The dawn of a new spectrum policy? (Briefly Noted).
Thierer, Adam
IN WHAT MAY BE A WATERSHED MOMENT IN the history of American
telecommunications policy, the Federal Communications Commission's
Spectrum Policy Task Force recently released its eagerly awaited report
and proposed nothing less than a revolution in federal spectrum
management. The task force was established by FCC chairman Michael
Powell in June 2002 to explore improvements in spectrum management and
conduct the first-ever comprehensive review of spectrum policy at the
agency. The resulting report not only does an excellent job of laying
out the problems associated with federal management of the
electromagnetic spectrum, it also outlines a refreshingly bold set of
policy recommendations to correct the problems associated with nearly a
century's worth of central planning in wireless telecommunications.
The report begins by acknowledging, "The time is ripe for
spectrum policy reform. Increasing demand for spectrum-based services
and devices is straining longstanding and outmoded spectrum
policies." It notes that the FCC'S traditional
"command-and-control approach" to spectrum management is the
primary cause of the regulatory failure because that approach has
imposed significant restrictions on spectrum use and users.
Exclusivity or a commons? The task force goes on to suggest a bold
vision for governing spectrum in the future that has as its cornerstone
the principle of flexible use. The report notes that there are two ways
to achieve the goal of increased flexibility: through exclusive-use
rights or by way of a "commons" model of governance.
Under an exclusive-use model, spectrum holders would be granted
clearly defined rights and have the ability to use or sell their
spectrum however they wish. That is really just a good old-fashion
private property rights regime for spectrum allocation, even though the
FCC does not call it that. By contrast, the commons model would allow
users to employ frequency-hopping technologies to scan the spectrum for
unused frequencies. Using smart antennas, software-defined radios, and
mesh networks, spectrum users would increasingly be able to
simultaneously operate alongside other users if "overlay" or
underlay" rights are permitted for low-power, non-interfering
devices and transmissions.
A new debate The intellectual battle between adherents to the
property rights and commons models of spectrum governance has been a
refreshing telecommunications debate for two reasons. First, at the
heart of both models is a desire to promote increased flexibility,
innovation, and efficient use of the spectrum resource. More important,
both groups generally agree that the current command-and-control system
is a complete failure and must be replaced. Indeed, both commons and
property rights proponents question the continuing need for the FCC in
this process at all. Second, and perhaps because of those preceding
points, this war of ideas has not been characterized by the rancor
typically witnessed in other telecom industry disputes. Advocates of
both models have been willing to listen to one another, take seriously
the criticisms of the other side, and even integrate some of their
suggestions into each other's models.
There is good reason for them to do so. Ultimately, the future of
spectrum governance cannot come down to an either/or choice between the
two models; rather, it must reflect a synthesis of the two schools of
thought. Property rights proponents are correct to stress the important
benefits of exclusive use in the spectrum resource because many users
want the freedom to own, sublease, combine, or sell spectrum on their
own terms. Moreover, many current incumbent users of the spectrum will
argue that they have de facto rights in their spectrum licenses and
should be granted unconditional property rights anyway.
On the other hand, the commons crowd is correct in stressing the
importance of preserving certain portions of the spectrum for shared,
nonexclusive use by companies and consumers. Such shared use could take
one of two forms. First, government could designate (or, better yet,
purchase at auction) certain bands of spectrum for commons use, much as
it purchases large portions of land for public parks and opens those
areas to common use. In addition, overlay and underlay areas should be
allowed throughout the spectrum as long as users do not interfere with
other users. That is a quite practical solution, as such
"easements" already exist in some bands of the spectrum, but
many other underutilized portions could be opened up for such
homesteading. Finally, it is important to acknowledge that private
spectrum owners will likely contract with independent users to create
commons areas within their exclusive allocations. Just as shopping mall
owners lease store or sidewalk space to third parties, so too will
private s pectrum band managers sublease portions of their property for
other uses, including commons areas.
Rapid transition Now that the Spectrum Task Force has done such an
outstanding job of laying out the problem and some potential solutions,
the next logical question is when and how policymakers will respond.
Ironically, another remarkable report issued by the FCC the same day as
the task force report may offer a first step. In a new working paper
entitled "A Proposal for a Rapid Transition to Market Allocation of
Spectrum," authors Evan Kwerel and John Williams of the FCC's
Office of Plans and Policy outline an ingenious scheme to expedite the
transition to a spectrum free market. Kwerel and Williams, who have done
pioneering work on spectrum policy at the FCC, propose to auction off
untapped or underutilized spectrum while encouraging incumbent licensees
who control large swaths of spectrum to put their holdings on the
auction block. Although incumbents would have the right to opt out of
the auction entirely, if they put their spectrum on the block they would
have the ability to buy back that spectrum and ga in complete and
immediate operational flexibility. If they do not put it up for auction,
flexible use would be denied for five years. They would also have the
right to accept the highest bid for their spectrum and just walk away.
For incumbents, such a scheme would help reveal the market price of
spectrum and give them an idea of what the true opportunity costs of
holding that spectrum really are. For others desiring more spectrum, the
process would finally give them a chance to get their hands on it.
Sea change Even if the FCC takes no more action on this issue, the
Spectrum Task Force report and the new OPP study would likely constitute
an important legacy of the Bush administration's FCC. But there is
good reason to believe that the agency will take action; it has already
taken several other important steps on that front, and its leaders
remain committed to the task of spectrum reform. For example, in a
recent speech, Chairman Powell argued, "Today's marketplace
demands that we provide license holders with greater flexibility to
respond to consumer wants, market realities, and national needs without
first having to ask for the FCC's permission. I believe license
holders should be granted the maximum flexibility to use -- or allow
others to use -- the spectrum (within technical constraints) to provide
any services demanded by the public." During the Cato
Institute's annual Technology & Society conference last fall,
FCC commissioner Kathleen Abernathy delivered a sweeping set of remarks
on spectrum reform that mirrored the task force report's findings.
It would have been unthinkable for an FCC official to say such
things just 10 years ago. This is a stunning sea change in opinion on
federal spectrum management. The FCC, and the Spectrum Task Force in
particular, deserves high praise for this ground-breaking report and
breathtaking set of policy recommendations.
Adam Thierer is the director of telecommunications studies at the
Cato Institute. He can be contacted by e-mail at atheirer@cato.org.