
replied that the first "a" in FAA stands for
"aviation" and that what happens on highways is not that
agency's responsibility.
As anyone who has worked on regulatory issues knows, government
agencies are not staffed with objective bureaucrats. The sympathies and
paths to career advancement and outside pressures tend to go in one
direction, toward more regulation. What is more, scarcely anyone arrives
at the EPA without a sense of mission that he is going to fix things.
One of my coworkers explained to me on my first day working at OIRA that
working at the EPA--the prime generator of regulations that go through
OIRA--is more like a religion than a job for many. My acquaintances at
the EPA do not disagree with that sentiment.
Most people at the EPA consider environmental groups such as the
Natural Resources Defense Council to be their stakeholders. In my
experience, they make no bones about it. They are as much beholden to
those entities as the typical Hill staffer is to any other lobby--they
are sympathetic to many of the things the environmental groups are
trying to do, they form social relationships with each other, and hope
to some day get a job with the groups when they leave the government.
On my first day at OIRA, I visited EPA headquarters to attend a
meeting with a coworker just to see how things worked. The meeting was
with a contingent of EPA staffers and began with the ranking EPA worker
issuing a rather loud warning and glaring in our direction that the
meeting was strictly off-the-record and that everyone had better keep
quiet about the proceedings. By the time my coworker and I had returned
to our offices 45 minutes after the meeting had ended, the minutes of
the meeting had been posted on the Web page of one of the environmental
groups.
NECESSARY WORK Hahn's monograph is a careful defense of the
utterly defensible. Having to spend pages to support the idea of
discounting benefits that accrue in the future will seem to most readers
of Regulation to be utterly superfluous, much like defending the
standardization of time zones. Economists who are unfamiliar with the
literature may be dumbfounded that people actually believe that
discounting applies to some investments but not investments in health or
safety.
Another criticism of regulatory analysis that the people with the
Center for Progressive Reform level at Hahn regards the range of values
for VSL that he uses in his analyses. On this matter, Hahn uses a range
between $3 million and $7 million. That actually covers the range of the
mainstream on this issue--the EPA prefers the latter number and cites a
meta-analysis by Kip Viscusi and Joe Aldy as support, while other
agencies use a number closer to $3 million, citing another meta-analysis
done by Janusz Mrozek and Laura Taylor. In reality, the actual number
used by the agencies is closer to the upper end of Hahn's range;
when the cost-benefit analysis looks close, the tie always goes to the
regulation. Indeed, Hahn shows the robustness of the cost-benefit
analysis tables by calculating the costs and benefits with different
discount rates and VSL estimates, and showing that the proportion of
regulations passing muster does not vary more than five percentage
points.
Other complaints of Hahn's work are even more egregious. Hahn
finds it necessary to rebut complaints that he ignores the effects of
inflation by carefully pointing out that the choice of a base year is
irrelevant when making comparisons of real values.
Hahn is at his best in defending how economists quantify
qualitative benefits as well as explaining in general how regulatory
scorecards work. In this area, the complaints of the Progressive Reform
contingent have some merit and need to be carefully addressed, and Hahn
does just that. Many of the benefits of regulation do not come with a
price tag on them; to tease out the true worth to society of various
improvements can be difficult or close to impossible to do in a way that
satisfies everyone. When a proposed rule has considerable non-monetary
benefits, regulators generally acknowledge this and take it into
consideration, even if the benefits do not appear in the cost-benefit
league tables published by the OMB.
Economists, at their best, quantify the previously unquantifiable.
What made John Morrall's Regulation article ("A Review of the
Record," November/ December 1986) so important was that he informed
so many of us for the first time of the enormous opportunity costs that
regulations imposed on the economy. Most of what has been done in this
area since then has been, in essence, an elaboration of Morrall's
early work, with a good deal of it being done by Morrall himself.
IMPROVING THE DATA Regulation in the United States often devolves
into a contest between the regulators at the various agencies and OIRA,
which theoretically has the final say over whether a regulation gets
issued. The analysts at OIRA evaluate regulations to see whether they
make sense from a cost-benefit perspective. It is an intensely political
game, needless to say. During the last years of the Clinton
administration, virtually no regulations proposed by federal agencies
were ever returned by OIRA, an abrogation of duties that the
administration defended by saying that they let the agencies know early
on what would be acceptable to them. Frustrated OIRA analysts referred
to this as "preemptive caving." Even during the best of times,
the political will needed to combat a well-meaning but cost-ineffective
rule is simply not there.
Even during the Bush administration, returning a rule is not easy.
In 2002, an attempt to void a ridiculous Department of Agriculture rule
designed to increase the prices of some obscure fruit grown in
California in order to increase farmer income by $20 million generated
so much heat that it eventually resulted in a meeting between the head
of the OMB and the head of the USDA on the issue, with the USDA getting
its way.
There is a lot of research pertinent to cost-benefit analysis, and
agencies are finally starting to take serious the need to apply some
rigor to the calculations of benefits and costs of regulatory actions.
Thanks to the work of economists like Robert Hahn, the field is
improving its ability to quantify vague but very real costs and benefits
produced from regulations. The idea that we should not bother with any
evaluation of our regulatory endeavors is a disturbingly luddite idea
that does not deserve to be seriously considered. But Hahn, ever the
scholar, gives it serious attention and dismembers it fully.
Ike Brannon is an economist for the Joint Economic Committee of the
U.S. Congress.
The views expressed in this article do not necessarily reflect the
views of the JEC or the U.S. Congress.