The governance of telecommuters: an agency and transaction cost analysis.
Brice, Jeff, Jr. ; Nelson, Millicent ; Gunby, Norris White, Jr. 等
INTRODUCTION
This paper seeks to stimulate research about the managerial
challenges of a constantly evolving bureaucratic workforce.
Specifically, this work seeks to add to organizational theory by
integrating transaction cost theory and agency theory with forecasted
trends in the governance of telecommuting employees. Telecommuters, or
"teleworkers", are employees that are allowed to perform
organizational work from a residence, or other location, instead of
reporting to a centralized office location (Siha & Monroe, 2006).
While the two managerial theories have been applied in a large number of
organizational settings and circumstances, there have been no prior
attempts to integrate these theories to forecast the effects of
uncertainty on the control of a telecommuting workforce. This paper
proposes a managerial framework that incorporates transaction
uncertainty (from transaction cost theory) and outcome uncertainty (from
agency theory) as determinants of employee control. First, the two
theories are described and then adapted to present the hierarchical
governance of a telecommuting workforce. After which, propositions are
developed about which managerial control mechanisms are to be used under
varying degrees of transaction and outcome uncertainty, considering the
gravity of the work to be produced and the level of trust in the
employee.
LITERATURE REVIEW
Transaction-Cost Theory
Transaction costs are the costs of negotiating, monitoring, and
governing exchanges between people (Williamson, 1975). In transaction
cost theory, a main purpose of the organization is to reduce the overall
costs of exchanging goods and services in the environment and the costs
of supervising exchanges within the organization. In-house transaction
costs are generally labeled as "bureaucratic" or
"hierarchical" costs and are the costs that are germane to
this analysis. Internal business exchange structures of interest here
are those that concern the governance aspect of distance employees,
commonly referred to as "telecommuters".
Determinants of Transaction Costs
The major determinants of transaction costs are identified as
transaction uncertainty (Jones, 1987) and performance ambiguity (Ouchi,
1980; Jones, 1987).
Transaction uncertainty is associated with the extent that the
employer-employee alliance is not consistent. This is primarily due to a
lack of familiarity of the employer with the employee. The lesser the
degree of familiarity with the employee, the more confirmation
concerning the employee's work methods, attitude, and capability is
necessary for the employer. Transaction uncertainty may decline over
time, with augmented communication and interactivity, allowing the
operational relationship of both parties to become less unpredictable
(Jones, 1987).
Performance ambiguity is linked to the accepted hazard that an
employee takes on when work is carried out for an organization (Ouchi,
1980). Specifically, the implicit exposure involves the costs that must
be endured by the employee when work is delivered that does not have
acceptable utility for the employer. The consequences suffered for
sub-par work are typically a deficiency in the agreed upon remuneration
for such work and/or the economic opportunity cost related with having
to rectify the mistakes or recreate the deliverable(s) entirely.
Accordingly, performance ambiguity refers to the employee's
capacity to appraise work accurateness and to appropriately assess
it's usefulness for the employer (Ouchi, 1980). It is a function of
task specificity, employer assistance, and the employee's
competence in the performance of said task. The higher the levels of
task specificity, employer assistance, and employee competence, the
lower the level of performance ambiguity (Ouchi, 1980; Jones, 1987).
Agency Theory
The goal of agency theory is effective control of employees using
some form of monitoring (Eisenhardt, 1988). Agency theory approaches the
problem of employee control as a matter of risk sharing. It implies that
observability (employee monitoring) and outcome uncertainty (the
probability of incorrect work) are the determinants of control; and,
that there is an element of risk with regard to income streams in any
control system (Eisenhardt, 1988, 1989; Kren & Kerr, 1993). The more
an employee can be observed, the less risk (performance ambiguity) the
employee has to assume. Because of monitoring, the employer is more
knowledgeable about the work performed and, thus, uncertainty is
decreased.
Outcome uncertainty is also decreased by the nature of the work
involved (Eisenhardt, 1989). Standardized, routine outputs are
negatively related to outcome uncertainty because the employer and
employee know exactly what is to be produced and received. The more
secure the employer is about the usefulness of the employee's work,
the more certain is the employee's compensation. However, in
instances where observability and/or product standardization is low,
outcome uncertainty is high and the employee suffers the risk for
producing the wrong outcomes. Thus, compensation is dependent on the
organization's perceived utility of the outcomes produced. The
consequences that the employer suffers when an employee produces
low-utility output are a function of the import of the project assigned.
If incorrect employee output causes a loss of future income for the
employer, the economic ramifications (costs) are high.
Transaction Cost and Agency theories are complements of each other
because performance ambiguity and outcome uncertainty are near
equivalents. In prior research, performance ambiguity was conceptualized
as the costs that client organizations incur to monitor and evaluate the
performance of other parties in an exchange (Jones, 1987). Telecommuters
may be conceptualized much like independent organizations or other
separate entities. Traditionally, telecommuters maintain their own
working schedules and have little physical interaction with the
traditional organizational center (Bailey & Kurland, 2002). In this
paper, performance ambiguity is related to outcome uncertainty as the
economic opportunity cost (risk) incurred by employees under conditions
of low observability and/or non-routine product expectations within the
organization. Non-routine output increases the risk of incorrect
employee performance and increases the likelihood of lost economic
opportunities by the employer.
Outcome uncertainty is related, therefore, to the real or economic
costs (risk) suffered by employers associated with telecommuting
employees and the non-standard (or routine) character of their work.
The Transactional Nature of Internal Organization
A transaction is a bilateral exchange between two or more parties.
In an employment transaction, the conditions for execution are
determined and work is carried out according to procedures developed
and/or agreed upon (Commons 1950). Williamson (1975) writes that all
societal, financial, and political transactions bring about transaction
costs. In transaction cost theory, organizations transform, in both
capacity and internal alignment, in order to diminish transaction cost
difficulties over time (Yarbrough & Yarbrough, 1987).
The origins of transaction costs may be viewed as transmission
problems that are introduced into the exchange process of a market
transaction (Williamson 1975). Transaction costs are the negotiating,
monitoring, and enforcement costs that must be endured to facilitate a
transmission between several parties (Klein, Crawford, & Alchain,
1978). The six main causes of transaction complications (Jones &
Hill, 1988) are:
1. Bounded Rationality--Rational human behavior is determined
within the bounded limits of each individual's knowledge and the
cognitive facility to process information.
2. Opportunism--People tend to act according to what is aligned
with their own self-interests. Opportunism occurs when one, or both, of
the parties to a transaction seek to alter the provisions of an
agreement after the fact.
3. Uncertainty / Complexity--There is extensive uncertainty and
complexity in the business environment.
4. Small Numbers Trading Relationships--Reliance on a single
supplier for any resource will likely result in opportunistic behavior
on the part of the supplier. However, these types of trading
relationships are commonly found.
5. Asset Specificity--Significant sunk costs in resources (assets)
that have limited use outside of an individual business transaction.
6. Information Impactedness--In a typical business exchange, it is
common for one party to the transaction to have more knowledge than the
other(s).
Each one, or any combination of these sources, may bring about
transaction complications and increase costs. All of these factors make
business dealings risky and inefficient. For example, behavioral
uncertainty on the part of an employee may increase the cost of
enforcing contracts due to the possible lack of productivity brought
about by agent opportunism. In order to prevent this situation, the
employer must incur the increased cost of authoring comprehensive
agreements that will restrain employee behavior under a diversity of
situational contingencies (Arrow, 1974). Given that the employer is
limited by the bounded rationality of their own cognitive experience and
cannot plan for every contingency, increased transaction costs due to
opportunism may still be apparent because of information impactedness in
favor of the employee. In other words, the employee may find weaknesses
in the contract and exploit these to their benefit. In addition, the
threat of increased costs due to opportunism may be heightened if there
is asset specificity or small numbers bargaining conditions, which
further restrains the employer from seeking other agency alternatives
due to the high switching costs involved (Pisano, 1990).
There is an economic benefit to the organization when the use of
hierarchy is selected over the use of the market as a basis for
employer/employee transactions (Jones & Hill, 1988). The use of
hierarchy is highlighted by internalization of the workforce, which
remains the primary work arrangement in business. Internalization is
more efficient than the market because the more exacting the approach
implemented, the more influence each party has over the other's
actions. If an organization depended solely on the market to carry out
its chief objective, each work deliverable produced would be the
consequence of a convoluted bartering and monitoring routine that would
have to be repeated every working day. By internalizing the workforce,
the bartering expense is kept to a single employment search and offer
situation; and, monitoring is made unproblematic by including it as an
element of the employment agreement. Therefore, the costs of
negotiation, monitoring, and exchange are decreased.
The most important advantage that an organizational employment
agreement has over mutually exclusive market negotiations is that the
employee consents to be compensated with fixed wages in exchange for
suborning to the right of superiors to direct and monitor the employees
work efforts, thereby, minimizing the likelihood for incidences of
self-interest agent opportunism. Furthermore, hierarchy creates an
atmosphere of trust much more apparently than a market can between
negotiating parties with their inherent self-interest biases (Ouchi,
1980).
Agency theory makes it clear that transaction costs are, likely,
still apparent even when organizations opt for bureaucracy instead of
the market. The likelihood of agent opportunism continues to be a threat
on any occasion that authority is entrusted to an agent (Shapiro, 2005).
The employment of bureaucratic mechanisms in organizations routinely
results in some control insufficiency of the work systems (Jones &
Hill, 1988). The distribution of authority to subordinates may encourage
them to create agendas that further their own self-interests in
preference to organizational goals and objectives (Leibowitz &
Tollison, 1980). This "moral hazard" inefficiency is
characteristic of contractual business exchanges (Alchain &
Woodward, 1987). The moral hazard in telecommuting refers to
opportunistic shirking, stealing, and other problems that arise when
employee actions cannot be viewed by appropriate supervisory personnel.
The challenge, therefore, becomes to develop a control structure that
provides the organization with the information necessary to discern, and
eliminate, opportunistic activity.
Types of Control
Managerial control within organizations may be defined as the
practice of developing standards, observing and assessing performance,
judging outcomes, acknowledging accomplishments, and taking necessary
action to cure deficiencies in the work performed (Hill & Jones,
1993). Most organizational functions are driven off course because
individuals who are in charge choose not to behave in accordance with
organizational goals and policies (Hofstde, 1978). Agency theory
concedes that employees may maximize personal gain by choosing to
freeload, embezzle, or otherwise avoiding executing occupational
responsibilities (Shapiro, 2005). An indispensable phase in the planning
of effective control systems, then, is to make certain that employee
decisions correspond with organizational objectives. Agency theory
distinguishes two such control methods, behavior control and output
control (Eisenhardt, 1989).
Behavior control means that the employee is compensated with
earnings at a fixed rate for displaying appropriate work behaviors and
that employee work habits during performance can be scrutinized,
generally in person, to insure congruence with organizational standards
and policies (Eisenhardt, 1988). When output control is used, a
worker's pay is dependent on the level of productivity which can be
ascertained without the need for observation of the work being performed
(Eisenhardt, 1989). With output control, reliance on the use of
commissions or piece-rate compensation for performance is customary.
Another type of control, clan control, involves self-regulating groups
of workers who naturally express behaviors that are congruent with the
socialized acceptance of shared organizational customs and values
(Ouchi, 1979). Clan control is applied when behavior and output controls
cannot be established. Behavior and output controls are of interest
here.
In situations involving unfettered behavior control, the worker has
no mandate to deliver specific goods or services. The agreement is that
he or she will simply employ the required work methodology without
deviation (Eisenhardt, 1988). Compensation and incentives are dependent
on the demonstration of mandated behaviors through personal observation
or written reports. Therefore, risk is diminished for the employee in
relation to his or her income by strict adherence to the mandated
behavioral methodology. Alternatively, under complete output control
workers have a responsibility to deliver goods and services that meet
clearly defined standards of acceptance. In cases of failure, the worker
suffers by sacrificing rewards (income). Output control indicates that
the worker accepts any and all of the effects for any inadequacy
connected to the results produced and, therefore, accepts all of the
risk involved (Baiman, 1982; Holstrom, 1979) for mistakes. However, the
employer also suffers damage when the output from the worker is valuable
and necessary to obtain organizational revenues. Consequently, risk
exposure and actual damages are experienced by both sides involved in
the transaction.
The most advantageous selection between the two options depends on
a compromise concerning the cost of evaluating behaviors and the cost of
assessing outputs while passing on the risk of the transaction to the
employee. Under conditions of diminished surveillance, management can
elect to buy information about the employee's behavior; thereby,
utilizing a behavioral control approach by developing a structured
notification apparatus that can closely monitor the employee's
behavior. This notification apparatus might exist in several forms
including the usage of incentive-based whistleblowing schemes,
additional layers of management, supplementary reporting requirements,
and improved fiscal control procedures. Basically, the development of a
more restrictive working environment. These mechanisms may be costly,
but the employees do not suffer the possibility that mandated behaviors
may not yield expected rewards due to causes not within their control.
On the other hand, the organization can choose to employ output
control. Agency theory contends that output controls during periods of
environmental uncertainty are risky for employees because outcomes are
primarily a consequence of their actions and of the prevailing state of
affairs (Baiman, 1982). Therefore, a worker may be penalized for
inadequate outcomes that are the result of, at least partially,
circumstances outside of their control. Due to the perilous nature of
this position, organizations may find that they must compensate workers
at the highest levels since a significant portion of the risk in the
employment arrangement has shifted to the employee. Consequently, it has
been previously demonstrated that it is more cost-effective for firms to
mitigate this risk by compensating workers by means of fixed salaries
than it is to pay high commissions or piece-work rates that recompense
for employee acceptance of the risk described (Basu, Lal, Srinivasan,
& Staelin, 1985).
To sum up, it is deemed better to implement behavioral controls
through a structured notification mechanism when specifics about worker
behavior is deficient and when the transaction cost of assembling these
details is less expensive than discerning the actual utility of outputs
produced.
Trends in Telecommuting
The concept of telecommuting is but one example of what
organizations are doing to fight the high costs associated with doing
business. By definition, telecommuting is the practice of performing
work outside of the traditional workplace while sustaining communication
via computer-based means (Wright, 1993). Specifically, work is carried
out in locations that are isolated from central offices or production
facilities and where employees have no personal contact with co-workers.
Typically, there are three types of work locations where telecommuters
perform their duties: 1) Satellite work centers, 2) Neighborhood work
centers, and 3) Home-based work centers (Olson, 1982). Satellite work
centers house groups of employees from a single business and are located
a distance from the employee's homes and conventional workplace.
Satellite office space is usually selected in an area that is convenient
to the employees and/or prospective customers. Neighborhood work centers
are identical to satellite work centers with the exception that they are
designed to house employees from several businesses at the same time.
The most common form of telecommuting occurs within home-based work
centers. A home-based work center exists whenever an employee routinely
works from their own home. It is estimated that over 20 million workers
in the United States telecommute, with the largest portion of this
workforce choosing to work from their own homes (Kirk & Belovics,
2006).
Telecommuting is a growing phenomenon that is forecasted to become
more of an operational norm in years to come. In the 1990's, an
estimated 42% of companies in the United States used telecommuting to
cut employee commutes, free office space, offer family friendly
flexibility, and to save the company money (Girard, 1997). A more recent
study found that the practice of telecommuting is still growing in that
19% of all federal government employees were engaged in some form of
routine telecommuting to do their jobs (Arnold, 2006).
How effective are these home-office employees? The National Academy
of Science conducted a test in 1985 that showed telecommuting raised
productivity by 15% to 25% (Cote-O'Hara, 1993). Other studies have
been known to show normative productivity gains from 10% to 40% (Nie,
1999). These productivity gains are largely the result of the conversion
of automobile commuting time that is transferred to work time. Other
reasons are that telecommuting employees eliminate typical office
distractions during the workday (such as personal conversations) and
they usually work longer hours than other types of employees (Mello,
2007). Telecommuters generally have more energy than other employees
because they can choose to work during the times of day (or night) when
their energy levels are highest (Cote-O'Hara, 1993). Also,
absenteeism predictably declines because employees can choose to work
part-time on those days that they normally would have missed due to
illness (Cote-O'Hara, 1993).
The promise of telecommuting offers societal benefits that may
ultimately have far greater consequences than increased business
productivity. As the population of telecommuters grows, this should
result in an inverse decrease in the overall number of traditional
automobile commuters. A decrease in the number of conventional commuters
should also result in less pollution, less traffic, fewer accidents, and
decreased travel-related costs for the worker. A more comprehensive
interpretation of telecommuting benefits may envision increased
independence from fossil fuels, fewer health-related costs, a healthier
(greener) environment, and a redistribution of government investment
from infrastructure development and maintenance to helping solve the
more critical societal ills (poverty, hunger, education, etc). In
essence, the societal benefits of telecommuting may contain partial
answers to reinvigorating the economic and competitive strength of the
populous.
This premise of this paper is one that visualizes the future
workplace as one where employers and employees rarely interact
physically. While telecommuting does decrease some bureaucratic costs,
such as extensive fixed asset investment in real estate, the question of
what type of managerial control should be employed, and under what
circumstances, with these satellite employees is an issue that must be
resolved.
The Governance Structure of Telecommuting Organizations
Transaction cost theory tells us that the costs of economic
activities are not technologically determined but are dependent on the
form of organization under which the activities are conducted (Yarbrough
& Yarbrough, 1988). Therefore, if an organization wants to structure
itself so that it can implement a behavioral control information system,
it should and it will. In this case, management may surmise that the
increased expense of tight behavioral monitoring is worth it to ensure
that the required work methodology is being executed without deviation.
Likewise, if management wants to concede observability as a lost cause,
an output control system will likely be maintained. It is rational to
assume, however, that, in these cases, the nature of products or
services produced under an output control environment will be such that
delayed acceptance until reasonable quality can be achieved will not
place the firm in a position of undue stress. Therefore, it is of no
consequence that telecommuters may utilize higher levels of technology
to remain in the privacy of their own homes, or work in satellite
locations away from the corporate center, because transaction cost
theory claims that the resource requirement to implement this strategy
is only a secondary consideration. More importantly, organizations will
employ a telecommuting strategy because the internal structure of the
firm will naturally evolve to select a strategy and governance structure
that minimizes total bureaucratic costs (Coase, 1937). So, the question
naturally becomes, how can managers implement a behavioral control
system with a workforce that is located in physically remote locations;
and, when is the total economic cost of obtaining behavioral information
in the circumstance of telecommuting less costly than exposing the firm
to the inherent risks involved in the utilization of output monitoring?
Behavioral Controls and Telecommuting
There are six primary methods that managers commonly utilize to
control the behavior of telecommuters (Fairweather, 1999; Festead,
Jewson, & Walters, 2003). They are summarized as followed:
1. Use of Technological Monitoring Devices--Computer Based
Performance Monitoring (CBPM) systems are software programs that collect
and transmit a wide variety of data about the productivity and work
patterns of employees from their computer (Fairweather, 1999). CBPM
allows managers to easily, and constantly, access and monitor data
collected on all of the employees networked into the system. Typical
uses include monitoring the number of data entry keystrokes per hour for
each employee, the length of telephone calls and time between calls, the
time an individual spends away from his or her desk, the time to process
claims, and to record total work hours logged per day, among other
things.
2. Monitoring of Telephone Communications--The recording and/or
monitoring of telephone communications has been an accepted practice for
many years in a wide variety of industries. Reasons that telephone
conversations may be monitored include quality control, curtailment of
personal use, and organizational privacy concerns (Fairweather, 1999) .
3. Electronic Mail Monitoring/Archiving--Firms routinely monitor
and archive electronic mail transmissions to deter employee abuse of
organizational time and resources by conversing with friends and
relatives. For business related use, other reasons may include
monitoring for illegal or fraudulent purposes, divulging trade secrets,
and inappropriate relations with organizational stakeholders
(Fairweather, 1999).
4. Use of Video and Audio Recording Devices--A typical use of video
and audio recording devices in telecommuting is to help combat feelings
of isolation formed in telecommuting employees by allowing them to
correspond with the main office by means of teleconferencing
(Fairweather, 1999). The two-way visual and audio interaction of
teleconferencing, if performed on a routine basis, allows the
telecommuter to retain visibility, develop personal relationships with
their peers, and preserve the perception that they are a part of the
team. Alternatively, cameras and microphones may also be installed
around the entire work area of the employee and used as a means for
comprehensive behavioral surveillance. In this fashion, managers may
monitor and record every movement and utterance of employees while they
go about the performance of their organizational responsibilities. In
essence, these devices may allow the manager the highest level of
intimate knowledge about the working behavior of employees because the
monitoring may be done at any, or all, times work is supposed to be
performed and without detection.
5. Home / Satellite Office Visits--Managers use announced, and
unexpected, visits to telecommuter work locations for a variety of
legitimate business reasons which includes health and safety
assessments, performance appraisals, coaching, training, sickness
monitoring, feedback, etc. However, personal visits also give managers
the opportunity to inspect the demeanor, attitude, and condition of the
worker. Many workers (and their families) find unannounced personal
visits to be somewhat intrusive but some managers find it imperative to
observe employees up close (Festead, Jewson, & Walters, 2003).
6. Trust--Trust exists when telecommuting workers are recognized by
management for possessing the capabilities of individual
self-discipline, self-motivation, and self-management. It entails a
relationship, between selected workers and management, of shared ethical
and business commitment in which rewards, productivity, and respect are
exchanged without investigation. In practice, trust functions as a form
of control and not an alternative to it. When organizations emphasize
trust as a component for eligibility to be allowed to telecommute, the
employees will be selected because, based on historical performance with
different levels of responsibility, management has discerned that there
is no need for high levels of observational scrutiny. Generally, higher
grade workers who have clear records of proven reliability identify the
archetype of a telecommuter selected on the basis of trust (Festead,
Jewson, & Walters, 2003).
Each of the aforementioned behavioral monitoring strategies
increases the short-term organizational costs of business transactions
in terms of resource acquisition (purchase and installation of
monitoring devices), labor expense (personnel cost to monitor
telecommuters), travel expense (related to site visits), and opportunity
costs (when trust is unfounded and the business is exposed to the cost
of risk). However, under transaction cost rationale, these costs are
justified because they serve to lessen transaction complications and,
thereby, decrease the long-term costs of regular exchanges (Hill &
Jones, 1993). For example, portable teleconferencing systems (e.g.,
laptop enabled with web-cam, microphone, and a portable
bluetooth-enabled phone) can be taken to meetings, seminars, and other
corporate functions and allow managers to listen in and interact with
the telecommuting employee in the field so that they can know exactly
what occurred and correct any mistakes in real time (decreases
uncertainty and information impactedness). Organizations may also choose
to conduct comprehensive surveillance with installed video and audio
devices in employee work areas in order to make continuous appraisals of
employee performance (decreases uncertainty and opportunism).
Additionally, there is time-tracking software that can let managers know
how much time an employee has put into certain projects (CBPM) and
electronic bracelets that can pinpoint the exact location of an employee
out of the office (decreases uncertainty and opportunism). When compared
to the cost of maintaining office buildings (decreases asset
specificity) and hiring managers to supervise employees on location
(decreases opportunism), these behavioral monitoring devices are
cost-efficient and readily available.
How do managers feel about telecommuting? Many managers oppose the
arrangement, dreading the supposed loss of control over, and access to,
employees and perceived reduction in their own value to the company
(bounded-rationality). In most organizations, telecommuting requires a
fairly major change in culture (Cote-O'Hara, 1993).
Output Controls and Telecommuting
Organizations employ output controls to monitor their telecommuting
employees mainly because, considering the costs of behavioral monitoring
strategies, they are deemed as unobservable (Kurland & Cooper,
2002). In other words, the assumption is that the cost of behavioral
monitoring is prohibitive to these firms so observation of the
telecommuter is not a viable option for them. For these businesses, the
organizational culture has evolved from managing by activity (direct
observation of the work in progress) to managing solely by production
results. Agency theory argues, however, that output monitoring is more
costly than effecting behavioral controls (Basu, Lal, Srinivasan, &
Staelin, 1985) since workers must be compensated to take on the risk of
possibly producing low utility output. Therefore, the employer must
regularly pay a premium for the employee's services. When the
employee delivers unacceptable output results on a project that the
employer needs to secure income, the employer bears the penalty of
missed economic gain. This is the cost (risk) of outcome uncertainty
that is of interest here. However, in cases of standardized and routine
output risk is negligible because output usefulness is guaranteed.
Transaction costs decrease as employee and employer risks decrease.
Thus, under the transaction cost theory, output control may not be
advantageous under all situations.
Characteristics of Bureaucratic Transactions
In order for the employer-employee bureaucratic agreement to take
place, both parties must benefit from it. Reducing the bureaucratic
costs increases the mutual rewards each party may gain from the
transaction. Therefore, the purpose of investigating the
employer-employee interaction from agency and transaction cost
standpoints is to discern those dimensions of the exchange that may lead
to risk and increased costs. Two transaction characteristics,
transaction uncertainty, from the transaction cost perspective (Ouchi,
1980), and outcome uncertainty, from agency theory (Holstrom, 1979),
account for the amount of negotiating, monitoring, enforcement and
risk-related costs built-in between employers and, in this case,
telecommuting employees. Both of these characteristics have an effect on
the scale of information that must be managed to conclude such
transactions. For this paper, transaction uncertainty represents those
elements leading to costs for the organization to monitor the behavior
of telecommuters, while, outcome uncertainty represents those costs for
the organization related to the nature of employee work (standard or
non-routine) and the inherent risks related to producing this work.
An Organizational Control Framework for the Management of
Telecommuters
The determinants for organizational control of telecommuting
employees are described by varying levels of transaction and outcome
uncertainty while considering the utility of the work performed for the
employer.
Transaction Uncertainty and Telecommuters
Transaction uncertainty may be interpreted as the degree of
familiarity that the employer has with an employee's work habits,
reliability, and performance (Jones, 1987) and exists to the degree that
telecommuting employees are not physically observable. However, the
organization must have some evidence that employees are performing those
duties which they were hired to perform. If not, workers will remain
free from scrutiny and agent opportunism tendencies may surface. To
alleviate this risk, the organization should take steps to avoid it
Principally, the organization must make an effort to dissuade
telecommuting employees from, among other things, farming out sensitive
work, shirking during the workday, and misrepresenting the company to
clientele. As the tendency for unsupervised agents is to behave
opportunistically (stealing, cheating, selling sensitive information,
etc.), organizations must guard themselves against possible security
breaches (Shapiro, 2005). Therefore, behavioral monitoring is indicated.
This rationale implies, however, that the work output from telecommuters
has a fairly high utility value for the employer. In cases where the
utility value is not significant, output controls may be established
because the risk assumed by the employee is minimal. As risk for the
employee decreases, organizational costs for those risks assumed
decreases making output control less expensive than behavioral
monitoring.
In addition, the level of transaction uncertainty is a function of
infrequency. The more repeated the exchange between an employee and an
organization, the lower the uncertainty and cost of transactions (Jones,
1987). Initial transaction uncertainty will decrease with extensive
behavioral monitoring. Over a period of time, however, extensive
monitoring will not be necessary. This is because when exchange is
frequent, the parties to transactions become used to dealing with each
other and rely more on past experience (Williamson, 1975).
In summary, transaction uncertainty will decrease with behavioral
monitoring and is cost efficient under conditions of high work utility
and/or high employee assumed risk. The level of behavioral monitoring,
however, will decrease with an increase in transaction frequency over
time, due to a familiarity of the transacting parties.
Outcome Uncertainty and Telecommuters
Outcome uncertainty refers to the nature of the work performed
(standard or non-routine) which affects the amount of risk assumed, by
the telecommuting employee, for producing low-utility output
(Eisenhardt, 1989). Increased employee risks are positively related to
increased bureaucratic costs (Jones, 1987). Outcome uncertainty is
heightened by non-standard outputs because they are unique and
dissimilar. Examples of non-standard outputs are business plans,
consulting services, medical advice, and contract proposals. There is
variation in the accomplishment of the work, as well as its usefulness
to the employer. If the telecommuter, acting as an agent for the
employer, incompetently negotiates a project price for work that will
result in a loss for the employer, then it is the employer who will lose
profits on the deal because of being legally bound to deliver as per the
contract agreement. Behavioral monitoring will reduce this risk of
potential lost income. Alternatively, if the type of output expected is
of low utility and standardized, one should use pure output monitoring
(without paying a premium) because the risks are low for the employer
and employee. Therefore, output monitoring may be a less expensive
option.
A related workforce drawback forwarded by managers is the impact of
telecommuting on both formal and informal communications (Gibson,
Blackwell, Dominicis, & Demerath, 2002). The significance of such
dialogue to the successful conclusion of assignments is critical. The
lack of recurrent advice and criticism (formal and informal) from
supervisors and colleagues can cause confusion, needless errors, and
duplication of work (Ford, 1991). This lack of communication increases
outcome uncertainty because high utility outputs cannot be guaranteed
without strict direction. Behavioral monitoring may decrease this
uncertainty by increasing communication.
In summary, outcome uncertainty is increased for work that is
non-standard in nature due to the risks that the employer might suffer
for high utility work not being produced adequately.
PROPOSITION CONSTRUCTION
Based on the review of literature previously, a framework of
governance possibilities for daily telecommuters may be constructed by
integrating the employer-employee relationship variables transaction
uncertainty, outcome uncertainty, and work utility (See Figure 1). In
review, transaction uncertainty is defined as the level and degree of
familiarity that employers have in their employees (Williamson, 1975;
Jones, 1987). Outcome uncertainty concerns the risk that employees and
employers suffer in case the outputs delivered are unacceptable. This
risk is tied into the nature of the work performed--there is more
outcome uncertainty for non-routine (or customized) outputs than for
simple, routine, or standardized outputs (Eisenhardt, 1989). Finally,
work utility is a function of the importance of the outputs produced to
the organization (Eisenhardt, 1989). It may be surmised that it is
rational for organizations to ensure the quality of high utility outputs
by taking precautions. In essence, more control may be necessary when
the firm depends on the delivery of high utility outputs.
In CELL ONE, transaction uncertainty, outcome uncertainty, and work
utility all assume low levels. Therefore, there is familiarity with the
employee and his or her general work habits, the nature of the output
expected is routine, and the importance of the product or service is
low. Under these conditions, the firm should not invest in technology to
monitor the telecommuter because, since there are no risks assumed by
the employer or employee, costs will remain low. The firm should,
therefore, institute an output control system and compensate the
employee at standard rates for the work performed.
In CELL TWO, transaction uncertainty and work utility remain at low
levels but outcome uncertainty is high. Specifically, the employer is
familiar with the employee's general work habits but the outputs
required are non-routine (specialized). Under these circumstances, the
firm should implement behavioral control utilizing technology as an
alternative to implementing output control and compensating the employee
for the risks assumed due to the probability of producing unacceptable
work. In other words, it will be less expensive over the long-term for
the employer to interact with the employee and provide direction than it
will be to continually pay a premium for work under an output control
setting.
In CELL THREE, transaction and outcome uncertainty is low but work
utility is high. The employer is familiar with the telecommuting
employee and his or her work habits; and, the nature of the work
produced is routine. However, work utility is high meaning that the work
is important for future company income. Therefore, the choice between
control mechanisms rests on the trust that the employer has in the
employee. The firm should institute behavioral monitoring using
technology if there is any question about employee competence, honesty,
or timeliness. However, if agent opportunism is not an issue (based on
the historical reliability of the worker) an output control mechanism
(no premium) will be less expensive.
In CELL FOUR, transaction uncertainty is low but outcome
uncertainty and work utility is high. In other words, the worker's
habits are well known but the product or service is valuable to the firm
and it is of a customized nature. This condition will require the use of
behavioral monitoring so that the firm can be assured that the work is
being performed correctly and that it will be done on time.
In CELL FIVE, transaction uncertainty is high, outcome uncertainty
is low, and work utility is low. This cell describes a situation where
the employer is not familiar with the employee's work habits or
abilities; but, the output expected is routine and of little importance.
This condition requires the implementation of an output control strategy
because, since the output is routine, there are no assumed risks for
which the employer has to pay a premium. In the case of employee
failure, it is more cost effective, under these circumstances, to cancel
the employer-employee agreement and to hire someone else rather than
invest in technology that would allow the employer to interact with the
telecommuter.
In CELL SIX, the employer is unfamiliar with the employee's
work habits and abilities, the work performed is of little importance,
and the work is non-standard. Since it has been demonstrated that
behavioral monitoring may be less expensive than paying output control
premiums for employee assumed risk (Basu, Lal, Srinivasan, &
Staelin, 1985), behavioral monitoring using technology is indicated.
However, if the cost of behavioral monitoring is more than the cumulated
cost of paying higher premiums, output controls will be established.
In CELLS SEVEN AND EIGHT, behavioral monitoring will be implemented
because of the importance of the work and the unfamiliarity of the
employer with the employee. Outcome uncertainty is not relevant, in
these cases, because there is no reason to trust an unfamiliar remote
employee to work on vitally important projects without some direction
from management, regardless of the nature of the work (standard or
non-routine). In this state of affairs, the risk of forgone income to
the employer is best mediated by behavioral monitoring.
Propositions
From the framework above, the following propositions are theorized:
Proposition 1: Low transaction and outcome uncertainty is
positively related to output control of telecommuting employees for low
utility work.
Proposition 2: Low transaction uncertainty and high outcome
uncertainty is positively related to behavioral control of telecommuting
employees regardless of the utility of the work.
Proposition 3: Low transaction and outcome uncertainty is
positively related to behavioral control of telecommuting employees in
cases of high work utility and a lack of trust for the employees.
Proposition 4: Low transaction and outcome uncertainty is
positively related to output control of telecommuting employees in cases
of high work utility and high trust for the employees.
Proposition 5: High transaction uncertainty and low outcome
uncertainty is positively related to output control of telecommuting
employees in cases of low work utility.
Proposition 6: High transaction and outcome uncertainty is
positively related to behavioral control of telecommuting employees in
cases of low work utility if the cost of monitoring technology is less
than the cumulated payment of output control premiums.
Proposition 7: High transaction uncertainty and high work utility
is positively related to behavioral control of telecommuting employees
regardless of outcome uncertainty.
DISCUSSION & CONCLUSION
This paper contributes to organizational theory and management
practice by integrating transaction cost and agency theories to attempt
to forecast the impact of telecommuting on the governance practices and
structure of organizations. The impending role of the satellite
workforce is one that is changing as technology further evolves.
Behavioral control has been identified as the most efficient method to
insure the quality of outputs and monitor employees. It is currently
possible to maintain control of telecommuters by using readily available
technological devices. However, the cost of these behavioral controls
can be prohibitive, depending on several work characteristics, and in
those instances output controls may be most appropriate.
While the list of new technology that makes it possible to observe
the behavior of employees and interact with them is expanding, the fear
that these devices will be used to abuse the workforce is rising also
(Fairweather, 1999). There is a possibility that
"micro-managers" will attempt to implement overly intrusive
management systems creating, in effect, a 24 hour "electronic
bureaucracy" from which there is no escape. It is possible.
Although the scope of this paper was limited to a partial analysis
of hierarchical governance choices for a telecommuting workforce, the
investigation did not take into consideration other determinants of
control such as professionalism, task specificity, task interdependence,
incentive programs, organizational culture, specific industry
application, etc. The areas for future research and speculation are
broad and the implications are numerous.
In summary, based on environmental and business trends, a
significant and growing percentage of the future workforce might be one
where telecommuters work from their homes, or other satellite offices,
and are controlled by organizations, through technology, employing
behavioral or output controls. This paper is an attempt to discern under
what conditions organizations may favor one control strategy over
another.
REFERENCES
Alchian, A., & Woodward, S. (1987). Reflections on the theory
of a firm. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 143(1):
110-136.
Arnold, J.T., (2006). Making the leap. HR Magazine, 51(5): 80-86.
Arrow, K. J. (1974). The limits of organization. New York: Norton.
Bailey, D., and Kurland, N. (2002). A review of telework research:
findings, new directions, and lessons for the study of modern work.
Journal of Organizational Behavior, 23(1): 383-400.
Baiman, S. (1982), Agency research in managerial accounting: A
survey. Journal of Accounting Literature, 1(1): 124-53.
Basu, A., Lal, R., Srinivasan, V., & Staelin, R. (1985). Sales
force compensation plans: An agency theoretic perspective. Marketing
Science, 4(1): 267-291.
Coase, R. The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(1): 386-405.
Commons, J.R. (1950) The economics of collective action. Madison,
WI: University of Wisconsin Press.
Cote-O Hara, J. (1993). Sending them home to work: Telecommuting.
Business Quarterly, 57(3): 104-109.
Eisenhardt, K. (1988). Agency and institutional theory
explanations: The case of retail sales compensation. Academy of
Management Journal, 31(1): 488-511.
Eisenhardt, K. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review.
Academy of Management Review, 14(1): 57-74.
Fairweather, N.B., (1999). Surveillance in employment: The case of
teleworking. Journal of Business Ethics, 22(1): 3949.
Felstead, A., Jewson, N., & Walters, S., (2003). Managerial
control of employees working at home. British Journal of Industrial
Relations, 41(2): 241-264.
Ford, R. C., (1991). Is your organization ready for telecommuting.
SAM Advanced Management Journal, 56(4): 19-23.
Gibson, J.W., Blackwell, C.W., Dominicis, P., & Demerath, N.,
(2002). Telecommuting in the 21st century: Benefits, issues, and a
leadership model which will work. The Journal of Leadership Studies,
8(4): 75-86.
Girard, K., (1997). Ditching the commute. Computerworld, 31(35):
1-3.
Hill, C., & Jones, G. (1993). Strategic management (2nd ed.).
Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.
Hofstede, G. (1978). The poverty of management control philosophy.
Academy of Management Review, 2(1): 450-461.
Holmstrom, B. (1979). Moral hazard and observability. Bell Journal
of Economics, 10(1): 74-91.
Jones, G.R. Organization -client transactions and organizational
governance structures. Academy of Management Journal. 30(2): 197-218.
Jones, G.R. and Hill, C., (1988). Transaction cost analysis of
strategy-structure choice. Strategic Management Journal. 9(2): 159-172.
Kirk, J., & Belovics, R. (2006). Making e-working work. Journal
of Employment Counseling, 43(1): 39-46.
Klein, B., Crawford, R., and Alchain, A., (1978). Vertical
integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting
process. Journal of Law and Economics. 21(1): 297-326.
Kren, L., & Kerr, J. (1993). The effect of behavior monitoring
and uncertainty on the use of performance contingent compensation.
Accounting & Business Research, 23(1): 159-168.
Kurland, N., Cooper, C. D., (2002). Manager control and employee
isolation in telecommuting environments. Journal of High Technology
Management Research, 13(1): 107-126.
Leibowitz, A. and Tollison, R., (1980). Free riding, shirking, and
team production in legal partnerships. Economic Inquiry, 18(1): 380-394.
Mello, J.A., (2007). Managing telework programs effectively.
Employee Responsibilities & Rights Journal, 19(4): 247261.
Nie, N., (1990). Tracking our techno-future. American Demographics,
21(7): 50-53.
Olson, M. (1982). New information technology and organizational
culture. Management Information Systems Quarterly, 6(4): 71-92.
Ouchi, W.Z., (1979). A conceptual framework for the design of
organizational control mechanisms. Management Science, 25(4): 833-47.
Ouchi, W.Z., (1980). Markets, bureaucracies and clans.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 25 (1): 129-41.
Pisano, G. (1990). The R&D boundaries of the firm: An empirical
analysis. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1): 153-176.
Shapiro, S. P., (2005). Agency theory. Annual Review of Sociology,
31(1): 263-284.
Siha, S., and Monroe, R., (2006). Telecommuting's past and
future: a literature review and research agenda. Business Process
Management Journal, 12(4): 455-482.
Williamson, O. (1975). Markets and hierarchies. New York: Free
Press.
Wright, P.C. (1993). Telecommuting and employee effectiveness:
Career and managerial Issues. International Journal of Career
Management, 5(1): 4-9.
Yarbrough, B.V. and Yarbrough, R.M., (1988). The transactional
structure of the firm: A comparative survey. Journal of Economic
Behavior & Organization, 10(1): 1-28.
Jeff Brice, Jr., Texas Southern University
Millicent Nelson, Middle Tennessee State University
Norris White Gunby, Jr., Elon University
Figure 1: Framework for Organizational Control of Telecommuting
Employees
Work Utility
Low High Low High
Outcome Output Output or Output Behavioral
Uncertainty Behavioral
(Low) Cell 1 Cell3 Cell 5 Cell 7
Outcome Behavioral Behavioral Output or Behavioral
Uncertainty Behavioral
(High) Cell 2 Cell 4 Cell 6 Cell 8
Transaction Uncertainty Transaction Uncertainty
(Low) (High)