Federalism and regulation: what sorts of regulation are best handled on the federal level?
Hahn, Robert W. ; Layne-Farrar, Anne ; Passell, Peter 等
ECONOMISTS GENERALLY AGREE ABOUT the role of regulation in modern
market economies: If there is no significant "market failure,"
then government should not intervene. If the failure is substantial, and
there is good reason to believe that regulation would improve outcomes,
government should intervene.
By contrast, the issue of which level of government in a federal
system should do the regulating (if regulation is indeed appropriate)
often divides free market economists who otherwise have little
difficulty finding common ground. On the one hand, the efficiency of
applying one set of rules to national markets is embodied in the
Commerce Clause of the U.S. Constitution. On the other, decentralization within a federal system is prized, both for its capacity to reflect
diverse values and for the opportunities it creates to use states and
localities as laboratories for innovation in regulation.
On balance, we do not believe there is a simple way to decide, from
an economic efficiency standpoint, what jurisdiction is best suited to
regulating. In some cases, the specific history of regulation in an
industry and the institutions created to do the regulating matter a lot.
The most that theory can offer here is a disciplined way of thinking
about the issue.
WHY REGULATE AT ALL?
To justify regulation as a means of increasing economic efficiency,
there must be evidence that markets are distorting resource allocation.
However, evidence of that distortion does not prove that the
intervention will increase welfare. As public choice economics suggests,
regulation can do more harm than good for reasons ranging from the high
cost of obtaining information to interest-group capture. Thus, making
the case for regulation is a two-stage process: Is there good evidence
that the unfettered market has failed, and if so, is regulation likely
to improve matters?
The significance of this second hurdle is all too apparent in light
of the problematic experiences with regulation even where it is easy to
demonstrate market failure--cases ranging from efforts to internalize the costs of air pollution to the assessment of the safety and efficacy
of prescription drugs. As discussed below, the imperfect nature of
regulation is also relevant in the context of federalism: In some
instances, the decisive factor favoring regulation at one level of
government rather than another is the quality of the regulatory
institutions.
REASONS TO CENTRALIZE REGULATION
If the potential welfare gains from intervention in private
transactions do outweigh the losses, one is still left to choose the
appropriate level of government to intervene. The case for centralizing
regulation in a federal system is based on a variety of arguments.
Externalities The actions of regulators in one locality will often
affect producers and consumers in another. And, other matters equal,
regulators in one jurisdiction will have incentives to give greater
weight to the interests of their constituents than others affected. The
classic examples are siting disputes. In some cases, like the creation
of national storage facilities for high-level radioactive waste from
nuclear power plants, the potential consequences for those directly
affected have the potential to be very serious. In most, the tensions
have the same source, but the stakes are not as high.
Commercial airports, for example, may generate substantial net
benefits for a large region. However, the minority of people who live
closest to the site, and are thus most affected by the noise and
congestion, may have disproportionate influence over decisions. For
example, local activists have been able to block the conversion of the
El Toro military air base in Orange County, Calif.--one of the few
remaining sites for creating a commercial airport in a region much in
need of airport capacity.
Conversely, local regulators may choose to ignore the costs
generated in their jurisdiction that damage another. Thus, sulfur
emissions from smokestacks in one state end up as acid rain in states
downwind. Sewage, farm runoffs, and other contaminants that leak into
watersheds may damage water quality hundreds of miles away.
As Ronald Coase pointed out, such externalities need not lead to
inefficient resource allocation if it is practical for the parties with
conflicting interests to make side deals. For example, those adversely
affected might pay polluters to abate emissions, or polluters might
compensate neighbors for losses that are capitalized in the value of
their land. But the transaction costs typically are very high, or the
resulting changes in the distribution of wealth simply may be deemed
socially inequitable.
Some pollution externalities--for example, chemicals that damage
the atmosphere's protective ozone layer--affect the whole planet.
But the principles for minimizing efficiency losses are the same: Either
one must create institutions to enforce trans-national regulation or
else reduce the transaction costs for Coase-style side deals. Hence the
logic of emissions trading systems, in which the initial distribution of
wealth is skewed in favor of the nations least willing to sacrifice.
China is reluctant to invest in power sources that emit less carbon
dioxide, but might be induced to switch to carbon-efficient fuels if it
could sell the emissions rights to other countries.
Economies of scale Uniform regulation can remove a barrier to the
exploitation of economies of scale in design, manufacturing, and
inventory. For example, it is cheaper for an automaker to meet one
bumper crash standard for the whole country than to sell cars with
bumpers tailored to individual state rules.
The idea has not been lost on suppliers of products, services, and
inputs prepared to sacrifice scale economies in order to achieve market
power. As a result, local variations in building codes both raise
production costs and make it more difficult for outsiders to obtain the
know-how to challenge locally dominant builders (and their unions).
The scale economies case for centralized regulation needs to be
qualified. For one thing, the straightforward efficiency gains from
greater production scale may be outweighed by advantages of
specialization--one size does not necessarily fit all. A carbon monoxide emissions standard that meets a cost-benefit test in protecting health
in downtown Denver may be seriously wasteful in Montana.
For another, model codes that are privately negotiated and then
blessed by individual localities may be effective. Thus, adoption of the
Uniform Commercial Code allows individual states to obtain the benefits
of central regulation without accepting the formal loss of sovereignty.
Note, too, that while centralized regulation may be preferable to
balkanized regulation, the good may prove the enemy of the best when
there is no strong justification for regulation at all. If, for example,
one large jurisdiction (like California or New York) threatens to go it
alone on regulation, it may well pay national producers to support
otherwise inefficient federal regulation. Federal water conservation
standards for toilets solved the balkanization problem for manufacturers
worried about local ordinances, but probably cannot be justified in
cost-benefit terms.
Race to the bottom Regulation typically produces losers as well as
winners. If the potential losers are mobile, they can change
jurisdictions in a decentralized system and either avoid the
consequences of regulation or deter its imposition in the first place.
For example, many large corporations are chartered in Delaware and
cruise ships carry flags of convenience to avoid national labor laws.
Consider worker safety, where the cost to individuals of obtaining
relevant information by individuals may lead to market failure.
While most states regulate workplace safety, competition among
states to increase tax bases, create jobs, and satisfy special interests
may lead the states to reduce worker protection below the efficient
level. Thus, the creation of the Occupational Safety and Health
Administration within the U.S. Department of Labor and the promulgation of minimum workplace safety standards were rationalized as a way to stop
a welfare-reducing "race to the bottom" by the states. And the
federalization of regulation did work in the sense that it reduced
injury rates in some categories in states with lax rules of their own.
However. it is hard to say, before the fact, whether federal
regulation prevents a competitive race to the bottom or inhibits a
competitive race to the top. Many economic historians, for example,
argue that decentralization offered an escape valve to business in the
20th century during periods of rising regulation of state labor markets.
That, in turn, served the economy's long-term interest in economic
growth. By the same token, interstate competition to attract business
today has undoubtedly put pressure on states to prevent abuses of tort
law and to invest more in public education. And it is also leading
communities to invest in amenities ranging from parks to cultural
centers in order to attract highly skilled workers.
Expertise The difficulty for even best-effort regulation to mimic
efficient market outcomes is always a daunting problem. And it typically
is exacerbated in cases in which regulation is decentralized and
regulatory resources are spread thin.
Antitrust offers a good example. While the Federal Trade Commission
and the Department of Justice have a combined budget for specialized
antitrust staff that exceeds $200 million, competition policy is an
afterthought for state attorneys general. California, the state with the
largest financial commitment to antitrust enforcement, spends less than
$6 million annually on antitrust--less than one percent of the
California attorney general's budget.
The best case for giving the states any role in antitrust is to use
their potential to serve as watchdogs--to identify restraints on trade
that escape Washington's radar screen. But that benign function can
be more than offset by the attorneys general inclination to free-ride on
federal cases. Thus, in the Microsoft civil suit, the Justice
Department's obligation to include the states in decision-making
blurred prosecutorial focus and inhibited efforts to reach a negotiated
settlement.
It is also worth noting the increasing difficulty of amassing
sufficient expertise with decentralized regulation, because both markets
and products are becoming more complex. In the Microsoft case, for
example, the merits of arguments turned on arcane issues such as the
practicality of removing some functions from operating system software
without degrading other capacities.
The arguments that apply to regulatory agencies apply equally well
to the courts. Appeals of state regulation tend to be at the state
level, where courts have less expertise and judges are apt to be more
influenced by interest-group pressure.
More generally, regulation is increasingly challenged by the need
for technological expertise--and worse, the difficulty of anticipating
efficiency effects of regulation in the context of rapid technological
change. It is worth noting that, in some cases, states lacking expertise
have evolved ways to use the expertise of other states that have
specialized in the regulation of specific industries. New York's
insurance rules have been used as the model for other states, while
Pennsylvania has served the same function for decades in regulating the
safety of food processing.
Interest-group capture One problem that constantly dogs regulation
is the risk of disproportionate interest-group influence. The
institutions of regulation can offer some degree of protection. For
example, sunshine rules may make capture more difficult, as may
expedited review by an independent judiciary. But probably the most
dependable way to minimize successful rent-seeking is to dilute the
influence of individual interests by providing easy access to groups
with competing interests. For example, state-level licensing of
physicians, lawyers, and other professionals makes it easy to restrict
entry because out-of-staters have no place at the table. By the same
token, state regulation of automobile dealer franchises has made it
difficult to create national dealerships and has prevented automakers
from integrating retailing.
Decentralized antitrust regulation has also had the effect of
facilitating interest group capture. In the Microsoft case, many state
attorneys general were extremely reluctant to settle in part because
their business constituencies were dominated by Microsoft's rivals.
It is no coincidence that California, with its Silicon Valley
constituency, and Massachusetts, home to Sun Microsystems research
facilities, opposed compromise--or that the California legislature
appropriated funds to appeal the court's last ruling.
REASONS TO DECENTRALIZE REGULATION
While centralization carries considerable appeal, there are two
classic justifications for decentralization: diversities of values and
opportunity for experimentation. Let us consider each of those.
Diversity of values There are strong objective reasons for
designing economic regulation to imitate competitive market outcomes and
bring resource allocation closer to Pareto optimality. But where
regulation affects income distribution or intangible social values, an
efficiency standard is, at best, incomplete.
A large dose of skepticism is appropriate here because it is hard
to know whether differences in regulation really follow from differences
in values. For example, differences in tolerance of smoking may reflect
community choices--or simply the impulse to collect sumptuary taxes, or
the power of tobacco growers and cigarette manufacturers. In other
cases, though, there is little question that differences in regulation
reflect differing local circumstances or values. A few states have
legalized marijuana for medical use, while Vermont permits same-sex
marriages. And many southern states have fought federal constitutional
prohibitions against government-supported expression of religion.
The diversity-of-values justification for decentralization makes
many social scientists uncomfortable, and with good reason. Among other
problems, it implies that collective values are more than an arbitrarily
weighted index of individual values--a notion that fits awkwardly in the
economist's utilitarian framework. And it collides with the
libertarian impulse with which most free market economists (and many
Americans) identify. Hardly anyone, after all, sees the Bill of Rights
as an unjustified limitation on states' rights to regulate speech
or deny due process.
Opportunities for experimentation By contrast, virtually everyone
pragmatically celebrates decentralization as a source of innovation in
government regulation--an idea that goes back at least as far as Justice
Louis Brandeis' famed dissent in the 1932 case New York State Ice
Co. v. Liebman. Indeed, the states as-laboratories concept has been
instrumental in the backlash against federal regulation since the 1970s.
Thus, the very positive experiences of California and Texas in
deregulating airlines led to a federal deregulation movement that
ultimately dismantled decades-old constraints on markets in
transportation and energy. The experiments with workfare in Wisconsin
and other states helped to create a centrist coalition that reformed
public assistance. Oregon has pioneered an effort to create some order
in the way medical budgets for the poor are managed. And state
experiments in public education reform, ranging from school vouchers to
standardized testing, have led to a broader national campaign.
Failure counts almost as much as success. California's
catastrophic experiment in deregulating wholesale electricity prices
while maintaining retail price regulation is likely to influence energy
regulation for the foreseeable future.
A CASE STUDY: WIRELESS COMMUNICATIONS
Mobile communications regulation merits a close look for a variety
of reasons. It is very large--its total revenues of $76 billion amounted
to almost one-third of all telecommunications revenues in 2002. It is
growing rapidly: In 2002, subscribers totaled 141 million--a five-fold
increase in a decade. And as one of the few growth areas in information
technology, the numbers almost certainly underestimate the
industry's contribution to the economy because of potential
spillovers in productivity.
Prior to 1993, states had the power to regulate prices and terms of
service in what was then the decade-old cell phone industry. Not
surprisingly, the states exercised the option. For one thing, it seemed
a logical extension of state regulation of intrastate wired phone
service. For another, the potential for competition was limited because
the Federal Communications Commission had assigned radio spectrum for
cellular communications to just two providers in each locality, one of
which was the old Bell operating company.
But under the umbrella of the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of
1993, Washington preempted state authority over rate and entry
regulation in mobile telephony. The addition of more spectrum
(distributed through federal auctions), along with improvements in
technology, increased the number of potential competing systems and
facilitated the assembly of six national service networks.
The FCC chose to waive its right to regulate rates and entry. But
state predictions that service providers could and would exploit market
power in an unregulated environment did not come true. Falling costs,
combined with increased competition in virtually all service areas, has
led to dramatic increases in both the number of subscribers and average
usage rates along with dramatic declines in prices.
The average price of a minute of calling time fell by nearly
three-quarters between 1994 and 2001. And, as the carriers rely on
aggressive marketing techniques that emphasize sales of large,
fixed-charge "buckets" of monthly minutes and prepaid service
that obviates the need for a good credit history, the trend shows no
sign of slowing. Indeed, the implementation of FCC-mandated
"portability," which will allow customers to take their
telephone numbers with them when they change carriers, should increase
competition yet more--especially competition for business users.
State proposals Note, however, that Washington did leave states
some authority to regulate mobile phone service under the general rubric of consumer protection, at least where state regulation does not
interfere with rates and terms. Several states have proposals in the
works. The most ambitious is the proposed California Telecommunications
Bill of Rights, which would limit phone service providers'
discretion in a wide range of activities, with the focus on disclosure
of contract terms and redress in cases in which customers are not
satisfied with service. On first view, most of the California provisions
seem innocuous. However, the potential costs, both in terms of carrier
resources and consumer time and convenience, could be substantial. A
study for Verizon Wireless by the economic consulting firm LECG estimated that the costs would exceed 10 percent of the average wireless
bill. Further, it could be argued that the rules outlined in the
California Bill of Rights skate dangerously close to affecting wireless
rates and terms--an area not covered by state regulation.
One obvious question is whether there is evidence of any market
failure to justify such intervention. What evidence there is is weak.
Every area code in California has at least five competing providers,
while unit service prices are falling. And though the California Public
Utilities Commission does receive thousands of complaints about wireless
service each year, the rate of complaints is quite low in light of the
size of the market--the state has roughly 16 million cell phone
subscribers. By the same token, even if there was a market failure and
even if the proposed rules were on target, it is by no means clear that
the benefits of intervention would exceed the costs. More relevant here,
one must ask whether the state is the appropriate level for regulation.
As noted earlier, when a state as large as California tries to regulate
a national market like wireless, it can dictate national standards. In
effect, one state can determine federal rules without considering
potential impacts on other states. While this does not negate the
benefits of having states serve as laboratories for new ideas, it
clearly weakens that argument.
Externalities Many of the consequences of California regulation
would spill into other jurisdictions. For example, the state's
Telecommunications Bill of Rights would require exhaustive disclosure in
advertising, making it impractical for service providers to advertise
promotions in national media without meeting California rules. More
generally, any regulation that significantly raised costs and prices in
California would reduce the number (or rate of growth) of subscribers
and thus reduce the value of the national phone network to all
subscribers.
Expertise One might also wonder whether individual states have
adequate expertise to regulate wireless communications. While the
states' jurisdiction is seemingly limited to areas in which it has
considerable experience--information disclosure, consumer fraud, and the
like--there is more here than meets the eye.
For example, wireless technology for connecting to the telephone
network is converging with wireless e-mail and Internet technology. And
the manner in which multiple wireless services are packaged for
marketing is likely to change rapidly. Hence, the extensive disclosure
and contract cancellation provisions of California's proposed
regulations, designed with today's cell phone services in mind,
could limit the providers' marketing practices in ways not yet
imagined.
Race to the ... The mobile communications industry, in ironic
contrast to the people who use it, is not mobile. Providers of national
service have a considerable stake in a strong presence in every state.
Thus, while a state's regulatory climate may affect the pace of
local investment, one cannot depend on wireless communications providers
facing onerous state rules to vote with their feet. Indeed, an insidious
aspect of state consumer protection regulation, where consumers cannot
see the links between state intervention and the size of their cell
phone bills, is that it may be catching: Regulators, hard-pressed to
show they are vigilant, may well be tempted to imitate the most
restrictive state model.
Interest group capture Generalizations are problematic here. It is
conceivable that some service providers in some places exercise
considerable influence over rulemaking. However, there certainly is
anecdotal evidence that non-profit consumer groups have disproportionate
influence on standard "consumer protection" issues at the
state level--particularly where regulators are often planning to run for
elective office.
The fact that consumer groups do not have a direct financial stake
in regulation may, on first thought, seem reassuring. But those groups
generally reject the notion that regulation should be subject to
cost-benefit tests or that competition is a reliable source of consumer
protection, and are thus inclined to support measures that, on balance,
reduce efficiency.
For example, the California Telecommunications Bill of Rights would
require a service provider to offer all official documents in all the
languages in which it solicits business. That would certainly generate
some benefits, but it might well inhibit competition for customers from
smaller ethnic groups.
Moreover, consumer protection groups typically are closely allied
with the trial bar. And trial lawyers have strong interests in rules
that make litigation easier--and thus, raise transaction costs.
Experimentation While there may be possibilities for innovation in
the regulation of wireless communications, the FCC already controls the
most plausible areas for productivity- and welfare-enhancing change,
like spectrum use. Moreover, there is no particular history of state
innovation in what is commonly called "consumer protection."
Indeed, innovation in regulation has largely been directed at minimizing
the efficiency losses associated with market intervention--typically by
mimicking the incentives inherent in competitive markets. Consumer
groups and trial lawyers, by contrast, focus on equity issues--in their
world, the problem with market power is that it distributes income to
sellers, not that it distorts the allocation of resources. Moreover, the
trial bar has little incentive to reduce transaction costs in
regulation--and in many cases it plainly has incentives to increase
them.
Diversity of values In theory, one might imagine that states would
have different tastes for traditional consumer protections, in the sense
that some communities would accept a greater loss in efficiency to
improve outcomes for individuals most likely to be victimized by
misleading marketing practices. However, it is a stretch to believe that
diversity-generates much value here, particularly in light of the fact
that every state has laws against egregious consumer fraud and that
opportunities for misleading marketing will diminish under the Federal
Trade Commission's new limits on telemarketing.
THE NEVER-ENDING DEBATE
Out of the context of a specific market at a specific time, it is
hard to imagine a definitive answer to the question of the optimal
degree of decentralization of regulation. More likely, attempts at
generalization distract from serious analysis.
Nonetheless, there are some key factors in critical markets that
suggest the burden increasingly ought to fall on the proponents of
decentralization. Scale, scope, and network efficiencies are growing in
many markets, raising the potential costs of balkanization. And rapid
technological change strains the expertise of under-funded,
under-skilled local regulators. At the same time, one must be careful
not to assume that skilled regulators will necessarily do the right
thing. The political context in which such regulators operate is
critical.
The case of wireless communications is revealing. The rapidly
changing industry has thrived under the increasingly light touch of
federal regulation. Furthermore, attempts to reassert rights to
intervene in the narrow area left to the states say more about the
political economy of government than about failure to regulate
adequately at the federal level.
A GROWING TECHNOLOGY ECOSYSTEM
Despite a hesitant global economy and the burst of the dot-com
bubble, the information technology market is poised to exceed $1
trillion this year and is expected to grow another 40 percent by 2005.
With millions of people employed at hundreds of thousands of
information technology companies around the world, it's clear that
the high-tech industry continues to serve as an engine of global
economic growth and opportunity.
In just the last two decades, we have seen the tremendous growth of
a global "technology ecosystem" of companies that create
hardware, software and services for businesses, governments, educational
institutions and consumers worldwide. A recent study by IDC found that
from 1995 to 2001, growth in the IT industry outpaced the broader
economy in all 28 countries they studied, and is expected to grow 45
percent or more over the next several years in at least half of those
countries.
The introduction of the PC in 1981 was one of the catalysts for
this tremendous growth. Prior to this, few computers were compatible
with one another. The software and hardware you bought would only work
reliably on one model of computer, and it was difficult to share
information with partners and colleagues who used a different model. The
expense of creating products for dozens of different computers prevented
many companies from taking risks to create innovative new products; and
the wide range of incompatible software and peripherals from a number of
different companies left many companies dependent on a single vendor for
everything from hardware to services. The result was fewer choices and
higher prices for consumers.
The PC's industry-standard blueprint for hardware and a
compatible operating system changed all that. Hardware companies could
then compete to build better PCs for their customers, confident that
they could run all the popular applications. Software companies could
create products that would work well on the greatest number of
computers. Other companies introduced development platforms and tools
that worked with these standard computers and operating systems, making
it even easier for developers to write innovative software. And still
more companies offered printers, modems and other peripherals that were
easy to configure and use.
Today, more than 750,000 companies around the world design,
manufacture and sell PC systems, create compelling software for
everything from household finances to advanced scientific research, and
build the printers, digital cameras, media players and other peripherals
that make computers even more useful. The opportunities surrounding the
PC are incredible-the IDC study showed that Microsoft partners generate
$8 in revenue for every $1 earned by Microsoft.
The same industry that made the PC a success is now embarking on
the next computing revolution--a world in which intelligent devices will
connect people, businesses, information and services wherever and
whenever needed. This next transformation--building on open Internet
standards such as XML (eXtensible Markup Language)--will offer
incredible new computing experiences for people and businesses and vast
new growth opportunities for tens of thousands of companies around the
world.
As the world of computing expands to encompass everything from
handheld devices to computer servers that make the world's largest
corporations more efficient, agile and secure, Microsoft is committed to
enabling people and businesses to fully realize their potential--and to
nurturing technology's role in economic growth and prosperity
around the world.
One in a series of essays on technology and society. More
information is available at microsoft.com/issues.
READINGS
* Antitrust in the New Economy," by Richard Posner. Antitrust
Law Journal, Vol. 68 (2001).
* The Calculus of Consent, by James Buchanan and Gordon Tullock.
Ann Arbor, Mich.: University of Michigan Press, 1960.
* "Federalism as a Commitment to Preserving Market
Incentives," by Yingyi Quan and Barry Weingast. Journal of Economic
Perspectives, Vol. 11, No. 4 (Fall 1997).
* "The Problem of Social Cost," by Ronald Coase. Journal
of Law and Economics, Vol. 3 (1960).
* "Rethinking Federalism," by Robert Inman and Daniel
Rubinfeld. Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 11 (Fall 1997).
Robert W. Hahn is the executive director of the AEI-Brookings Joint
Center for Regulatory Studies and a resident scholar at the American
Enterprise Institute.
Anne Layne-Farrar is a senior consultant with NERA Economic
Consulting.
Peter Passell is a senior fellow at the Milken Institute in Santa
Monica, Calif.