Much ado about order flow: how should regulators respond to "side" payments made by markets to brokers? (Securities & Investment).
Ferrell, Allen
IN THE LAST QUARTER OF A CENTURY, there has been a remarkable --
and much needed--shift in public policy towards deregulation in a host
of areas. The wholesale revision and discarding of unnecessary
regulations has occurred in industries ranging from trucking and
airlines to the production and I distribution of natural gas. Equally
important (although not as widely appreciated), there has been a
noticeable increase in the reluctance to impose new regulatory
requirements on various sectors of the American economy.
How have the securities markets fared in the move toward
deregulation? Few industries would appear to be more competitive, fast
moving, and innovative than today's financial markets. Yet, during
the last 25 years, there has been a marked increase in the regulation of
the very structure of those markets. The regulatory initiatives are
almost wholly removed from traditional concerns over fraud,
misrepresentation, and nondisclosure in the financial markets. Rather
than protecting the uninformed and naive, the new frontier in securities
regulation is concerned with shaping the internal structure of
securities markets and the relationship between those markets. In other
words, regulators are now in the business of mandating how securities
markets should be set up and how competing markets should interact with
each other. As a result, the Securities and Exchange Commission
routinely needs to address such issues as what prices securities markets
can charge other markets for data (such as stock quotations), what types
of non-price competition between securities markets will be permitted,
and which systems should be in place for routing investors' orders
between securities markets.
Among the many practices now under SEC scrutiny is that of some
markets offering "side" payments to brokers in exchange for
brokers routing investors' orders to them. The practice is referred
to as "payment for order flow." The payments range from cash
(usually in the range of one to three cents for each stock trade routed)
to in-kind payments, such as overlooking settlement errors for which the
broker would normally be liable.
The practice of paying for order flow has exploded in the last 15
years and, as a result, the SEC has become increasingly concerned over
whether investors are being well served by brokers who receive them. To
put things more crassly, the SEC is worried that order flow payments are
the equivalent of kickbacks to brokers in return for not sending
investors' orders to the securities market offering the most
competitive price.
Given the competitive landscape of securities trading and our
nascent knowledge of market microstructure, regulators who are examining
the practice of order flow payments would be well served to adopt the
Hippocratic Oath's injunction of "First, do no harm." In
operational terms, competition between securities markets should be
presumed to resolve market microstructure issues satisfactorily, unless
compelling evidence suggests otherwise. In the case of payments for
order flow, the evidence suggests that the practice may benefit
investors by making it easier for them to judge broker performance. What
is more, the practice may indicate the need for less SEC regulation of
securities markets, not more. To understand why that may be the case, we
must examine why order flow payments occur and what effects they have on
brokers and investors.
DIFFERENT MARKETS
Most investors' orders (especially those from individual
investors) are routed to securities markets through brokers. In return
for a commission, a broker will either buy or sell securities on the
investor's behalf. For many stocks, especially the more actively
traded New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) and NASDAQ securities, there are a
number of trading venues that the broker can choose from for execution
of an investor's order. There are the NYSE and American Stock
Exchange, regional exchanges, proprietary trading systems (such as
Instinet), foreign exchanges, and competing NASDAQ dealers. For
instance, for many NASDAQ securities, there often are upwards of 11
competing dealers to which a broker can send an investor's order
for execution, as well as a number of proprietary trading systems that
create markets in NASDAQ securities.
Auction and dealer markets Perhaps the most fundamental choice
facing a broker is whether to send an investor's order to an
auction market or a dealer market. Auction and dealer markets represent
two very different ways of structuring a securities market. Both types
of market have long co-existed, often offering execution services in the
same security at the same time. An auction market is a market in which
investors' orders are matched according to that market's
trading rules. An investor wishing to sell 100 shares of IBM, for
instance, might end up selling his shares in an auction market to
another investor who wishes to buy 100 shares of IBM. In a dealer
market, however, investors do not trade with each other but with a
dealer that maintains its own portfolio of stocks. A security's
"spread" -- the difference between the offer and bid price --
compensates a dealer for its intermediation services.
In practice, the distinction between auction and dealer markets
often becomes blurred. The NYSE, which is considered the paradigmatic auction market, also provides intermediation services through the
institution of the NYSE specialist. Similarly, the NASDAQ marketplace is
not a pure dealer market, given the ability of investors to display
their limit orders -- orders for which investors have specified a price
at which they are willing to sell or buy stock--in dealers'
quotations. As a result, investors' orders, as in auction markets,
can directly interact without dealer intermediation. Nevertheless, the
distinction remains an extremely important one. The NASDAQ market, in
comparison to the NYSE, provides for far more dealer intermediation.
NYSE vs. NASDAQ Competition between auction and dealer markets --
NASDAQ and the NYSE in particular -- has been fierce. As E*Trade's
recent high profile decision to switch from being listed on the NASDAQ
to the NYSE vividly demonstrates, the two markets compete relentlessly
on listing companies. Less appreciated by the public, NASDAQ dealers and
the NYSE also compete on attracting order flow. For many of the most
actively traded NYSE securities, brokers have the option of routing
investors' orders not to the NYSE, but to a NASDAQ dealer who makes
a market in that security. That is the so-called "third
market" in NYSE-listed securities. And NASDAQ is not the only
dealer competitor to the NYSE. Dealer specialists on the regional
exchanges, broker-dealer firms internalizing order flow (i.e., firms
that own brokers and dealers, thus enabling trade execution to occur
without the orders ever going out to an open market), and dealers on
foreign exchanges all represent competitive threats to the NYSE. As one
would ex pect, dealer and auction markets also compete fiercely with
each other for order flow.
ROUTING INVESTORS' ORDERS
To assess possible inefficiencies in brokers' routing of
investors' orders to securities markets, we must answer two
questions:
* How does a broker decide where to send an investor's order
for execution? Or, to ask the same question from a different
perspective, how do securities markets compete for investors'
orders from brokers?
* Where should a broker send an investor's order for
execution?
By answering those questions, we can better analyze the practice of
offering payments for order flow.
Where to send an order? A broker's decision on where to send
an investor's order depends on how brokers compete for
investors' business. To a significant extent, brokers compete on
the basis of commission rates. Fortunately, commission rates -- even for
the smallest of investors -- are easy to compare. Since the abolition of
fixed rates in 1975, commissions have steadily and dramatically
declined. In the last 20 years, NYSE members' securities
commissions as a percentage of total revenue have declined by some 70
percent. What is more, competition on the basis of providing the lowest
commission rates has intensified in the last few years with the arrival
of online brokers. Many online brokers, with great fanfare, charge only
a few dollars per trade. As a result, well-established brokers with an
impressive client base, such as Charles Schwab and Merrill Lynch, have
been forced to slash commission rates to remain competitive.
Price improvement In sharp contrast to commission rates, other
aspects of brokerage performance are much more difficult for the typical
investor to assess. In particular, it is a daunting task for an investor
to determine whether a broker has done the best possible job on his
behalf when it comes to trade execution. Indeed, many investors are not
even aware that it is possible to improve upon the NBBO (National Best
Bid and Offer) prices -- the prices that are posted publicly and
disseminated by the securities markets (and reproduced in such places as
the Wall Street Journal and online quotation services).
If an investor wants to know if he received the best possible price
for his stock, it is impossible for him to do so merely by checking the
NBBO. An investor's order, regardless of which broker happens to
handle it, is always filled at a price at least as good as the NBBO at
the time of execution. The central issue for measuring a broker's
quality of execution is whether he could have achieved a price better
than the NBBO price at the time of execution. In other words, was there
an opportunity for price improvement over the NBBO?
An investor would need to be tremendously well informed in order to
answer that question. For one thing, he would need to know what
opportunities for price improvement existed on each security market.
Suppose, for instance, the broker sent an investor's order to a
dealer for execution. It would be important to know whether the broker
could have gotten a better price for the order on, say, the NYSE. To
learn that, the investor would need to know, among other things, what
the probability was that the order would have received price improvement
if it had been sent to the floor of the NYSE.
That is vital information because a significant percentage of
orders routed to the NYSE receive price improvement. One study found
that, for orders involving less than 400 shares, 60 percent of all NYSE
stock trades that occurred when the NBBO spread was one-quarter of a
point were executed within the NBBO spread. In contrast, for the same
time period and order size, only 38 percent of trades were executed
within the spread when sent to the third market. That means that better
prices were offered on the NYSE for small investors' orders, when
compared to NASDAQ, a significant percentage of the time. Other studies
have substantiated those findings, demonstrating that the NYSE, when
executing small orders (at least under a broad range of circumstances),
often offers prices better than the NBBO or what is available on the
NASDAQ market. What is more, other markets may offer price improvement
opportunities for a particular security that are better than the NYSE.
How can an investor monitor whether his broker is ta king advantage of
all such opportunities?
Costs Not only will an investor have to assess broker success in
obtaining price improvement, but also whether those improvements offset
the costs of trading in the various markets. There are several different
possible costs that need to be considered in answering that question.
Some securities markets, such as several proprietary trading systems,
charge access fees for executing investors' orders. Moreover,
finding the absolute best price -- even in the absence of access fees --
for any given order may not be a cost-effective use of a broker's
resources and time. Automatically routing orders to a particular
securities market, even if it does not always offer the best possible
price, may be the best way to handle large numbers of small orders that
do not merit individualized treatment.
Payments and commissions Obviously, most individual investors do
not form a judgment, let alone an informed one, on the quality of a
broker's trade execution. That is not a sign of irrationality or
incompetence. Rather, it demonstrates just the opposite; the amount of
energy and time necessary to make such a judgment simply is not worth
it. Life is, alas, short. Even poor brokerage quality on an order will
likely cost an investor, at the most, only a few dollars. Because of
investors' inability to monitor brokerage performance, brokers will
compete for investors' orders not on the basis of trade execution
performance but on other dimensions that investors can, and do, form a
judgment.
Probably the single most important of those dimensions is
commission rates. Brokers who receive payments for order flow will tend
to route orders to whoever offers the largest payments. With that money
in hand, the broker will have a powerful incentive to reduce its
commission rates because doing so will make it more attractive to
investors placing orders. If a broker foregoes some order flow payments
in order to route investors' orders to the market offering the best
price (but not the largest order flow payments), it will have to charge
a higher commission rate as a result. Because small investors judge
brokers based on commission rates, and not on quality of trade
execution, a broker gains nothing by getting the best prices for
investors' orders.
Indeed, competition between securities markets based on order flow
payments has an additional effect. To the extent that providing inferior
trade execution enables securities markets to offer larger order flow
payments to brokers, they will do so. The security market that fails to
offer the largest payments to brokers will be placed at a competitive
disadvantage vis-a-vis those that do.
The tradeoff between inferior trade execution and maximizing order
flow payments has, in fact, occurred. Securities markets that offer
little, if any, price improvement on the NBBO price typically are the
markets offering the largest side payments. Non-NYSE dealer securities
markets, which often offer the largest order flow payments, commonly
offer limited opportunities for price improvement for small orders
routed to them pursuant to payment for order flow agreements. One study
analyzed all orders in 500 NYSE-listed securities received in 1988 and
1989. The study found that, in 1988, traders who placed orders for less
than 400 shares and had their orders routed to a non-NYSE securities
market received, on average, 1.07 cents less per share than similarly
sized orders sent to the NYSE. For small orders routed to third-market
dealers, the disparity was even larger -- 1.51 cents per share. The data
from 1989 is similar. Other subsequent econometric studies have provided
further evidence that the securities mark ets that typically offer the
largest order flow payments also often offer inferior trade execution
for the type of orders routed pursuant to payment for order flow
agreements.
How should brokers decide? If a broker is interested in maximizing
the welfare of his investors, where should it send orders? The answer to
that question is quite complicated because there are a number of
considerations that can go into trade execution decisions. Those include
such factors as price improvement opportunities on different securities
markets, order flow payments, access fees, and the cost of
individualized routing decisions. The bottom line, for most investors,
is whether they are getting the best possible overall deal, taking into
account both trade execution quality and commission rates.
Consider, for a moment, price improvement opportunities. While
unquestionably important, it is not necessarily the case that the
securities market that offers the best price (which often turns out to
be the NYSE for NYSE-listed securities) is the appropriate market to
which investors' orders should be routed. An investor's
overall economic interest may be best served by having his order routed
to a securities market offering an inferior price. Suppose a NASDAQ
dealer offered to clear an investor's order at the NBBO with an
order flow payment of $6, while the price available on the NYSE floor
for filling the order was $5 better than the NBBO. Obviously, if the
order flow payments were used to reduce the commission rate charged, an
investor would be better served if the order were sent to the dealer.
While price improvement opportunities are sometimes larger than order
flow payments, that is not inevitably so.
Speed of execution is another aspect of brokerage execution
quality. Most orders routed pursuant to order flow agreements are small
orders placed by nonprofessional traders. While immediacy might be a
very important consideration for some larger, sophisticated investors,
the difference in execution times (which amounts to a few seconds) at
the NYSE and NASDAQ is unlikely to be significant for the average
investor placing a market buy or sell order of a few hundred shares.
The appropriate market Some commentators argue that payment for
order flow is unproblematic because competition between securities
markets on the basis of providing order flow payments will still ensure
an efficient allocation of investors' orders. The market offering
the largest side payment should receive investors' orders. That
argument ignores a crucial, and often overlooked, fact: To a significant
extent, auction markets, such as the NYSE, are institutionally incapable
of providing side payments to brokers because auction markets simply
match investors' orders without dealer intermediation. It is
dealers, not auction markets, who offer (and are capable of offering)
large order flow payments for small orders.
One can readily see the consequences of the inability of auction
markets to offer order flow payments on their competitive position.
Dealer competitors have been increasingly successful in attracting order
flow in NYSE-listed stocks from the NYSE, especially in small orders. As
a percentage of all the transactions in NYSE-listed securities, the
third market's share increased from 2.39 percent in 1976 to 10.77
percent in 1995. As of 1996, the NYSE had only47 percent of the market
for orders less than 1,000 shares in NYSE-listed securities, despite the
frequent opportunity for price improvement on the NYSE.
Some conclude from those trends that investors' orders are not
being routed to the appropriate securities market. How has the SEC
responded to the practice of paying for order flow?
ENTER THE REGULATORS
Regulators have long focused their attention on the issues
surrounding how investors' orders are routed to securities markets.
The Securities Acts Amendments of 1975 explicitly instructed the SEC to
ensure that investors' orders receive "an opportunity to
obtain best execution." Since that time, the SEC has tirelessly and
repeatedly proclaimed the importance of guaranteeing that
investors' orders receive the best possible execution. Numerous
regulatory structures have been erected to that end, but they have met
with very little success.
Intermarket trading system rules One such regulatory attempt was
the adoption of intermarket trading system rules that require securities
markets to match the NBBO or route an investor's order to the
securities market offering the NBBO. The rules were adopted in the hope
that they would guarantee that investors' orders would receive best
execution and that securities markets would compete on the basis of
posting competitive quotes. But the regime has been a near-complete
failure because the NBBO often is not the best price that investors can
get. For a variety of reasons, securities markets are either unwilling
or incapable of publicly posting their best price and thereby competing
for order flow on that basis.
There are several reasons why the prices available on exchanges
often are better than publicly posted prices. One reason is that auction
markets are able to cross investors' orders directly at prices
within the NBBO spread. Whether an investor's order will be crossed
at prices better than the NBBO is very difficult to predict (and hence
reflect in the publicly posted price) because it depends on the other
orders that happen to be routed to the exchange floor at a particular
point in time.
Another reason that exchange prices often are better than the NBBO
is because of the arbitrage risk a securities market creates if it
publicly posts its best price. If market conditions change and the
securities market is unable to adjust its public quotation quickly
enough, the securities market might very well have to buy or sell stocks
at a value different than what they are worth. Sophisticated traders
will quickly take advantage of any outdated or ill-advised quotations at
the expense of securities markets. Indeed, securities markets are very
mindful of that fact; the National Association of Securities Dealers has
documented that markets have been forced to widen their posted spreads
in order to protect themselves against such arbitrage possibilities.
Disclosure requirements In an attempt to address concerns over
order flow payments, the SEC has imposed disclosure requirements on
brokers, mandating that they release information concerning the payments
that they receive. Investors, upon request, can receive detailed
information concerning the routing of their orders. But it is unclear
whether the statements provide investors with useful information. An
investor should not be concerned with brokerage receipt of side payments
per se, but rather the extent to which the broker is forgoing price-improvement opportunities as a result. Furthermore, the functional
equivalent of order flow payments can be created through internal
routing of order flow in a vertically integrated broker-dealer firm,
without money ever changing hands. The disclosure requirements do little
to address internalization.
A DIFFERENT APPROACH: DEREGULATION
A better approach to addressing order flow payment concerns would
be the removal of the legal requirement that brokers credit
investors' orders with the actual price received. Brokers could
then fill investors' orders at the NBBO and keep any price
improvement realized on the order for themselves. Let us call this the
"NBBO pricing option."
A broker who adopts the NBBO pricing option will have a powerful
incentive to route small investors' orders to the securities market
offering the best possible price, because the failure to do so would
come at the broker's expense. Of course, if the market offering the
best possible price for an order also charged large access fees, or if
the benefits of the best price were otherwise economically outweighed,
the broker may decide to send the order to another securities market. In
any event, brokers would have the proper incentive to make the efficient
routing decision.
How would that benefit investors? The fact that discount brokers
have been using their sizable order flow payments to reduce their
commission rates points to the answer. There can be little doubt of the
intense competition between brokers over commission fees. As a result,
any benefits accruing to brokers from employing the NBBO pricing option
would accrue to investors in a form they could readily observe and
appreciate -- most likely lower commission rates.
With an efficient allocation of investors' orders, brokers
would no longer reward securities markets for merely offering side
payments in lieu of better prices. Auction markets such as the NYSE
would no longer be disadvantaged just because they are institutionally
incapable of offering order flow payments. Indeed, to the extent that
prices can adjust more quickly and at less cost than side payments,
markets will have a new reason to compete on the basis of posting
competitive prices.
An analogy might be useful in illustrating the logic behind such
deregulation. No one protests the fact that car manufacturers
occasionally receive cash rebates from their suppliers. If General
Motors were to receive a rebate from its muffler supplier, is the
automaker less likely to serve the interests of its customers? Of course
not. Presumably, any rebate would be passed along to car buyers in the
form of lower prices. The same would be true in the securities industry.
Deregulation would permit brokers, like other firms in the economy, to
pass on to investors the benefits resulting from their vertical
relationships.
Old vision Why has such deregulation not already occurred? Why,
instead, has the SEC erected an ineffective and cumbersome regulatory
regime? One reason lies in the fact that securities market regulation,
and the attitudes that have informed it, has not adequately reflected
the dramatic increase in competition faced by securities markets in
recent times. A regulatory mindset that evolved in the presence of
natural monopolies, as the NYSE once was, now is anachronistic.
A second reason is the SEC'S implicit vision of how
competition between securities markets should be structured. That vision
is one of competition for order flow based on public price quotations
posted by securities markets -- whichever market offers the best
publicly posted price should receive investors' orders. Order flow
payments and other forms of nonprice competition represent a threat to
that vision (although it is only a vision, as there is relatively little
quote-competition between the securities markets). Deregulation of how
brokers compete for investors' business, which could conceivably
(but not necessarily) result in more competition over commission rates
and other nonprice dimensions, would represent a move from the vision of
quote-based competition.
CONCLUSION
There has been increasing general recognition over the last 25
years (even if there is sometimes a failure to act on it) that a
regulatory cure can often be worse than the purported market failure. In
the case of payments for order flow, the purported market failure -- an
alleged conflict of interest between brokers and investors -- is, in
reality, the unintended byproduct of the current regulatory structure.
Rather than more regulation, the appropriate course of action to resolve
the market flow payment issue is deregulation.
Perhaps more importantly, there is a general lesson to be drawn
concerning how the regulation of securities markets should be
approached. The current level of competition substantially increases the
justificatory burden of a would-be regulator. Regulators should
appreciate the value of that competition instead of promulgating new
rules that impede competition and, as a result, harm investors.
READINGS
* "Best Execution in Market 2000: An Examination of Current
Equity Market Developments," published by the Securities and
Exchange Commission, 1994.
* "The Causes and Consequences of the Rise in Third Market and
Regional Trading," by Hans R. Stoll. Journal of Corporate Law, Vol.
19 (1994).
* "Differences in Execution Prices Among the NYSE, the
Regionals, and NASD," Working Paper 4-92, by Marshall E. Blume and
Michael Goldstein. White Center for Financial Research, 1992.
* "The Law and Economics of Best Execution," by Jonathan
Macey and Maureen O'Hara. Journal of Financial intermediation, Vol.
6 (1997).
* "Market Integration and Price Execution for NYSE-Listed
Securities," by Charles M.C. Lee. Journal of Finance, Vol. 48
(1993).
* "Posted versus Effective Spreads: Good Prices or Bad
Quotes?" by David Fialkowski and Mitchell A. Peterson. Journal of
Finance, Vol. 35 (1994).
* "A Proposal for Solving the 'Payment for Order
Flow' Problem," by Allen Ferrell. Southern Cal California Law
Review, Vol. 74 (2001).
* "Report on the Practice of Preferencing," published by
the Securities and Exchange Commission, 1997.
* "U.S. Equity Markets: Recent Competitive Developments,"
by James E. Shapiro. Printed in Global Equity Markets: Technological,
Competitive, and Regulatory Challenges, edited by Robert A. Schwartz.
New York, N.Y.: McGraw-Hill Professional Publishing, 1995.
Allen Ferrell is an assistant professor of law at Harvard
University and a former Harvard John M. Olin Research Professor in Law,
Economics, and Business. He is also a member of the National Association
of Securities Dealers' Economic Advisory Board. His interests
include corporate governance, finance, regulation of financial
institutions, and securities regulation. He can be contacted by e-mail
at fferrell@law.harvard.edu.