Not calling the police (First): a market for response would lower the public cost of false alarms. (Law Enforcement).
Blackstone, Erwin A. ; Hakim, Simon ; Spiegel, Uriel 等
COMMUNITIES ACROSS THE UNITED States created and operate 911
emergency communication systems to provide prompt response for medical,
fire, and law enforcement emergencies. Many of those systems have
carried heavy call loads for years, but they have become even more
burdened after September 11, as callers report suspicious activities
that they fear might be linked to terrorism.
The burden on the nation's 911 systems would be lessened
significantly if there were a decrease in the number of incoming
non-emergency calls and false fire and burglar alarms. For example, 53
percent of 911 calls in Atlanta during 1997 were of a non-emergency
nature. In 2000, Philadelphia police reported that 96 percent of fire
alarms, 97 percent of burglar alarms, and 75 percent of medical alarms
turned Out to be of a non-event nature. Those false alarms and
non-emergency calls place an enormous burden on emergency services providers and the public; each response consumes valuable resources and
subtracts from the manpower that could be mustered for real emergencies.
One especially costly form of non-emergency call is police response
to activated home and business burglar alarms. Police response to
burglar alarms constitutes 10 to 20 percent of all police calls, but 94
to 99 percent of those alarms turn out to be false. For example, in
DeKalb, Ga., in 2000, only 39 out of over 144,000 alarm calls were
actual or attempted burglaries. That same year, 97.5 percent of 30,000
police responses to burglar alarms in Seattle were false, and only 40
burglars were actually apprehended. Chicago police annually respond to
over 300,000 alarms, 98 percent of which are false.
Those false activations involve significant cost. In 2000, total
national cost for responding to 36 million false burglar alarms was $1.8
billion. If the alarm problem did not exist, at least 35,000 officers
could be shifted to other duties. Those financial and manpower costs
prove especially burdensome for police departments in large cities. For
example, the Seattle Police Department calculated that, on average, it
cost the department $52 to respond to each false alarm in 2000. And the
police were not the only emergency service providers affected by the
alarms; the city's 911 center spent $303,237 processing alarm calls
in 2000, most of which were false.
Undercurrent conditions, police response to false alarms yields no
benefits to the community. Instead, response is an earmarked service to
the alarm owner that slows overall police response because of the large
number of false alarms. Accordingly, few burglars "on the job"
are apprehended. Thus, the effectiveness of burglar alarms in capturing
or deterring burglars is modest, and the cost per arrested burglar is
high. In Seattle, the cost per burglar for the 40 who were apprehended
during alarm calls in 2000 was $38,500.
POLICY RESPONSES
Local governments have attempted many "solutions" to the
false alarm problem. Those include fines for false alarms, education
programs for alarm owners, a cessation of response services for repeat
false activators, the imposition of registration fees on alarm
ownership, and even mandates that calls for alarm response come over
"900" phone lines. None of those "solutions" has
achieved more than short-term success.
Fines Local governments that implement false alarm fines typically
allow an alarm owner three "free passes" per year. (Public and
religious institutions often enjoy unlimited free response.) Additional
false activations result in a fine of either a standard amount or at an
escalating rate. New Orleans, for example, provides five responses per
year at no charge, but then assesses a fine of $25 for false alarms six
to 14, and $75 for 15 to 20 in a year. The city ceases response after 20
false alarms.
Punitive policies range from simply refusing to respond after a
certain number of false activations in a year to possible arrest of the
alarm owner. Pennsylvania state law makes more than three false alarms a
summary criminal offense, punishable by a fine of $300. What is more, in
accordance with last year's much publicized U.S. Supreme Court
decision, someone charged with even a minor summary offense punishable
by no more than a small fine can be arrested. Hence, by law, the owner
of an alarm that is inadvertently activated could be taken to jail in
some communities.
The false activator should not be viewed as a criminal. Fines are
aimed at punishing offenders and/or deterring particular behavior.
Responding to an alarm should be viewed as a market transaction where a
service is rendered. Fines should reflect the probability of an event
multiplied by the social cost of the adverse behavior. In the case of
alarms, the only damage is the opportunity cost of the resources that
can be simply priced. Punitive action is inappropriate.
Education In most cases, a small group of alarm owners is
responsible for most false activations. User error accounts for 76
percent of all false alarms, and 20 percent of users account for 80
percent of false alarms. In an effort to curtail the number of
"repeat offenders," some police departments conduct seminars
and visit with repeat activators to suggest how to curb false
activations. For example, West Palm Beach, Fla., will forego assessing a
$250 false alarm fine if the alarm owner chooses to attend a one-hour
class.
Unfortunately, those education programs appear to have little, if
any, positive effects. In cities such as Ft. Lauderdale, Fla., Portland,
Ore., Philadelphia, and Elgin, Ill., police education programs met with
no long-term success, even though the police expended considerable
resources that could have been better used in other activities.
Registration fees Some communities require home- and business
owners who purchase alarms to pay "registration fees" that are
intended to defray the cost of monitoring and response. As a result of
those policies, police departments and alarm companies expend enormous
effort on registration records and the handling of fees. What is more,
the fees are collected from all alarm owners --both the cautious and the
negligent -- so they do not provide a disincentive for repeat false
activators. Instead, careful owners subsidize alarm activators.
Price and cost The fundamental problem with all of those strategies
is that the pricing of the service is divorced from the cost of
production that would prevail under competitive market conditions. Most
communities price response below cost. That, of course, discourages
caution in the use of alarms. In communities where there is no express
fee for response, all taxpayers -- including those who do not have
alarms -- subsidize the false activators. And, in communities where
there are fees, careful alarm owners subsidize false activators.
There are also problems for communities that price alarm response
above cost. Such pricing is a disincentive to potential alarm purchasers
and, thus, unnecessarily restricts the use of alarm systems and
sacrifices security. What is more, the overpricing means that alarm
activators subsidize other activities of the municipality.
In order to address the false alarm problem, communities must price
response correctly. There should be no unfair subsidizing of repeat
false activators by others (or vice versa), and repeat false alarm
activators should pay the price for the many responses that they
produce. The most efficient way to accomplish that pricing is to
establish a market of private alarm response providers.
AN ALARM RESPONSE MARKET
Even though police currently provide alarm response services at
taxpayer expense, that service could be provided privately. That way,
consumption of the alarm response private goods would be restricted to
those who pay, and service providers would adjust their pricing to
adequately cover the service.
Critics of such a move to markets would argue that response to an
alarm is a public good and, therefore, properly an obligation of the
police. The actual capture of a suspect by police reduces the pool of
active burglars and provides spillover benefits to the entire community,
and thus is properly thought of as a public good. Thus, the police
should not charge for response to an actual or attempted burglary. But
94 to 99 percent of all alarm activations are false; hence, response to
those activations should not be the responsibility of the public. When
police respond to false activations, the community at large subsidizes a
private service provided solely to the activator. Clearly, such cross
subsidies are unwarranted; if police divest the service, alarm owners
will contact private guard companies to respond.
Under a market approach, police would only respond to a request
from someone on site who has verified that an actual or attempted
burglary probably occurred or is occurring. When a real burglary occurs
(remember that no more than six percent of alarm activations are for a
real event), the police respond. That likely would improve the arrest
rate for burglars (and thus provide a public benefit) because police
would be relieved of the duty to respond to all alarm activations, and
instead would respond more quickly to confirmed burglary attempts.
Case study Salt Lake City implemented such a policy in December of
2000, after years of mounting costs and lost man-hours from false
alarms. In the preceding year, Salt Lake police responded to 8,213 false
alarms, at a direct cost of $492,780. The average response time was 40
minutes and occasionally took as long as 2.5 hours. Further, only 12
percent of the city's residences and businesses had alarm systems;
hence, 88 percent of the population subsidized a private service to a
small, well-defined group of people. The large number of false alarms
had more than just a financial cost for Salt Lake residents; because
police were kept busy with false alarm calls, the department was forced
to downgrade response to other public services, such as response to
domestic disturbance calls.
Those public costs dissipated significantly following the December
2000 ordinance. Police were no longer the primary responders to burglar
alarms; instead, seven guard companies began offering initial response
services for fees ranging from $15 to $35 an incident - rates that were
substantially less than the $60 average cost to the police. (One company
offered a monthly contract for $30 that included unlimited response.)
Security company response time ranged from six to 15 minutes, with most
responses under 10 minutes. One company even offered a guarantee that
response would occur within 20 minutes or there would be no charge for
the service.
In the first seven months following implementation of the new
policy, police response to false alarms dropped a remarkable 90 percent.
That decline translated to a direct savings to police of about $400,000.
The reduction in false alarms enabled the Salt Lake police to respond
more quickly to other emergencies, resulting in an overall decrease in
average police response times from five minutes to three.
Importantly, the number of burglaries did not increase under the
new policy; in fact, there was a 24-percent decline from 1998. Also,
during those first seven months of the new policy, police arrested six
burglars while responding to only 720 calls; that compares favorably to
the five burglars whom police arrested in all of 1999 when they
responded to 10,200 calls.
Market potential There is no reason to think that the Salt Lake
City results could not be replicated elsewhere. If other areas were to
adopt similar policies, many private security firms would enter the
market to provide services. Such a market would prove very inviting
because alarm response involves modest skills, is labor intensive, the
extent of economies of scale is limited, and entry barriers are modest.
Thus, in large urban areas, many alarm response companies would offer
various products if the police response were no longer subsidized.
Guard firms, in particular, are strong potential entrants. For
example, in Philadelphia in 1995, there were 54 establishments providing
detective and armored car services, all of which employed guards who
could double as alarm responders. The market for alarm response would
enjoy economies of scope; the lowered costs arise from the provision of
bundles of services that include response, patrol, vacation services,
and stationary guards. Alarm companies that offer installation,
monitoring, and physical response to alarms probably would also enjoy
such economies.
Public-private competition Another approach to reducing the public
cost of false alarms would be for police departments and private firms
to compete in the same marketplace over the provision of initial
response services. Some police departments that want to accrue
additional revenue and have sufficient resources to provide response
could offer the service to customers at a price. It is even possible
that some police departments would provide service outside of their
jurisdiction lines. Economies of scale and scope, even if modest in
extent, may prompt police to compete in response, and bid for service in
adjacent communities. Potential customers, in turn, maybe willing to pay
for the premium service provided by police, or may opt for service from
a private firm that likely would have lower rates.
To foster competition, police departments would have to remove
entry barriers such as free responses and pricing below cost. Cost-based
pricing by police would enable entry by private security companies and
eliminate cross subsidies that unfairly harm taxpayers who do not have
alarm systems or who do not trigger false alarms regularly. Such a
marketplace of police and private services would offer consumers a
variety of choices in quality of service and price.
OTHER NON-PUBLIC GOODS
A private market for initial alarm response reduces the number of
false activations, reduces taxpayer costs, and allows police to
concentrate on the apprehension of criminals. Could those benefits be
brought to other services provided by police departments?
Police departments provide many services that are not true public
goods, such as escorting funerals, conducting investigations for
insurance purposes, and opening locked cars. Those services could also
be turned over to private service providers. Perhaps private competitors
could even handle such traditional police services as crime
investigation, traffic control, parking violations, and management of
911 systems. Relieved of those duties, the police could better focus on
the true law enforcement duties of apprehending perpetrators and
protecting the peace.
READINGS
* "City Services in the Competitive Marketplace," by
Stephen Goldsmith. Published in Making Government Work: Lessons from
America's Governors and Mayors, edited by Paul Andrisani, Simon
Hakim, and Eva Leeds. Lanham, Md.: Rowman and Littlefield, 2000.
* "Crying Wolf with Public Safety," by Erwin A.
Blackstone and Simon Hakim. American City and County, August 1996.
* "Dividend Justices: Back Full Arrest on Minor Charges,"
by Linda Greenhouse. New York Times, April 25, 2001, p. Al.
* "An Economic Theory of Clubs," by James M. Buchanan.
Economica, Vol. 32, No. 2 (February 1965).
* "Erie Bank File Suit Against Police to Contest Law,"
published in Security Sales, March 2001. p. 24.
* "The False Alarm Solution: Verified Response,"
published by the Salt Lake City Police Department. No date.
* "Keeping a Watchful Eye on the Cost of Response to False
Alarms," by Simon Hakim and Erwin A. Blackstone. Security Dealer,
August 1996.
* Model States Report, published by the Alarm Industry Research and
Education Foundation (AIREF). Bethesda, Md., AIREF: 1999.
* Police Services: The Private Challenge, by Erwin A. Blackstone
and Simon Hakim. Oakland, Calif: The Independent Institute, 1996.
* "Private Ayes: A Tale of Four Cities," by Erwin A.
Blackstone and Simon Hakim. American City and County, February 1997.
* "Privatization in Criminal Justice: One Perspective in
Southern California," by Jerry A. Usher. Published in Privatizing
the U.S. Justice System, edited by Gary W. Bowman et al. Jefferson,
N.C.: McFarland Publisher, 1992
* Securing Home and Business: A Guide to the Electronic Security
Industry, by Simon Hakim and Erwin A. Blackstone. Newton, Mass.:
Butterworth-Heinemann, 1997.
* The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods and Club Goods, by
Richard Comes and Todd Sandler. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University
Press, 1986.
Erwin A. Blackstone is a professor of economics at Temple
University and a member of Temple's Center for Competitive
Government He has written on a number of topics, including antitrust and
the removal of market barriers. Blackstone can be contacted by e-mail at
eablacks@sbm.temple.edu.
Simon Hakim is a professor of economics at Temple University and
the co-director of Temple's Center for Competitive Government. He
has written on crime and deterrence, and police expenditures and
organization. He can be contacted by e-mail at shakim@sbm.temple.edu.
Uriel Spiegel is an associate professor of economics at Bar-Ilan
University in Ramat-Gan, Israel. He has written on public finance,
microeconomics, privatization, and industrial organization.