First, do no harm. (Mercatus Reports: Commentary).
Klick, Jonathan ; Stratmann, Thomas
WHEN CONGRESS PASSED THE OCCUpational Safety and Health Act in
1970, then secretary of labor James Hodgson heralded it as the
"most significant legislative achievement" for workers in a
decade. The agency created to implement the provisions of the Act, the
Occupational Safety and Health Administration, took as its mission
"to save lives, prevent injuries, and protect the health of
America's workers."
In carrying out that mission, OSHA's staff of more than 1,000
inspectors visited work sites 35,897 times in 2001, discovering nearly
80,000 safety violations amounting to $82 million in fines. It remains
an open question, however, whether OSHA really does "protect the
health of America's workers."
OSHA claims that the issue is clear-cut, declaring that its
activities make America's workplaces safer, and there are a few
academic studies supporting that view. Unfortunately, there are just as
many studies suggesting that OSHA enforcement does little to change the
level of safety enjoyed by workers.
Statistical analysis of the issue is difficult because OSHA targets
much of its enforcement at industries and firms that, by the nature of
the work they do, have the most dangerous conditions for workers.
Because of that, it is difficult to isolate the causal effect of OSHA
enforcement. On the surface, it appears that the firms OSHA inspects and
fines tend to have the highest rates of worker injuries and deaths, but
it is not possible to conclude from this relationship that OSHA
enforcement leads to more accidents and fatalities. Instead, it is more
likely that accidents and fatalities lead to more OSHA enforcement.
Enforcement's effects
In a new Mercatus Center research paper, "Offsetting Behaviors
in the Workplace," we attempt to get around this
"selection" effect through the use of an instrumental
variables technique to determine exactly what greater OSHA enforcement
accomplishes. The key to our technique is to find variables that affect
how frequently OSHA performs inspections and what level of fines it
levies, but do not otherwise affect the safety of workers. With such
variables, we can effectively model the level of OSHA enforcement
independent of the underlying safety of the targeted industries.
It turns out that OSHA tends to target industries that are less
economically important, and performs more inspections and assesses more
fines in those industries with relatively low gross state industry
products. Thus, gross state industry product is our first instrument.
Another instrument that proves to be useful is whether or not OSHA has
granted "final approval" to a state agency to control worker
safety regulation within the state. Under the Occupational Safety and
Health Act, states may apply to take over worker safety regulation.
After a period of state control, if OSHA determines that state
enforcement is "at least as effective" as federal enforcement,
final approval is granted, and the state agency can receive funding for
up to 50 percent of its costs from the federal government. However, OSHA
can revoke final approval if it determines that the state agency is no
longer effectively protecting workers. After final approval is given,
the level of inspections increases and the level of fines tends to d
ecrease.
Using those instruments, we examined the effect of worker safety
inspections and fines on the fatality rates at the industry level within
the states comprising OSHA's Region IV (Alabama, Florida, Georgia,
Kentucky, Mississippi, North Carolina, South Carolina, and Tennessee)
and Region IX (Arizona, California, Hawaii, and Nevada) for the period
1992-2001. Surprisingly, we found that fines have no statistically
significant effect on death rates and increasing inspections actually
leads to significantly higher fatality rates. On average, we found that
an additional 100 inspections in a given state-industry in a particular
year leads to between 1 and 2.5 additional deaths in that industry. That
result is robust to a wide range of statistical specifications.
OSHA efforts and worker efforts
What accounts for such a surprising result? The intuition is quite
simple. If worker safety depends on firm inputs and worker inputs, when
the firm increases its efforts because of OSHA enforcement, the worker
rationally substitutes away from his own efforts. That is, if the firm
is doing more to protect the worker, the worker has less incentive to
protect himself.
On net, that substitution implies that increasing firm safety
inputs could lead to more, less, or the same amount of worker safety
depending on worker preferences. In this case, it appears as though
workers more than offset the additional safety measures induced by
increased OSHA enforcement.
Our finding resembles of the so-called "Peltzman Effect."
In a 1975 issue of The Journal of Political Economy, University of
Chicago professor Sam Peltzman speculated that automobile safety devices
might induce individuals to drive more recklessly because safety
equipment such as seatbelts protected the drivers from some of the costs
of their risk-taking. He found evidence of that effect, though he did
not find that drivers more than offset the benefits to themselves of the
improved safety.
The policy implication of this offsetting behavior in the workplace
is striking. If workers effectively undo safety regulations, it is
doubtful that OSHA can do much to "save lives, prevent injuries,
and protect the health of America's workers."
Jonathan Klick is the Dorothy Donnelley Moller research fellow at
The Mercatus Center and a Robert A. Levy Fellow in Law and Liberty at
the George Mason University School of Law. He can be contacted by e-mail
at iklick@gmu.edu.
Thomas Stratmann is a faculty scholar at The Mercatus Center and a
professor of economics at George Mason University. He can be contacted
by e-mail at tstratma@gmu.edu.