Conservation cartels: competition policy can conflict with environmental protection.
Adler, Jonathan H.
IN THE 1930s, FRANK MANAKA SOUGHT WORK as a fisherman off the coast
of Monterey. California. He chartered a boat but was unable to market
his catch. Local canneries would not purchase fish from him. In 1940, he
filed suit against the Monterey Sardine Industries, Inc., a cooperative
association of fishing boat owners, and the Del Mar Canning Company for
allegedly conspiring to set prices and restrict entry into the
California sardine fishery. Under an agreement between the association,
the local canneries, and the local fishermen's union, fine
association set the price for which its members' fish were sold to
canneries and reduction plants. The canneries, in turn, agreed to
purchase fish exclusively from members of Monterey Sardine who were
assigned to it by the association. Manaka was not a member, so he could
not sell his fish and so he sued.
Although Monterey Sardine may have operated like the typical
collusive cartel, it served both pecuniary and conservation purposes. On
the one hand, it increased members' profits by increasing fish
prices and restricting entry by non-local fishers. On the other, it
helped to conserve fish stocks by limiting the harvest. Challenged by
Manaka, Monterey Sardine Industries was found guilty of conspiracy in
restraint of trade under the Sherman Act. The federal district court
held that the association was "not freed from the restrictive
provisions of the anti-trust act" merely because it sought
"the conservation of important food fish." In other words, the
association's conduct was no less exclusionary because it served,
in part, to conserve fish stocks.
In the 1930s, the California sardine fishery was at its peak,
yielding over 500,000 tons of fish per year. By the early 1950s, the
annual catch had dropped to under 20,000 tons as the fishery began to
collapse. It is possible that the sardine fishery's decline was
unavoidable. Commercial harvesting might have depleted the fishery even
if Monterey Sardine Industries' collusive arrangement had been
permitted to survive. Changing environmental conditions might have made
the collapse inevitable. Then again, perhaps if it were not for
antitrust enforcement, this tragedy of the marine commons might have
been avoided. The existence of a private association capable of ensuring
the local fish catch was maintained at a sustainable level might have
saved the fishery. Busting up this "conservation cartel" might
have made the fishery more "competitive" in a narrow sense,
while at the same time undermining the equally important goal of
resource conservation.
Off the California coast and elsewhere, fishermen who sought to
organize such "conservation cartels" to manage fisheries and
control catches were prosecuted for antitrust violations. At the same
time, the depletion of ocean fisheries continued apace, to the point
where fishery depletion has become one of the greatest environmental
problems on the planet. Antitrust law, though well-intentioned, may have
discouraged--if not in some cases actually prohibited--private
arrangements that could ensure the sustainable utilization of marine
resources.
THE MARINE COMMONS
Conservation of marine fisheries presents the archetypal "commons" problem, most famously depicted by ecologist Garrett
Hardin in "The Tragedy of the Commons." Hardin described the
fate of a common pasture, unowned and available to all. In such a
situation, it is in each herder's self-interest to maximize his use
of the commons at the expense of the community at large. Each herder
captures all of the benefit from adding one more animal to his herd; the
costs of over grazing the pasture, however, are distributed amongst
every pasture user. When all the herders respond to the incentives
created by the open-access nature of the commons, the pasture is
overgrazed. "Each man is locked into a system that compels him to
increase his herd without limit--in a world that is limited,"
Hardin wrote. The pursuit of self-interest in an open-access commons
results in a tragedy; "Freedom in a commons brings ruin to
all."
This analysis applies well to most marine fisheries; indeed, it was
described and documented by fishery economists over a decade before
Hardin's influential essay. So long as there is open-access to the
fishery, each fisher has an incentive to catch as much as possible, even
beyond the point of sustainability. The incentives for such behavior are
strong in the fishery context because the marginal cost of an active
fisherman increasing his effort is often quite small compared to the
potential economic reward. Fishers do not benefit from self-restraint
because none have any assurance that other participants in the fishery
will follow suit.
Open-access fisheries have suffered from the tragedy of the commons
just as Hardin would have predicted. On the open seas,
overcapacity--what many describe as "too many boats chasing too few
fish"--is the norm, resulting in substantial depletion of fishery
stocks worldwide. Approximately 65 percent of fisheries are fully
exploited or overexploited, according to the United Nations Food and
Agriculture Organization, and that number continues to climb. An
additional 10 percent of fisheries are "significantly
depleted."
The plight of domestic fisheries is no less grave despite several
decades of federal regulation. In 2003, the National Marine Fisheries
Service (NMFS) reported that 66 fish stocks were subject to overfishing and another 86 species were already overfished. In the same report, the
NMFS acknowledged that out of the 932 fish stocks under federal
management, the status of nearly 700 is unknown. While the NMFS reports
the number of healthy fish species has increased in recent years, such
gains have come at tremendous cost to local fishing communities faced
with fishery closings and other stringent conservation measures.
Populations of once-abundant food fish such as cod, haddock, and
flounder may be near collapse.
PRIVATE PROPERTY The initial choice of solutions to the commons
problem, as described by Hardin, is between political controls and some
form of private property. "The tragedy of the commons ... is
averted by private property, or something for many like it," he
explained. But where private property is lacking, the commons can only
be saved by "mutual coercion, mutually agreed upon." As Hardin
presented it, conservation of the commons requires privatization or
government regulation. In either case, the aim is the same--to control
access and limit overuse of the underlying resource.
Private property tends to avert the commons problem because
property owners have a substantial incentive to maximize the value of
the resource in question. This necessarily requires accounting for the
value that others place on the resource and the value of sustaining the
resource over time. The benefits of property ownership do not depend on
each owner acting solely, or even primarily, with a profit motive,
however. In addition to providing incentives for greater resource
stewardship, property rights also foster private ordering by reducing
the transaction costs associated with negotiating over remaining
externalities.
Despite the potential benefits from property rights, individuated
ownership in fisheries is generally lacking. Many fish species are
mobile across vast expanses and access is difficult to monitor. Those
factors, among others, make it particularly costly to define and enforce
property rights in the marine context. There are some exceptions,
however, such as privately owned oyster beds, and a handful of countries
have moved toward property-based fishery management regimes known as
"individual transferable quotas" or "individual fishing
quotas." Nonetheless, individuated private property rights in
fisheries are the exception.
COLLECTIVE ASSOCIATIONS Where property rights in fisheries exist,
they tend to be collective or "common property" rights. As
Margaret McKean and Elinor Ostrom observed, "Common property
regimes are a way of privatizing the rights to something without
dividing it into pieces." Typically, such regimes evolved where the
marine resources require greater control and more efficient use, but
other factors make individuated ownership too costly or otherwise
culturally undesirable. In such cases, the rules governing the use of
the fishery are somewhat informal, often arising out of local custom or
community practice. In other cases, there have been efforts to adopt
formal collective rules to limit catches and conserve the underlying
resource. In each case, the management regimes have evolved over time in
an effort to increase the returns to the users of the resource.
Common property and other "collective" approaches to
fishery management appear to have been quite successful where they have
emerged. Such arrangements often evolved over time so as to facilitate
both the exploitation and conservation of the resource in question.
Today, some fishing communities have turned to various cooperative
approaches, including common property, to help rationalize fishery
management. Collective associations also may have a comparative
advantage against government agencies in regulating fishing activity,
particularly in the development, acquisition, and distribution of
relevant information about fish stocks, fishing activity, and the like.
In New Zealand, holders of individual fishing quotas have begun to
collaborate to conserve fish stocks by, among other things, monitoring
catch levels and supporting fishery research.
REGULATION Despite the potential benefits of property-based fishery
management regimes, the dominant approach to fishery conservation--where
conservation has been attempted at all--has been government regulation.
In practice, such regulations turn the fishery from an open-access
resource into a "regulated open-access" resource, and the
results have been little better than one would expect in the open-access
commons. Fishers operating under "regulated open access" have
little incentive to steward the underlying resource or support
sustainable regulatory measures. Even where fishery management decisions
are made by "expert" administrators, resource users typically
view longrun decisions as "substantially unpredictable and
unresponsive." The lack of a concrete property interest in the
fishery means that individual fishers have no expectation that
sustainable management will inure to their benefit. Thus, they push
regulatory entities to allow higher harvest rates. This problem is
compounded by the scientific uncertainty inherent in fishery
assessments, as this provides fishers with an excuse to push for less
conservative catch limits.
Fishery regulations have typically taken the form of limits on
season length, boat size, equipment, and even total seasonal catch. None
have worked particularly well, largely because they fail to alter the
open-access nature of the resource. Season limitations produce a
"race to fish" as fishers seek to catch as much as possible
before the fishery is closed. The results are rampant overcapitalization and a destructive "derby" system in which each fisher races to
catch as much as he or she can before the season closes. Mandates on the
type of equipment that can be used--an effort to control total catch by
mandating that fishers use less-efficient means of catching
fish--encourage fishers to increase their investment in additional
vessels or gear to compensate for the efficiency losses. Efforts to
protect fisheries by directly controlling entry have not fared much
better. License systems may limit the number of boats of firms in the
fishery, but they do not control the amount of effort. As with season
limitations, license limits also tend to encourage overcapitalization
and the "race to fish." The regulated commons seems no less
prone to tragedy than Hardin's uncontrolled one.
CONSERVATION VS. COLLUSION
Where formal private property institutions are absent, users of
marine commons may nonetheless seek to organize themselves into
communities or associations--what could be called "conservation
cartels"--to manage and maintain the marine commons. The
arrangements can be seen as an effort to define and enforce
quasi-communal property rights where such rights are absent. In the
commercial context, fishery associations often organize to limit the
catch. The limits are often indirect, achieved through the setting of
minimum prices or the exclusion of outsiders, as the impetus for such
measures is higher profit for the fishery rather than its sustainable
utilization over time, and enforcement costs preclude more direct
measures. Irrespective of the motivation that drives the formation of
such associations, the impact on the fishery is the same. Private
associations that limit the catch can help ensure the fishing practices
remain sustainable over time. Nonetheless, such environmentally
beneficial arrangements are subject to antitrust prosecution.
Resource conservation requires limiting consumption to sustainable
levels. The number offish caught in a given season cannot be greater
than the regenerative capacity of the fishery, or fish populations will
decline. Fishery output must be restricted. Yet antitrust law is
inherently suspect of private arrangements that restrict output. When
harvests are restricted, prices will increase above competitive levels.
In economic terms, conservation may yield monopoly rents for producers.
Private actors who seek to protect environmental resources by agreeing
to limit the exploitation of the resource are doing precisely what
antitrust law forbids. From the perspective of resource conservation, we
recognize the value of conserving a natural resource by restraining
consumption to sustainable levels. From the antitrust perspective, any
agreement or association that seeks to restrict output or otherwise
raise prices above their competitive levels is a pernicious market
influence to be expunged. In short, what conservation demands, antitrust
condemns.
Beginning in the late 1930s, there were several private and public
prosecutions of fishermen's unions and other cooperative efforts to
limit fishery exploitation. While in many, if not all, of those cases
the motivation for adopting measures to limit catches was pecuniary
(i.e., the fishers sought higher prices for their goods), the
conservation potential of such arrangements was evident. At a time when
fishery conservation had yet to become a matter of great public concern,
fishers adopted means to limit the fish catch to sustainable levels.
Despite those potential conservation benefits, the conservation
cartels were uniformly held per se illegal arrangements under the
Sherman Antitrust Act. Today, antitrust law continues to limit
collaboration among fishers in regulated fisheries, although some
fishing cooperatives have escaped antitrust condemnation.
The application of per se rules in the context of resource
conservation is a potential problem because what antitrust enforcers
fear--agreements that restrain output--is precisely what conservation
demands. When a monopolist or cartel restricts output, it is harmful to
consumers because it tends to increase prices and reduce consumer
welfare. When a conservationist reduces output, however, it can be
beneficial to consumers because it sustains a valuable resource.
Conservation of a depletable resource requires limiting consumption.
Such limits will tend to increase prices by lowering the market supply
of the resource, while at the same time preventing future price
increases by ensuring a long-term supply of the resource in question. By
reducing consumption in the short run, conservation can actually
increase consumption in the long run and therefore enhance consumer
welfare. Agreements among resource users may also help to overcome
free-rider problems or otherwise facilitate beneficial cooperation. In
this sense, such agreements are efficient (even if they increase price
or reduce output) as they address some of the inefficiencies resulting
from the existence of a common pool resource. Nonetheless, conservation
agreements can run afoul of antitrust law's prohibitions. As a
result, antitrust law may be inhibiting the evolution and development of
voluntary associations and community-based conservation measures that
conserve marine resources.
THE CONSERVATION CARTELS
Manaka v. Monterey Sardine Industries was not an isolated case. In
the 1930s and 1940s, there were several antitrust actions against
fishers' unions throughout the country. In some cases, the suits
were brought by government authorities. In others, private plaintiffs
used the antitrust statutes to seek treble damages against the
defendants. In case after case, the courts found against the
fishers' associations and condemned their cooperative efforts as
collusive attempts to restrain trade in seafood products.
In California, for example, the federal government successfully
prosecuted Local 36 of the International Fishermen & Allied Workers
of America for conspiracy to "restrain trade" in fresh fish
and crustaceans. Approximately 75 percent of the fishers operating out
of southern California were members of Local 36. Members of the union
were convicted of setting minimum prices for which they would sell
seafood to local dealers, agreeing to sell their catch solely to those
dealers who would contract with the union and engaging in various
tactics, including boycotts and picketing, to induce dealers to contract
with the union. The union ultimately sought to prevent non-members from
fishing off the coast of southern California and selling their catch in
southern California ports, thereby enabling the union to control the
catch and charge higher prices. Local 36, like the union defendants in
most of the fishery cases, unsuccessfully sought to demonstrate that
fishers' unions were subject to antitrust law exemptions provided
to labor unions and certain types of agricultural cooperatives,
including fishing cooperatives.
The indictment of Local 36 acknowledged that "except for the
illegal restraints described hereinafter, a much greater volume of fresh
fish and crustaceans would have been brought to the fishing ports.., and
sold, processed, and distributed." Irrespective of whether the
restrictions were adopted with conservation in mind, they had the same
effect as would have conservation measures on the fishery: they reduced
the volume offish caught. Yet this was part of Local 36's crime. By
reducing output, Local 36 may have been helping to conserve fisheries
off the Pacific Coast, but they were also "prevent[ing] the public
from receiving a normal and usual supply of fresh fish" and
maintaining non-competitive prices. Whether this had broader economic
impacts on fish markets was immaterial, as was whether the contract
price was "reasonable." As the court noted, "Unless
specifically authorized by legislation, a conspiracy to fix prices is in
and of itself a violation" of the Sherman Act. Conservation or
other benefits were immaterial: "No inquiry as to substantiality,
directness, effectiveness, or reasonableness of restraint is
permitted."
The fact that collusive arrangements among fishers and processors
could have positive environmental impacts has been acknowledged by
reviewing courts--and explicitly deemed irrelevant for purposes of the
antitrust analysis. As the court made explicit in the Manaka case:
Such an association as that of the boat owners is not
freed from the restrictive provisions of the anti-trust
act, because they profess in the interest of conservation
of important food fish to regulate the price and the
manner of taking such fish unauthorized by legislation
and uncontrolled by proper authority.
While the government may sanction collective efforts to control
output or increase prices, the courts deemed independent conservation
efforts tantamount to the defendant unions "taking the law into
their own hands."
The fact that fishery users are driven by their pursuit of profit
to create associations and adopt measures that could facilitate the
long-term conservation of ocean fisheries is not, as of yet, a
consideration in the application of antitrust laws. Rather, as the
Supreme Court noted in another context, "the interest of the public
in the preservation of competition is the primary consideration."
Indeed, some courts viewed private cooperative efforts to reduce fish
harvests as presumptively suspect. In Columbia River Packers Association
v. Hinton, a private antitrust action for damages against the Pacific
Coast Fishermen's Union, the court suggested that to allow private
associations to conserve fish stocks without government approval would
unduly threaten the public's right to have fish:
In any year when defendant's members did not 'choose
to fish', how would the consuming public get its needs
of salmon, tuna, and other marine products from North
Pacific waters? Since the union's contract does not guarantee
a supply of fish, where would the canneries get
fish, having agreed to look to the union for their sole
supply? Surely reasonable men will agree that the public's
interest in an important item of food supply should
not be put in such jeopardy.
Left out of the court's analysis was any consideration of
where the "consuming public" might "get its needs"
of fish should unrestrained harvests produce unsustainable levels of
consumption in Pacific fisheries. Surely, higher-priced fish are
preferable to no fish at all.
GCSOA Perhaps the best know antitrust prosecution of a fishery
association involved the Gulf Coast Shrimpers and Oystermans Association
(GCSOA). In the 1930s, shrimpers and oystermen operating along the
Mississippi coast created the GCSOA to increase their revenues by
controlling prices and limiting entry. The GCSOA entered into contracts
with local shrimp and oyster packers and canners whereby all association
members would sell their shrimp and oyster catch to contracting packers
and canners. In return, the packers and canners agreed to purchase all
of the catch offered by association members and to provide other
services. Some of the packers owned boats of their own that also abided
by the association's rules.
The federal government brought suit against the GCSOA for violating
the Sherman Antitrust Act. Specifically, the government alleged the
association prohibited its members from selling shrimp and oysters below
set prices and barred participating packers and canners from purchasing
catches below the set price or purchasing the catch of non-member
fishers. Violators were subject to fines, suspension of membership, and
forfeiture of proceeds from the offending catch. The GCSOA also
encouraged picketing and boycotting of non-participating packers and
canners. On this evidence, the GCSOA and several of its officers were
found guilty of antitrust violations.
Although the GCSOA engaged in proscribed conduct, it is not at all
clear that the union's activities were anticompetitive or otherwise
harmed consumer welfare. In their study of the case, Ronald Johnson and
Gary Libecap found that the union explicitly sought to alter the
harvesting practices of its members. The union set a floor on shrimp
prices based upon shrimp size, specifically the number of tails per
pound. This price was generally greater than prevailing market prices
for small shrimp. This discouraged the catching of smaller shrimp, so
shrimpers shifted their harvests to later in the season when shrimp are
larger and worth more. It also served to lessen the overall shrimp
catch, as shrimpers were not driven to catch more lower-value shrimp to
cover their expenses. Interestingly enough, Libecap notes, union price
floors for larger shrimp were generally no higher than the prevailing
market price, suggesting that the challenged arrangements did not have
an anticompetitive effect.
Until the arrangement was struck down, it was apparently successful
at discouraging the harvesting and sale of smaller, less-mature shrimp
in Mississippi. The state's shrimp prices were generally higher
than those in neighboring Louisiana, reflecting the greater proportion
of larger shrimp for which consumers would willingly pay higher prices.
From this evidence, Libecap concluded that "private group
regulations of fisheries could be an alternative to government
regulation if that option were politically acceptable." Yet it was
not. Years after the GCSOA was challenged in court, government
regulations were adopted with the same goal of increasing the value of
the local shrimp catch by discouraging the catching of smaller shrimp
early in the season.
STATE ACTION Associations of boat owners and fishing crews were
also subject to potential antitrust actions under state law.
Massachusetts successfully enjoined the Atlantic Fishermen's Union
and its members from conspiring to "control completely not only the
catching but the marketing and price" of all fish caught by boats
operating out of Gloucester, Boston, and New Bedford by operating a
"selling room" through which all union members were required
to sell their catch. The stated purpose of the union was to improve
working conditions and ensure that its members received a "fair
share of the profits of our labor commensurate with the dangers and
hardships" of fishing. Most boat crews operating out of
Massachusetts at the time consisted of the union's members.
Among other things, the union was accused of maintaining fish
prices "by limiting the quantities of fresh fish which could be
brought into the three ports named." Specifically, the union
adopted rules limiting the volume offish of various species that could
be brought in by a boat on each trip and setting minimum prices for fish
sales. According to the Massachusetts trial court, the artificial
limitations on fish supplies made it probable that "fish cost more
to the Massachusetts buyer and the Massachusetts ultimate consumer"
than it would have otherwise. The Massachusetts Supreme Court concurred,
finding that the union's "direct and intentional limitation of
total production and the arbitrary fixing of prices" was unlawful
without even needing to consider "whether prices have actually
reached a level which by some standard can be pronounced
unreasonable." The positive environmental benefits of reducing fish
catches off the shores of Massachusetts were not considered.
Notwithstanding the successful state prosecution of the Atlantic
Fishermen's Union's anticompetitive conduct, Patrick McHugh,
an officer of the union, was subsequently subject to federal prosecution
for his anticompetitive actions under the Sherman Act. In this case, the
court noted that McHugh's actions through the union
"effectively limited the quantity and species offish landed in New
Bedford.... Had it not been for defendants' illegal restraints, a
'much greater' volume of scallops and other fish would have
been brought into and sold in the port of New Bedford." Again, that
such actions might facilitate the conservation of local fisheries in the
long-run was not considered by the court.
STRUCTURE AND INCENTIVES
The various marine conservation cartels were not perfect. Most were
clearly focused more on maximizing receipts for their members than on
fishery conservation. But the effect of the litigation was to inhibit
the development of nongovernmental cooperative management structures
that could have addressed fishery problems. That the unions'
motivations were pecuniary or otherwise "impure" should be of
little consequence; Adam Smith's "invisible hand" does
not depend on noble intentions but self-interest. From a conservation
perspective, what matters is whether institutional arrangements
developed--or could have developed--to ensure sustainable utilization of
the resource. Congress would not enact the Magnuson Fishery Conservation
and Management Act for another two decades, and that act has been
largely ineffective. It is possible that collusive fishery
organizations, whatever their costs to consumers, would have done more
to conserve marine resources and ensure their long-term supply. Yet by
declaring such conservation cartels illegal per se, the courts
effectively foreclosed any experimentation with such approaches to
fishery conservation.
Were it simply enough for fishery associations to set catch limits,
it might be easy to condemn the other restraints adopted by Monterey
Sardine, the GCSOA, and the other fishers associations as
anticompetitive. Yet it is not enough to adopt the simple horizontal
restraint to protect the partnership. Because of the incentive to cheat,
the restraint must be enforced. Participants in a given fishery may
agree to catch limits, but there is no assurance that they will abide by
the limitations. As with any cartel, there is tremendous incentive to
cheat. Indeed, the more successful the partnership is at controlling the
catch, the greater incentive there is to cheat. In a marine fishery,
cheating is difficult to control. The activities and catches of
individual boats are difficult to monitor. It is easier to police
landings or sales to canneries, particularly as there will typically be
fewer canneries than fishers. Thus, the fishing association enters into
contracts with the canneries to monitor or control the volume of fish
caught. Minimum prices can help maintain fisher income, potentially
reducing the incentive to cheat. They will also reduce the quantity
offish that canneries will purchase. The vertical aspects of the
arrangement--the contracts between the fishermen and the
canneries--serve to help control shirking and free riding by individual
fishers.
Another threat to the viability of such a partnership in a marine
fishery is the entrance of outsiders. So long as there is open access to
the fishery, conservation efforts remain a questionable investment. A
fishing association cannot limit the catch if non-member fishers are
free to catch fish from the same fishery. The conservation cartel
addresses this concern by making contracts with canneries exclusive, so
that non-member fishers cannot sell their fish in competition with the
association. Such contracts protect the cartel by protecting its
investment in the conservation of the fishery.
Despite their anticompetitive appearance (if not effect), such
conservation measures ensure a long-run supply of fish and thus may be
welfare enhancing, the harm to individually excluded fishers not
withstanding. The short-term efficiency losses caused by the exclusion
may be outweighed by the long-term efficiency gains from conserving the
underlying resource and maximizing resource output over time. Protecting
an individual fishery from depletion may be pro-competitive insofar as
it maintains the fishery as a viable source of fish for consumers. That
does not mean that all such arrangements should necessarily be legal
under federal antitrust laws. It does, however, suggest that such
arrangements should not be inherently suspect.
RECONCILING COMPETITION WITH CONSERVATION
Antitrust law has evolved substantially since the prosecutions of
the GCSOA and other fishery associations. There is a growing recognition
that many arrangements that appear anticompetitive have the potential to
enhance consumer welfare. All economic agreements have the potential to
restrain trade to some degree. Yet some such agreements may benefit
consumers by increasing the efficiency of producing firms, there by
reducing prices. Where courts once rigidly applied per se rules to
condemn a wide range of cooperative conduct among firms, they are now
willing to take a closer look at the potential economic benefits of
cooperative behavior.
This increased appreciation of the potential for otherwise
anticompetitive arrangements to serve broader societal goals suggests
that courts should reconsider the per se condemnation of cooperative
fishery management. While such conduct may appear anticompetitive and
may even reduce output in some cases, it also has the potential to serve
conservation goals and thereby enhance total welfare. For this reason,
cooperative efforts to limit or otherwise control fish catch should be
analyzed under the rule of reason. Such a shift in approach is largely
consistent with contemporary antitrust doctrine and would enhance the
prospects for sustainable fishery management.
To date, courts have not been asked to address this question
directly. There are no cases evaluating efforts to solve coordination
problems in the context of an open-access commons; indeed, there are no
reported antitrust cases even addressing conservation concerns in the
fishery context over the last 30 years. The cases condemning voluntary
efforts to reduce or control fish catch have yet to be called into
question, let alone overturned. As the law stands, efforts to conserve
marine fisheries through private, cooperative efforts risk prosecution
under the Sherman Act.
There are a handful of successful fishery cooperatives in
operation, but their ability to actively participate in the management
of the underlying resource remains constrained by antitrust concerns.
Federal antitrust authorities could help facilitate the acceptance of
collaborative conservation efforts, but they cannot immunize such
arrangements from antitrust scrutiny. Should the courts fail to apply
the rule of reason to conservation-enhancing agreements among resource
users, however, statutory reforms could be considered. Yet a statutory
"fix" has the potential of imposing a
"one-size-fits-all" rule in an area where context-specific
judgments may be more appropriate.
In the conservation context, the cost of an overly restrictive
antitrust rule is not simply the invalidation of marginally more
efficient economic arrangements. In at least some instances, the cost of
an overly restrictive rule is the continuation of unsustainable fishery
practices that threaten to deplete, if not exhaust, marine fish
populations. The trade-off to be made is between the risk of economic
inefficiency and that of substantial environmental harm. While
restrictions on output may be undesirable from a consumer welfare
standpoint, such potentially anticompetitive behavior may be net
welfare-enhancing in comparison to the likely alternative of fishery
depletion. Viewed in this light, there seems to be ample justification
for evaluating the potentially collusive conduct of private fishery
associations under the rule of reason, rather than a per se rule.
Insofar as antitrust laws inhibit the development of formal
cooperative arrangements among resource users, it forces users to adopt
one of three courses, all of which maybe substantially less optimal than
the reliance upon formal cooperative efforts to control resource use.
First, they may seek government regulatory measures to limit consumption
of the resource. Given the poor record of regulatory measures aimed at
conserving fish stocks, that is a less-than-ideal course. The adoption
of property-based conservation schemes may provide substantial benefits,
but such proposals can be politically difficult to implement. A second
option is to adopt informal community restraints upon overfishing. Such
measures can be quite effective at controlling catch levels in many
contexts. Formalizing such arrangements is not an option, however, as to
memorialize the rules into formal contracts is to raise potential
antitrust concerns. A third option is simply to leave well enough alone
and to extract rents from the fishery so long as one can. Given the
nature of open access commons, this latter course may well lead to both
economic and ecological ruin.
The obstruction of cooperative solutions to the commons problem is
not likely to be unique to fisheries policy. At heart, most if not all
environmental problems are commons problems of some sort. Admittedly,
where total catch limits are in place, antitrust law is more tolerant of
agreements among fishing firms to allocate portions of the catch. Such
arrangements enable firms to capture some, but not all, of the gains
that would come from private property. Moreover, where there is no
government-imposed limit on the total catch from a fishery, the
limitation on vertical integration in fishing cooperatives--that is, the
limitation on agreements between fishers and processors or
wholesalers--can make it more difficult for fishing firms to implement
self-enforcing cooperative ventures.
CONCLUSION
The purported aim of antitrust law is to improve consumer welfare
by proscribing actions and arrangements that reduce output and increase
prices. Conservation aims to improve human welfare by maximizing the
long-term productive use of natural resources, an aim that often
requires limiting consumption to sustainable levels. While conservation
measures might increase prices in the short run, they enhance consumer
welfare by increasing long-term production and ensuring the availability
of valued resources over time. That is true whether the restrictions are
imposed by a private conservation cartel or a government agency.
Insofar as antitrust law fails to take this into account, it bars
the creation and evolution of ecologically valuable and socially
beneficial arrangements among resource users. The threat to consumer
welfare from potentially collusive arrangements is real, but no more so
than that of resource depletion and environmental ruin. A conservation
cartel may force consumers to pay higher prices for a time, but the
failure to conserve marine resources may lead to species extinction and
ecosystem disruption. It is time to consider that the costs of antitrust
law to conservation are greater than the threat of conservation cartels
in the marine commons.
READINGS
* "Antitrust and the Commons: Cooperation or Collusion?"
by Bruce Yandle. The Independent Review, Vol. 3 (1992).
* "Conservation through Collusion: Antitrust as an Obstacle to
Marine Resource Conservation," by Jonathan H. Adler. Washington
& Lee Law Review, Vol. 61 (2004).
* Contracting for Property Rights, by Gary D. Libecap. Cambridge, U
K: Cambridge University Press, 1989.
* "Contracting Problems and Regulation: The Case of the
Fishery," by Ronald N. Johnson and Gary D. Libecap. American
Economic Review, Vol. 21 (1982).
* Evolving Property Rights in Marine Fisheries, edited by Donald
Leal. Lanham, Md.: Rowman & Littlefield, 2004.
* "Legal Obstacles to Private Ordering in Marine
Fisheries," by Jonathan H. Adler. Roger Williams University Law
Review, Vol. 8 (2002).
* "The Tragedy of the Commons," by Garrett Hardin.
Science, Vol. 162 (1968).
Jonathan H. Adler is all associate professor of law and associate
director of the Center for Business Law and Regulation at Case Western
Reserve University School of Law. He also is a 2004 Julian Simon Fellow
at the Property & Environment Research Center. He may be contacted
by e mail at jha5@case.edu.
This article is adapted from a longer piece that appeared in the
2004 Washington & Lee Law Review.