Banking approaches the modern era: though some oppressive Depression-era regulation has been removed, there is still need for reform of the U.S. banking industry. (Banking & Finance).
Calomiris, Charles W.
THE PAST TWO DECADES HAVE SEEN A radical transformation of
regulations controlling the size, location, and activities of U.S.
banks. Included in those changes are state--level reforms of branching
barriers, relaxation of deposit interest rate ceilings, the passage of a
nationwide bank-branching law in 1994, and the expansion of bank powers
throughout the 1980s and 1990s. The reforms culminated in the passage of
the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act of 1999, which established financial holding
companies -- an alternative to more limited bank holding companies -- as
a platform for building the global, universal U.S. banks of the next
generation.
Prior to the sea change of the past two decades, banks mostly
focused narrowly on deposit taking and lending in separate local
markets. Now, U.S. banks operate on an unprecedented large scale
throughout the country and the world, and are able to marry traditional
lending and deposit-taking activities with investment banking, private
equity investing, asset management, insurance, and many other financial
services. What caused the drastic changes? What barriers to efficient
financial intermediation still remain? And what have we learned from the
recent experience about the next wave of innovation and deregulation in
the financial services industry?
A BRIEF HISTORY
In order to answer those questions, we must first recognize how
unusual the prior structure of U.S. commercial banking was in comparison
with other countries' banking systems. Commercial banking began in
the United States, as in most other countries, as an instrument of state
intervention and economic planning. Banks were chartered in the late
eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries to accomplish
government-sanctioned purposes. The scarcity of such charters created
monopoly rent for banks, which acted as an implicit tax-and-transfer
scheme that supported the activities in which the favored banks engaged.
By the middle of the nineteenth century, in most states, that
mercantilist approach was replaced by one of "free" bank
chartering. But banks were still subject to special taxes or required to
hold government paper as part of their extensive regulatory mandate.
State regulation One key feature of the U.S. system was that state
laws largely determined bank regulation. States were free to establish
barriers to entry in banking that limited new entrants from competing
with existing banks. Not only was interstate banking forbidden, but, in
most states until the 1980s, competition within states was also
circumscribed by regulations that limited branching or consolidation.
Despite the Constitution's clear mandate to ensure unfettered
interstate commerce, the Supreme Court did not interpret interstate
banking barriers as barriers to commerce. That opened the way for local
special interest groups (including both bankers and some bank borrowers)
to lobby for branching restrictions. The limits on branching produced a
system of thousands of banks, which reached nearly 30,000 by 1921.
Consequences The geographic fragmentation and narrowly
circumscribed powers of American banks made the U.S. system inferior in
several respects. It limited diversification of loan risks and
diversification of income from mixing different banking services. Small,
undiversified banks tended to be riskier, leading to greater instability
during economic downturns. Small, rural banks were most vulnerable, and
they responded by lobbying for deposit insurance -- at both the state
and national levels -- as a means to protect themselves at the expense
of taxpayers and large banks (which bore a disproportional share of the
costs of mutual deposit insurance). The perverse incentives of
state-level deposit insurance systems enacted before World War I
produced banking collapses in several states in the 1920s, which added
further to the costs from unit banking.
Unit banking also created a mismatch between the small scale of
banks and the growing scale of industrial enterprises, which
increasingly came to operate regional or nationwide networks of
production and distribution during the second industrial revolution of
the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. The mismatch made it
increasingly difficult for banks to finance industrial activity, either
as lenders or as underwriters of securities, and thus made the cost of
industrial finance unnecessarily high.
Finally, unit banking made agricultural finance more costly by
limiting the development of regional or national markets for
bankers' acceptances to finance the movement of crops (an
instrument that was prevalent in other countries). Bankers'
acceptances worked best in the context of nationwide branch banking,
where banks could finance crop movements through the clearing of
balances across regions within the same bank.
The Depression In the wake of the agricultural banking busts of the
1920s, those flaws became increasingly apparent to critics of the
American bank regulatory system. The recognition of the bank fragility
produced by entry barriers underlay a widespread and successful movement
to permit branching and consolidation within and across states, and to
repeal deposit insurance. As banks grew in size, they also found it
beneficial to increase industrial lending and develop additional
services for industrial borrowers, including the underwriting of
securities offerings. But the Great Depression cut that initial wave of
bank deregulation short.
The Depression accentuated the weakness of many small banks that
were already distressed. Bank distress during the Depression is a
complex subject. Recent empirical research by Joseph Mason and me shows
that, prior to 1933 (the trough of the Great Depression), the 1930s bank
failures -- like those of the 1920s -- were regional phenomena that
mirrored deteriorating local economic fundamentals. In early 1933,
sudden, economy-wide deposit withdrawals -- produced in part by
anticipation of President Franklin Roosevelt's decision to abandon
the gold standard -- led to a nationwide "bank holiday." But
before 1933, bank failures varied across regions in severity and timing,
and were predictable results of changes in local economic activity.
Local runs on banks (much less nationwide runs on banks) were not
important contributors to bank distress prior to early 1933.
From the standpoint of economic reasoning, the Great Depression
reinforced the logic of bank deregulation by showing the vulnerability
of a geographically fragmented and undiversified banking system.
Moreover, as Eugene White has shown, the Depression years also revealed
an advantage from universal banking: Banks that engaged in securities
underwriting during the 1920s benefited from greater income
diversification and were less likely to fail during the Depression.
Backlash But the effect of the Depression on the political economy
of bank regulation was to reverse the process of deregulation and the
removal of entry barriers. Populist senators and congressmen defended
small banks and portrayed them as victims of rapacious large banks,
which they accused of dishonest practices and blamed for causing the
Depression. The mixing of commercial and investment banking was
particularly vilified as creating conflicts of interest within banks
that combined underwriting and lending.
Recent historical studies by Randall Kroszner and Raghuram Rajan,
and by George Benston, have refuted congressional allegations that
universal banking promoted conflicts of interest. But those studies were
produced too late to prevent the regulatory backlash caused by
congressional accusations of impropriety. The historic 1933 Banking Act
was a classic logrolling compromise through which populist supporters of
small, rural banks, like Rep. Henry Steagall, won federal deposit
insurance in exchange for limiting the investment banking activities of
commercial banks (a favorite hobby horse of the sincere but misguided
Sen. Carter Glass).
From the standpoint of the industry and the public, federal deposit
insurance and limits on commercial banks was a "lose-lose"
compromise. From the standpoint of Congress, it was the usual
"win-win."
WHY DEREGULATION AFTER 1980?
From the perspective of this thumbnail historical sketch of U.S.
banking history, one might argue that the most remarkable aspect of the
post-1980 bank deregulation is that it was so delayed. Why did it take
so long to correct the regulatory mistakes that were exacerbated by the
Great Depression? What finally led the government to permit banks to
diversify regionally and branch out in products as well as locations?
Interestingly, the process of reform in the 1980s was somewhat
similar to the earlier experience of the 1920s. In both eras, bank
distress was an important spur to change, as it created local demands
for new inflows of bank credit to replace failed or shrinking banks.
That led to the relaxation of branching restrictions, first at the state
level, then regionally and nationally. And fortunately, there was no
Great Depression shock to interrupt the new process of rationalization
and reform.
Competition An additional important influence on post-1980
deregulation was the growing corn petition that American banks faced,
both domestically from securities markets and non-bank intermediaries
(e.g., finance companies) and internationally from other countries'
banks as opportunities for international competition expanded. The
constraining influence of American regulation became recognized both as
a cause of foreign bank entry into U.S. markets and a barrier to the
expansion of U.S. banks abroad. Technological changes in communications
and information technology that facilitated the development of
securities markets and international capital flows played a role here,
because they permitted new entrants to compete more easily with U.S.
banks and thus drove reluctant politicians to act. (See "The
Motivations Behind Banking Reform," Summer 2001.)
Regulation Q Another influence on competitive pressures facing
banks was the high inflation environment of the late 1960s and 1970s.
High inflation reduced the attractiveness of bank deposits, whose
interest rates were subject to "Regulation Q" ceilings.
Regulation Q -- another provision of the 1933 Act -- was intended in
part to limit competition within banking, and thereby strengthen banks.
Its other purpose was to discourage commercial bank financing of stock
market transactions through the call loan market. In the 1930s, Sen.
Glass opposed the "pyramiding" of reserves -- interbank
transfers of deposits to New York banks during times of low loan demand
in the periphery--because he believed that the practice made banks too
vulnerable to stock market cycles. Regulation Q was intended to cure the
alleged malady.
The most important effect of Regulation Q was to limit banks'
ability to compete with non-bank sources of finance in the 1960s and
1970s. High inflation eroded the return that savers could earn on
low-interest deposits, and thus encouraged alternative intermediaries
(e.g., credit unions and finance companies) and alternative instruments
to deposits, the most important of which was commercial paper. The
commercial paper market grew rapidly in the 1960s and 1970s, and became
an important alternative to bank loans for high-quality corporate
issuers. Just as importantly, commercial paper was the primary means of
financing the growth of finance companies, which became important
competitors in both commercial and consumer lending.
Institutional investors High and uncertain inflation also pointed
to the advantages of equity investments over debt in household
portfolios, and that encouraged the growth of equity as an alternative
to debt in corporate finance. The move to equities received assistance
from the establishment of new equity-holding intermediaries -- pension
funds and mutual funds -- that, as wholesale purchasers of stock
offerings, substantially reduced the physical and informational costs of
placing equity. The new "institutional investors" also funded
pioneering efforts in the development of venture capital intermediaries,
which transformed the financing options of growing young firms in new
industries. The growth of institutional investors was encouraged by tax
incentives for employee pensions and the decreasing attractiveness of
fixed-income instruments.
The need for change All of those changes in intermediation
technology became important in the 1960s and 1970s, and served to
undermine the dominant position of depository institutions as
repositories of savings and sources of funding. Because the banks'
new competitors were outside the purview of U.S. bank regulation, the
regulators were faced with the choice of either overseeing the shrinkage
of the U.S. banking industry or fostering its efficient transformation
through deregulation. The Federal Reserve played an important role in
advancing deregulation by relaxing barriers on bank activities (to the
extent allowed bylaw) and advocating the need for more sweeping changes
to preserve the competitive position of American banks.
Deposit insurance In addition to the relaxation of interest rate
ceilings, the elimination of entry barriers, and the expansion of bank
activities, the 1 980s and 1990s saw important changes to federal
deposit insurance. The reforms included the establishment of minimum
capital standards and the creation of a set of rules, collectively known
as "prompt corrective action," that, in principle, should
result in the closure of undercapitalized or insolvent banks before they
produce large losses for the insurance fund.
The reforms attempt to prevent deposit insurance from subsidizing
(and thus encouraging) greater risk-taking by banks. Here, the spurs to
change were the costly and politically embarrassing activities of
risk-taking thrifts and banks during the 1980s. The FIRREA Act of 1989
and the FDICIA Act of 1991 -- although unsatisfactory in important
respects -- represented a relatively rapid response (by congressional
standards) to the thrift and banking crises of the 1980s. As with the
Banking Act of 1933, Congress acted because the political costs of
failing to address perceived regulatory flaws became significantly
large.
BANKING AFTER THE REGULATORY CHANGES
The regulatory changes of the 1 980s and 1 990s are reflected in a
fundamental transformation within the banking industry. The industry now
consists of a complex structure of holding company subsidiaries that
perform a variety of financial transactions.
Size The size distribution of banks has taken on a
"barbell" shape, with giant nationwide banks and small local
banks, but few in between. The consolidation wave of the 1980s and 1990s
saw middling-size banks absorbed by nationwide or
"super-regional" powerhouses. There is a clear link between
size and scope driving scale economies in universal banking. Only larger
banks that operate vast networks, which can spread overhead costs over
many clients and assets, can expand into the full range of products and
services needed to enhance the value of bank-client relationships. Some
products (e.g., asset securitization, trust management, and derivatives
origination) enjoy very large economies of scale.
Interestingly, small banks have not disappeared. In fact, many new
small banks have been chartered during the consolidation waves of the 1
980s and 1 990s. The reason the small banks persist is that not all bank
customers need the full range of banking products and services provided
by large-scale universal banks. Small banks have flatter organizational
structures, implying less decision-making distance between senior
management and customers. In some instances, the shorter distance
permits small banks to process information about customer
creditworthiness more quickly, especially when judgments about the
character and experience of the borrower are central to the loan
decision. If small banks focus on particular niches defined by types of
customers they wish to attract, they can do so with greater agility than
larger universal banks, which must be all things to all people.
Technological changes that permit Internet access and
"outsourcing" allow small banks to profitably perform a wide
range of functions for customers in which they serve as the customer
contact but not the ultimate executor of all aspects of the transaction.
The availability of derivatives as hedging instruments and the
availability of software to assist small institutions in determining
their market risk exposures have also removed some of the competitive
disadvantage in managing market risk that used to adhere to small size.
Who benefits? It is not clear whether, on balance, regulation
currently favors small or large banks. Some fixed costs associated with
regulatory compliance favor large banks. On the other hand, large banks
make more attractive targets for extortionist demands by "community
groups," particularly when those banks seek regulatory approval for
large mergers. And the cost structure of check clearing by the Fed
(which does not charge marginal cost for its services) probably favors
small banks. Deposit insurance no longer favors large banks now that the
"too-big-to-fail" doctrine of the 1980s has been effectively
repealed as part of the 1991 FDICIA legislation. A bailout of a large
bank's uninsured depositors must now be paid for by a special
assessment on surviving banks, and thus the costs will be borne to a
large extent by surviving large banks. (See "The New Safety
Net," Summer 2001.) The hope of FDICIA's drafters is that this
will lead surviving large banks to lobby against such bailouts, thus
eliminating any f avoritism toward "too-big-to-fail" banks.
REGULATION AFTER GRAMM-LEACH-BLILEY
Gramm-Leach-Bliley accomplished three related objectives:
* It repealed remaining limits on bank entry into investment
banking and insurance.
* It established a new financial holding company structure to house
those activities.
* It defined the regulatory roles of the Fed, the Office of the
Comptroller of the Currency, the Securities and Exchange Commission, the
Commodity Futures Trading Commission, and other financial regulators in
the regulation of financial holding companies.
Although some observers greeted the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act as an
historic triumph of deregulation, it is better viewed as a modest
accomplishment. To the extent that the legislation expanded bank powers,
it was an extension and codification of changes that had occurred more
gradually over many years before the law's passage. And it is
likely that Gramm-Leach-Bliley will not be the last bank deregulation
bill. There remain several key issues not resolved by the act, and there
is every reason to believe that the continuing pressures of
technological change and competition will push the banking system
further than the drafters of Gramm-Leach-Bliley envisioned.
Six major flaws in bank regulatory structure remain:
* The lack of clarity about what financial activities are allowed
under the new law, which creates regulatory risk and invites
politicization of the regulatory process.
* The misguided goal under the new aw of segregating
"commerce" from "finance."
* The inappropriate reliance on the central bank as the overarching
financial regulator.
* The persistence of the view that chartered financial institutions
enjoy special rents by virtue of their charter, and that it is
appropriate for government to impose explicit or implicit taxes on them
to recover some of those rents.
* The absence of credible market discipline alongside supervisory
discipline to prevent abuse of the government safety net.
* The failure to rein in quasi-public institutions that compete
with private financial institutions in housing finance (i.e., the GSE problem).
In order for the U.S. banking industry to advance, lawmakers and
regulators must address each of those points.
Financial activities The new law allows financial activities to be
done within financial holding companies, but it does not clearly define
what a "financial activity" is. Whether banks should be
allowed to do real estate brokering, which is clearly a financial
activity by any reasonable definition, has been the most hotly contested
case thus far, as local real estate brokers battle to prevent banks from
entering their turf. If the Fed finds that real estate brokering is not
a financial activity, then banks will be prevented from engaging in that
activity.
Such regulatory roulette results in banks facing unnecessary risk
as they plot their strategic direction in customer and product
development. What is more, it politicizes the regulatory process. That,
no doubt, helps to explain why so few non-bank financial institutions
have sought to become financial holding companies under the rules
established by Gramm-Leach-Bliley.
Commerce vs. finance The fuzzy definition of permissible activities
is the result of the government's desire to prevent an unfettered
mixing of "finance" and "commerce." There is no
convincing economic argument for that separation.
Too risky? One commonly proffered argument revolves around the need
to limit the range of activities that can be financed by the insured
liabilities of commercial banks, in order to prevent abuse of the
government safety net. But regulators can solve that problem (and
already have solved that problem for many years) by requiring the bank
or financial holding company to house such activities (e.g., private
equity and underwriting) in separate subsidiaries. Sections 23a and 23b
of the Federal Reserve Act prevent risk transference from subsidiaries
to banks within the holding company by limiting inter-subsidiary
lending. Congress has already agreed that the safeguards are adequate
protection against risk transference to banks from non-bank financial
affiliates, so there is no reason to believe that non-financial
activities would pose a special problem for the safety net. Indeed,
there is reason to believe the opposite. Financial activities tend to
admit more opportunity for mischief in risk-taking than non-fina ncial
activities. And derivative transactions -- which can be a source of
large, sudden, increased risk by a bank looking to undertake risk at
public expense -- are often housed within chartered banks themselves.
Too powerful? Another argument for separating commerce from banking
revolves around concerns about the concentration of power that may
result from combining banking and credit. But in a large, highly
competitive economy like that of the United States, it is implausible to
argue that permitting Microsoft or AT&T to be affiliated with a
chartered commercial bank would somehow make the software or
telecommunications markets less competitive.
Trouble for the Fed The misguided separation of finance and
commerce (and the regulatory risks and political infighting that it
invites) is especially troubling given that the designated arbiter of
the definition of "financial activity" is the central bank.
Placing the Fed in the middle of such political disputes threatens its
primary monetary policy function by politicizing the central bank.
Similarly, giving the Fed "umbrella" authority to regulate
financial holding companies exposes the central bank to undesirable
political pressure. The mixing of monetary and regulatory power also
creates a potential conflict of goals within the central bank. The Fed
may be tempted to forbear from enforcing bank regulations because of
countercyclical goals that favor an expansion of credit. Recent
experience from around the world suggests that this is highly
undesirable and counterproductive behavior, but central bankers that
have such power often abuse it.
Most developed countries have recognized the dangers of housing
regulatory authority within their central banks. In Japan, Canada,
Australia, the United Kingdom, Germany, France, Italy, and many other
countries, the primary entities that regulate and supervise financial
intermediaries are independent of the monetary authorities. Only in the
United States does the central bank continue to play so important a role
in financial regulation and supervision. In part, that fact reflects the
deference with which pronouncements by Alan Greenspan were greeted on
Capitol Hill during the debate over banking reform. The Fed
chairman's successful power grab for his institution is one of the
unfortunate by-products of his remarkably successful career as a central
banker.
No rents to redistribute Another shortcoming of Gramm-Leach-Bliley
was its failure, despite the efforts of Sen. Phil Gramm (R-Texas), to
adequately address problems that were created by the Community
Reinvestment Act of 1977. (See "Renovating the CRA," Summer
2001.) The act begins with the premise that banks owe a special debt to
their communities by virtue of the privileges conferred on banks in
their charters. The CRA effectively requires banks to subsidize
community programs at their own expense.
The mercantilist logic that underlies the special taxation of
chartered banks is outdated; in today's competitive environment,
bank charters no longer confer rents on their recipients. Special taxes
on banks erode their ability to compete and discourage non-bank
financial firms from taking advantage of Gramm-Leach-Bliley provisions.
The safety net Gramm-Leach-Bliley also missed the opportunity to
extract the concession of credible deposit insurance reform from the
banking industry as a quid pro quo for deregulation. Because of its
complexity and technical nature, prudential capital regulation is little
understood or discussed in the press. But this is one of the most
important areas, inside and outside the United States, in which
government policy has failed and continues to fail.
The current approach to capital regulation -- requiring a minimum
amount of accounting equity relative to some measure of bank asset risk
as the means of establishing bank stability and proper incentives --
does not work. Neither capital nor risk is measured reliably. Experience
with bank failures in the United States over the past several years has
shown that the existing system of prompt corrective action does not
prevent many bank failures from resulting in large losses to the deposit
insurance fund.
There is a sore need for a reformed approach that incorporates
market signals into the supervisory process and depends on market
incentives to act upon perceived weaknesses in banks. Market discipline
would incorporate market estimates of bank default risk into prudential
regulation. That would increase the information used by examiners and,
even more importantly, make it harder for supervisors to deny obvious
problems. Thus, it would prevent distorted accounting and bureaucratic
"forbearance" from undermining prudential regulation.
Many advocates of reform have argued that the only credible
approach to preventing abuse of the government safety net is to
incorporate market discipline into the supervisory process. Numerous
proposals to accomplish that have been presented and debated -- most
notably, various plans to require large banks to issue a minimum amount
of uninsured debt as part of their capital requirements. The proposals
received substantial backing from academics and regulators, and even
received some support from the Bankers' Roundtable before the
passage of Gramm-Leach-Bliley. After the act passed, however, large
banks successfully opposed a subordinated debt requirement, arguing that
it was unnecessary and potentially costly.
GSEs Perhaps the final frontier of bank deregulation is the reform
of the government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) that control housing
finance in the United States (Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the twelve
Federal Home Loan Banks). The GSEs were formed with high public goals in
mind, but it appears that they have outlived their usefulness (if, in
fact, they ever were useful) and they create significant distortions and
risk.
Mae and Mac Fannie and Freddie are out of control, both
economically and politically. The two for-profit institutions enjoy
special benefits, including implicit taxpayer support for their
liabilities. Critics from across the political spectrum have chastised
the two GSEs for a number of reasons, including:
* They do not contribute significantly to Americans' ability
to own homes.
* The government guarantee of their debts wastes taxpayers'
money ($10 billion a year) and poses a risk of catastrophic loss to
taxpayers.
* Their role as privately owned firms with public benefits enables
them to compete inappropriately with U.S. Treasury securities, thus
raising government borrowing costs.
* They attempt to monopolize mortgage origination and use that
monopoly status to expand into retail operations, which could have
adverse consequences for competition in the industry.
* They exert a poisonous influence on Congress as powerful lobbying
organizations that spend oodles of cash to silence opponents.
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac should be reined in through a two-step
process: immediate prudential regulation of their financial structure
and risk management, followed by full privatization.
FHLBS The powers of the Federal Home Loan Banks (FHLBs), which
provide subsidized funding to member institutions (including thrifts,
banks, and insurance companies), were expanded under Gramm-Leach-Bliley.
Now the FHLBs provide subsidized financing of small business loans by
member institutions, in addition to subsidizing mortgage lending. Small
banks, in particular, lobbied hard for those subsidies. The political
power of the FHLBs has waxed over the past decade as they have come to
be one of the primary channels through which banks can gain access to
federal government largesse.
Possibilities What are the prospects for rectifying the GSEs'
key shortcomings? There is little immediate prospect that Congress will
address any of the problems. But in the long run, there is hope.
With respect to mixing commerce and finance, clever bankers will
find ways to work around regulatory limits, and eventually Congress
probably will be led to conclude that it is both practically impossible
and highly counterproductive to enforce such a separation. A similar
process led to the elimination of the barriers between banking and
finance, codified in 1999, and is likely to be repeated over the next
decades.
With respect to the five other problems, congressional action will
depend on the extent to which the shortcomings weaken U.S. banks to the
point that Congress is pressed to act. Here, the likely outcome is much
less certain, and will depend on exigencies that are hard to forecast.
The likelihood of reforming bank capital standards or privatizing the
GSEs will rise substantially if an embarrassing financial collapse
occurs at significant cost to taxpayers and surviving banks, just as the
prospects of removing the Fed from the regulatory process would be
heightened by a supervisory scandal.
CONCLUSION
Bank regulation does not adapt continuously to achieve the most
efficient outcome; it reacts to extreme circumstances. Those reactions
reflect unpredictable political bargains that often introduce as many
inefficient distortions as they purport to correct.
Bank deregulation in the 1980s and 1990s went a long way toward
eliminating the many inefficiencies of the state-regulated banking
system of the late 1800s. But important regulatory impediments still
exist, such as the distinction between finance and commerce, the moral
hazard created by deposit insurance, and the special status of the GSEs.
READINGS
* "Before the Glass-Steagall Act: An Analysis of the
Investment Banking Activities of National Banks," by Eugene N.
White. Explorations in Economic History, January 1986 (Vol. 23).
* "Causes of Bank Distress During the Great Depression,"
by Charles W. Calomiris and Joseph R. Mason. National Bureau of Economic
Research Working Paper, 2000.
* "Glass-Steagall: Repeal by Regulatory and Judicial
Reinterpretation," by George Kaufman and Larry Mote. Banking Law
Journal, September/October 1990.
* Government-Sponsored Enterprises: Mercantilist Companies in the
Modern World, by Thomas H. Stanton. Washington D.C.: AEI Press, 2002.
* "Is the Glass-Steagall Act Justified? A Study of the U.S.
Experience with Universal Banking Before 1933," by Randall S.
Kroszner and Raghuram G. Rajan. American Economic Review, September 1994
(Vol. 84).
* The Regulation and Reform of the American Banking System,
1900-1929, by Eugene N. White. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University
Press, 1983.
* The Separation of Commercial and Investment Banking: The
Glass-Steagall Act Revised and Reconsidered, by George Benston. Norwell,
Mass.: Kluwer Academic Press, 1989.
* Serving Two Masters, Yet Out of Control, edited by Peter J.
Wallison. Washington D.C.: AEI Press, 2001.
* The Transformation of the U.S. Banking Industry: What a Long,
Strange Trip It's Been," by Allen Berger, Anil Kashyap, and
J.M. Scalise. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1995, No. 2.
* U.S. Bank Deregulation in Historical Perspective, by Charles W.
Calomiris. New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press, 2000.
Charles W. Calomiris is the Paul M. Montrose Professor of Finance
and Economics at the Columbia Business School, the Arthur Burns Fellow
in Economics at the American Enterprise Institute, and a research
associate for the National Bureau of Economic Research. A prodigious
writer on banking and finance, Calomiris' most recent book is U.S.
Banking Deregulation in Historical Perspective. He can be contacted by
e-mail at ccalomiris@aei.org.