Re-examining imbeddedness: a critical analysis of global strategic management.
Mir, Raza ; Mir, Ali ; Hussain, Mehdi 等
ABSTRACT
Studies of the international tendencies in organizational
activities have led to the emergence of the sub-field of global
strategic management. Theorists of global strategy have suggested that
imbeddedness, both at the level of geography and culture, is an
impediment to growth, and advocate an approach that is free of such
constraints in the quest for above average profits.
In this paper, we suggest that global strategic theorists have
viewed the process of internationalization from a narrow and
western-oriented perspective. Drawing upon the more diverse views of
internationalization from economics and political science, we identify
the critical views of internationalization which do not find mention in
this research. We critique existing frameworks of global strategy, and
offer an alternate research agenda for international organizations as
well as theorists, as an imperative against intellectual marginalization and as a possibility for a more inclusive approach to non-western
subjects in the field of international business.
INTRODUCTION
In this paper, we attempt a critical examination of the assumptions
that appear to have informed the literature on international
corporatization in the field of Strategic Management, and therefore
question the theory building processes that have arisen from the
scholarship. In doing so, we seek to identify a few key research
questions and directions which might invest the field with a greater
degree of legitimacy, and address the various criticisms that have been
leveled against it from diverse ideological positions.
In the past few years, the literature in Strategic Management has
been increasingly captivated by the ideas of the globalization of
management strategy (van Gelder, 2004; Harris 2002; Nohria &
Ghoshal, 1994). While the issue of the internationalization of capital
has had a long history in the field of business strategy, going right
back to the works of Chandler (1962) and Perlmutter (1969), the current
resurgence in the field may be interpreted as an attempt by the academy
to respond to the issues that have arisen following the exponential
increase in the globalization of world economic activity (Dicken, 2003),
in terms of global shifts in manufacturing and production operations
internationalization of investment, and widening circuits of capital.
We review the literature in the field of Global Strategic
Management (GSM), in an attempt to locate the various ideological
assumptions that drive the field. Following from the economic
assumptions that are articulated within the mainstream scholarship in
GSM, we examine the influential microeconomic theories of the
Multinational Enterprise (MNE) that inform the mainstreams of GSM, in
particular the internalization theory (Hymer, 1976) and transaction cost
theory (Williamson, 1985). We also discuss the critical treatment of the
internalization theory as it unfolds in various other social sciences,
mainly economics and political science, offering a thesis that while the
mainstream views of internationalization accentuate the non-antagonistic
differences between the corporation and the state, they actually
understate how collusive arrangements between the transnational elites
actually create conditions for ensuring the successful performance and
economic domination of MNEs. In juxtaposing these points of view, we
attempt to contextualize the unqualified acceptance of the superior
performance (and beneficial impact) of MNEs by the field of GSM and
suggest that alternate research agendas in the field need to achieve a
more balanced understanding of the theme of globalization. We end with a
suggestion that theories of GSM need to exhibit greater sensitivity to
power imbalances, issues of national priorities and geo-political
egalitarianism, and the larger socio-cultural impacts of globalization
rather than operate in a purely economistic and unidirectional
perspective.
GLOBAL STRATEGIC MANAGEMENT--AN APPRAISAL OF THE LITERATURE
At face value, the literature in the field of Strategic Management
that deals with globalization appears to be marked by a great deal of
diversity. For instance, Melin's (1992) review of three volumes of
the Journal of International Business Studies found them representing
seven different areas of internationalization, namely finance and
banking, cross cultural aspects, international joint ventures, human
resources, foreign direct investments, coordination/control and host
government relationships. Such a broad spectrum of interest areas have
led to a variety of research interests, which appear to pull the field
in different directions.
While there have been many attempts at developing typologies of
research themes in the field, two influential organizational frameworks
for research in the field of Global Strategic Management (GSM) are
noteworthy.
Ghoshal (1987) sees global strategies as being mediated by two key
variables, strategic objectives and sources of competitive advantage. In
an attempt to recast the "totality of a multidimensional and
complex phenomenon" (p 438) into a two dimensional framework,
Ghoshal identifies three strategic objectives, namely efficiency, risk
management and innovation; and three sources of competitive advantage,
namely national differences, economies of scale and economies of scope.
From the network of this 3x3 matrix, Ghoshal identifies 9 strategies of
globalization, designed to "help managers and academics in
formulating various issues that arise in Global Strategic
Management" (p 433).
It is interesting to note that of the six aforementioned factors
that Ghoshal uses to form the perimeter of his taxonomy, only
'national differences' may be identified as being a
non-economistic variable. However, upon closer examination, it is
evident that Ghoshal's treatment of national differences also
arises from economistic aspects such as "wage rates, interest rates
of currency exchange rates" and second order effects like
"economically inefficient environments," or
"inter-organizational linkages, the educational system and
managerial know-how" (p 433). Moreover, the only variable in this
classification that may have been seen to have non-economistic
connotations, the educational system, is sandwiched between two economic
variables, almost as a guard against any ambivalence.
While Ghoshal's organizing framework can be critiqued as being
too constricting and reductionist, the framework proposed by Melin
(1992), is far more flexible. After an extensive review of the
literature, Melin identifies three broad themes of internationalization
in the mainstream literature. The first theme attempts to cast
internationalization as a stage in the development of a corporation. It
is here that we may place the influential 'eclectic theory' of
Dunning (1980, 1988), which sees foreign involvement as a function of
locational, integrational and ownership-specific advantages of the
internationalizing firms. The second theme attempts to study the
sequential and causal link between strategy and structure. A bulk of the
empirical research in internationalization has centered around this
theme (Martinez & Jarillo, 1989). Much of this research is concerned
with identifying the direction of the causal arrow in the
strategy-structure linkages. Chandler's (1962) famous assertion
that structure follows strategy has been continually supported and
refuted by a number of studies in the international context (Peters,
1984; Melin, 1989). The third theme that seems to have dominated the
internationalization debates has been termed the "Process
School" (Prahalad, 1990). Concentrating their research in the
direction of the Diversified Multinational Corporation (DMNC), the
researchers affiliated to the Process School eschew the
"architectural" approach of to the MNE literature in favor of
examining the constant balancing that MNEs have to perform between the
'economic imperative' of profit maximization, which suggests
centralized controls, and the 'political imperative' of having
to adjust to local demands, which necessitates the relinquishing of
authority in favor of a decentralized autonomy (see Doz & Prahalad,
1991, for a conceptual framework).
In addition to Ghoshal's and Melin's articulation of the
various directions from which this issue is being addressed, one could
add the case of "the battle of the consultants." Emerging from
the works of two of the most influential consultants in the field,
Kenichi Ohmae and Michael Porter, the debate has tended to end in
stalemate as both parties offer empirical evidence for apparently
contrasting analyses of the internationalization debate.
Discussing the issue of power relations in an "interlinked
economy," Ohmae (1990) concludes that the current economic bonds
between the industrially developed nations constitute linkages which
have been rendered "organic," and advises the developing (sic)
economies to respond to inducements to participate in a "borderless
world," where the free flow of individuals, capital and activities,
and the "weave of economic interdependence of nations" would
ensure the security and prosperity of all humankind. The rhetoric
conceals a prescription for the development of "global strategic
alliances" that would supersede and render obsolete the borders of
the nation state.
Porter (1990) on the other hand, is more circumspect. In an
inductive analysis of his experiences as an international consultant,
Porter develops a theory which suggests that nations with particular
combinations of circumstances have the potential to offer enormous
strengths to the forms of particular industries operating there. In his
view:
Competitive advantage is created and sustained through a highly
localized process. Differences in national economic structures,
values, cultures, institutions and histories contribute profoundly
to competitive success. The role of the home nation seems to be as
strong as or stronger than ever. While globalization of competition
may appear to make the nation less important, instead it seems to
make it more so. With fewer impediments to trade to shelter
uncompetitive domestic firms and industries, the home nation takes
on growing significance because it is the source of the skills and
the technology that underpin competitive advantage. (Porter, 1990,
p 19).
As we can see, the literature in GSM appears at face value to
approach the issue from a multiplicity of perspectives, is characterized
by debates and dissensions, and is driven by multiple research agendas.
However, an attempt to recast the spectrum of research viewpoints into
their basic ontological, epistemological, methodological and
sociological assumptions (Burrell & Morgan, 1979) reveals a
surprisingly high level of paradigmatic consensus.
In ontological terms, we see that the organization has constantly
been reified as an entity being conceptualized by default in the
personality of its Top Management Team. The epistemological positivism is constantly reiterated in the compulsion to cast the processes,
strategies and themes of international research into framing rules,
typologies and networks. While the process school has often condemned
"static and purely economic views" (Ghoshal, 1987) of the
internationalization process, it offers a surprisingly economistic view
of the human element in the discussion of the issues of human
involvement. The literature often equates human involvement with little
beyond issues of technological competence, wage rates and the assumption
of labor as being yet another factor of production. It is equally
interesting to note that none of the empirical studies identified by
Martinez and Jarillo (1989) or Melin (1992) contained any ethnographic
or interactional study, or any design aimed at addressing the processual
aspects of strategy. All studies revolved around quantitative,
measurement oriented designs, quite a few of which (e.g. Hall &
Salas, 1980; Peters, 1984; Melin, 1989; Stopford & Wells, 1972;
Franko, 1976) were engaged in determining issues of causality.
One exception to the methodological rule however, has been
Hamel's (1991) study of international strategic alliances, which
sought to study how various national organizations used the strategic
alliances they entered into as a basis for further learning and adding
to their portfolio of core competencies. However, Hamel's study
dealt exclusively with corporations where power imbalances were not a
major factor, and where theory building issues were more in the area of
the resource based view of firms rather than a study of the conditions
of internationalization in the sense of the classic MNE. Hamel's
study, while still in the same paradigmatic position as mainstream GSM,
does offer interesting methodological possibilities for future research
in the field.
While paradigmatic convergence of GSM theories is indeed striking,
it is in the examination of the sociological assumptions that
characterize the literature that one finds the greatest degree of
consensus. The entire corpus of literature surveyed on the issue of
internationalization was surprisingly devoid of any discussion on:
1. The nature of action choice that may be available to the
'subsidiary nation' in the multinational alliance;
2. The effect of the MNE on local/indigenous forms of industry in
the subsidiary nation;
3. The issue of hazards, environmental and ecological concerns that
accompany the setting up of an MNE;
4. The political impact of MNEs on the domestic economic policies
of nations.
This is not to suggest that there has been no criticism of MNEs in
the field or in other related social sciences. Indeed, the critique has
been quite severe in a number of ways. What is observable however, is
that none of this critique has been incorporated, or even addressed in
the theory building processes in the field. Such a process has been
accomplished by provincializing the discussion into a separate area of
analysis, from where it exerts only a marginal influence on the
mainstream.
It is indeed interesting to note that much of the critique leveled
against the principles and policies of international management in
general, and MNEs in particular, has suffered either of two
consequences. Either it has been consigned to extreme (and often
uninfluential) journals that sacrifice verifiability and rigor at the
altar of trenchant critique, or it has been socialized into a
cooperative and subservient discourse exemplified by a majority of the
literature in the discipline of Business Ethics, which is replete with
articles that, while apparently dealing with terms like
"multinational corporate social responsibility" (Amba Rao,
1993) and "multinational ethical responsibility" (Pratt,
1991), continue to offer blanket praise to MNEs for their
"beneficial effects, particularly in improved standard of
living" (Amba Rao, 1993) and restrict their injunctions against
MNEs to prescriptions about how they should improve their corporate
communication to communicate their productive role in a better manner
(Pratt, 1991). Some even go to the extent of absolving the MNE of any
ethical responsibility on the grounds that they have "fiduciary
responsibilities that must override personal moral suasion"
(Dobson, 1992). The whole aspect of "ethics" in such a
localized and non-interactive relationship with other facets of the
discipline is often seen as being cast in a mode of Kantian
de-ontological imperatives, emphasizing individual actions that satisfy
individual goals. Such ethics may often be at odds with non-Western
value systems which emphasize ethnic group over self, a factor that
needs to be taken into account when dealing with the issue of
international management. Thus, the issues of ethics by the MNE as
raised by forums such as those in the segregated discipline of Business
Ethics are a matter of some concern, as by the nature of their
provincialization and bounded-ness, they often end up serving the very
interests that they set out to question.
In sum, the theories of GSM as represented in the mainstreams of
the scholarship in Strategic Management, while portraying multiplicity
and diversity of interests and agendas, may be seen as being driven by a
tight set of basic assumptions that speak more of a consensus of a
paradigmatic location in a "functionalist" camp (Burrell &
Morgan, 1976).
LESSONS FROM OTHER SOCIAL SCIENCES
Irrespective of the nature of one's ideological affiliations,
it would be difficult to deny the reality that economic and political
structures have begun to be increasingly linked on an international
basis. As the capitalist economy continues to be further globalized, the
debate is not on the extent of internationalization, but on the way it
needs to be analyzed. While the mainstream social scientists believe
that the internationalization of capital has rendered the nation state
and economic class obsolete as units of analysis (Williamson, 1985),
scholars with critical affiliations are circumspect that these
distinctions have disappeared altogether (Ruccio, Resnick & Wolf,
1991).
While the issue of the transnational enterprise (and its
relationship with the nation state) has not been subjected to any major
dissenting views in the field of management, it has been the subject of
many contentious debates in some of the other social sciences,
especially the fields of economics and political science. In this
section, we briefly attempt to examine some aspects of the debates in
this field, in an attempt to use the experiences to inform mainstream
management theory.
The mainstream approach to the MNE can best be exemplified by the
transaction cost approach. Derived from the classical microeconomic
theoretical approach of using the market as the starting point of
analysis, the transaction cost approach attempts to explain both the
firm and the state as a safeguard against 'market failures'
such as monopolistic and oligopolistic markets which may deter the
optimal allocation of resources. The market, on its own, would not be
able to sustain optimum allocation except through paying a high price in
terms of transaction costs. The state then is conceptualized as an
institutional device with a monopoly over coercion and a task of
ensuring a market that does not degenerate into a situation of failure.
The firm on the other hand, resorts to a variety of activities such as
vertical and horizontal integration and contracts mediated by the state
to replicate the perfect market conditions (Hennart, 1991).
In the application of this theory to the multinational corporation,
the arguments of Buckley and Casson (1976) and of Williamson (1975;
1981; 1985) may be seen as an influential continuum. These theorists
develop their argument from the contention that intangible assets such
as know-how, technology and brand presence are rendered especially
vulnerable in an international licensing arrangement, and the M-form
structure of the MNE is the only effective way of a 'fair'
return on investment across national boundaries. Indeed, it is
interesting to see how much the transaction cost theory has influenced
the international trade commissions such as GATT in their argument for
an international protection for Intellectual Property Rights (Scherer
& Ross, 1990). The assumption here is that the subsidiary nations in
the transnational agreement may not be willing to or able to enforce the
contractually determined criteria of appropriability. This thesis draws
substantially from the economic theories developed by the so-named
Chicago School in Economic Theory, represented among others by
influential theorists like Stigler (1988) and Green (1987), who argue
that economic institutions need to be freed from the influence of
governments to function effectively. Thus, the economic theories
informing the mainstream school of international management put forward
an argument that is rooted in the imperatives of economic efficiency and
industrial mobility, to suggest that MNEs are the most efficient
industrial structures within the paradigm of industrial capitalism.
The critical (predominantly Marxian) perspective of microeconomic
theory shares the mainstream belief that the state's role lies in
its ability to ensure the reproduction of the capitalist mode of
production, with the important exception that the state is also vested
with the ownership of a large portion of the enterprise and the power to
distribute the surplus value in an 'equitable' manner among
the society (Pitelis, 1991).
The critical perspective of the MNE can be understood by
juxtaposing Marglin's (1974) research on the role of the technology
of production in the increasing span of capitalist control of enterprise
with Hymer's (1979) work on the similar role played by firm size
and structure in increasing the control mechanisms as the firm moved
from a Marshallian (owner controlled firm) paradigm through the national
corporations (public limited concerns) to the M-form organization
(characterized by a separation of strategic and operational decisions).
According to the critical theorists, both the aspects of totalizing
technology and the totalizing span of control find expression in the
MNE, which represents the cutting edge of the controlling, profit
seeking and exploitative processes that characterize private enterprise
in a capitalist economy.
The mainstream view of the MNE in Political Science may be seen
represented in the works of Walter Weyl (1917), George Ball (1967) or
even, with some qualification, Adolf Berle (1954). This view, which is
still the prevalent view as articulated by Drucker (1986), Ohmae (1990)
and other gurus of globalization, saw the MNE as a response to the
growing dispersion of the economic base of industrial activity, and
predicted that the nation state, which was "rooted in concepts
unsympathetic to the needs of the complex world" (Ball, 1967),
would only be able to deal with this dispersion by the emergence of the
MNE.
The critical view on the other hand, sharply dissents against this
default definition of the MNE as a part of a global marketplace,
existing as a realm of freedom apart from the coercive domain of nation
states. Instead, it contends that the proponents for this unproblematic
view of the MNE are guilty of a gross generalization, whereby they seek
to apply the logic of the corporate restructuring of American society to
multinational relations and the world market (Bowman, 1993).
RESEARCH AGENDAS FOR A PLURALITY OF APPROACH
The debates mentioned above have tended to be severe in their
intensity, but are surprisingly never reflected in the theoretical
discussions in the field of GSM. Consequently, it is not surprising to
see very little research that has emerged addressing critical
perspectives, even for purposes of refutation. Indeed, in incorporating
interdisciplinary wisdom from the other social sciences with regard to
the internationalization of business activity, traditional management
theory has been informed almost exclusively by the mainstream theories
of the MNE. The application of alternate perspectives in the treatment
of this subject points to the following research agendas:
1. What is the impact of technological 'innovation'
brought about by the MNE on the socio economic processes of the
subsidiary nations?
2. What were the specific circumstances that led to the MNE
possessing the shape, structure and economic values that it currently
seems to possess?
3. Did the international corporations evolve into the entities they
are from 'natural' or inevitable laws of technology and
organization? If not, what processes of policy making, legislating or
even fighting mediated the production of such a reality?
IMPLICATIONS FOR RESEARCH IN GLOBAL STRATEGIC MANAGEMENT
A fourth research question that could be asked from the perspective
of the previous section could be--What exactly is the relationship
between the MNE and the nation state, and what are the possible
implications of such a relationship on the scholarship in strategic
management? This question arises primarily out of the empirical
observation that not only has the MNE been in a situation of advantage
in its expansion into newer international markets due to its superiority
in technology and size, but it often seems to have benefited either from
fundamental changes in the economic policies of the subsidiary nation or
in its political environment.
Mainstream economic theory has tended to explain this phenomenon in
terms of the "efficient structure hypothesis" (Stigler, 1968),
whereby economic institutions, in the absence of coercive supervision,
tend to gravitate toward a situation of stability. This view is also
echoed in mainstream political science, where there is general agreement
that cooperation, rather than conflict, is the basis of international
relations (Keohane, 1984). Not surprisingly, strategic management has
also tended to assume this view, arguing that multinational enterprises
operate in "contestable" markets (Baumol, 1977), where until a
firm achieves a certain threshold market share, cooperation is ruled out
as a strategy (Graham, 1991) and that successful internationalization is
an indication of greater innovation and better learning experiences in
domestic markets (Porter, 1990).
The moot point raised by critical theorists, as to whether these
theories adequately portray existing power imbalances and the role of
international economic regimes in reinforcing these inequities continues
to be unengaged with. For instance, it has been contended that
international economic regimes such as the erstwhile Bretton Woods
Agreement on exchange rates, the IMF, GATT and OECD, which have a
history of dominance by a few select countries in selection of
leadership, staffing and finance, are nascent representatives of
materialized relations of social production, which is subjected to
shadow control by a few nation states, thus implying that the nature of
control by nation states of international processes is being transformed
rather than being diminished. Critical economic and political theories
contest the representation of national interests in terms of the
interests of specific dominant classes. They see the state as a
condensation of class relations (Poulantzas, 1978), acting as the
organizer of the disparate interests of specific social strata, where
the powers encapsulated by the state are functions of the extent to
which the elite classes gain control over surplus value. The process by
which transnational elites and local elites engage in commerce has been
theorized in critical economic analysis by making distinctions between
fundamental class processes, which exist at the site of production and
subsumed class processes, which exist in transnational value flows such
as intellectual property rights and international debt service
repayments (Resnick & Wolf, 1987).
This then is the central theme of this paper: while mainstream
management theory has borrowed consistently from a particular viewpoint
prevalent in the social sciences, it has neglected to engage with, even
for the purpose of refutation, the critical treatment of
internationalization in these fields. In doing so, much of the research
and theory building in mainstream GSM has been contingent upon the
reification of the industrialized elite classes as being the sole
objects of national interest. It suits such an approach to view MNEs as
divorced from all local context, as disimbedded postmodern entities
devoid of any roots either in communities or in nations, which of course
absolves them of all fiduciary responsibilities to any constituency.
For instance, the Process School may be seen as a study of how the
transnational elite, represented by the controlling forces of the DMNC,
and the controlling elites of nation states engage in the dynamics of
cooperation and competition. As long as the discourse is able to equate
the interests of this controlling elite with 'local'
interests, the Process School remains a model of rational processual
inquiry. Likewise, as long as theories of entry and diversification
retain their economistic focus and stay out of the realms of cultural
environmental or political introspection, their models of causality and
interpretation will continue to remain valid.
Such a unilinear and view of a process as complex as
internationalization is quite perplexing. While this view of the
organization offers a consistency of argument, it is in danger of
imminent marginalization because of the speciousness of the assumptions
that drive this consistency. The reality of the process of international
expansion is that firms entering newer markets are encountering a high
level of uncertainty, heterogeneity and multiplicity. Also, in their
interaction with local and indigenous forms of society and industry,
they are causing very fundamental impacts, which need to be assessed,
challenged and transformed in an attempt to mediate the harmonious
process of international economic exchange. With its superficial (and
often ethnocentric) treatment of these issues, research in strategic
management may in fact be contributing to its own marginalization. Its
current focus is inadequate to explain the existing reality and
certainly in no shape to offer projections and prescriptions for future
courses of action.
CONCLUSION
In this paper, we have tried to historicize the field of global
strategic management, and contrast its approach against those that can
be found in a variety of different social sciences. We have been forced
to conclude that despite having access to a lively diversity of
perspectives on MNEs from these traditions, management theorists have
remained very unilinear in their focus. One of their conclusions, which
needs to be unpacked in future studies, is that it is not necessary for
an MNE to be imbedded in any local context, and that such
disimbeddedness is actually possible and feasible (Bartlett &
Ghoshal, 1991). Such an approach, we argue, is ideological in character,
and leads to a highly unilinear focus, which can be counterproductive in
the long run. GSM theorists need to re-examine and re-evaluate the issue
of imbeddedness, and recognize its pervasiveness (Poole, 1991) as well
as its positive attributes.
It however needs to be qualified that research in GSM has been very
useful in that often provided the most meticulous and innovative
analytical methods and tools. It has led the way in informing various
facets of the Resource based view of the firm, through an examination of
the core competency theories (Hamel, 1991), internal differentiation
processes (Ghoshal & Nohria, 1989), inter-organizational networking
(Ghoshal & Bartlett, 1990), the role of subsidiaries in structural
and processual frameworks (Jarillo & Martinez, 1990), schematics of
knowledge flows (Gupta & Govindarajan, 1991) and various other
aspects of the firm.
However, unless it continues to subject its basic assumptions to
rigorous scrutiny, and attempts to address areas of criticism that arise
from other social sciences and ideological positions, it will not be
able to extricate itself from the allegations that it is little more
than a polemical and inward looking branch of the study of
organizations.
REFERENCES
Amba Rao, S. C. (1993). Multinational corporate social
responsibility, ethics and third world governments: An agenda for the
1990s. Journal of Business Ethics, 12, 553-572.
Ball, G. W. (1967, June). The promise of the multinational
corporation. Fortune, 80.
Bartlett, C. & S. Ghoshal. (Summer 1991). Global strategic
management: impact on the new frontiers of strategy research. Strategic
Management Journal, 12, 5-16.
Baumol, W., J.C. Panzar & R. D. Willig (1982). Contestable
markets and the theory of industry structure. San Diego, CA: Harcourt
Brace.
Berle, A.A. (1954). The 20th century capitalist revolution. San
Diego, CA: Harcourt Brace.
Bowman, S.R. (1993). The ideology of transnational enterprise. The
Social Science Journal, 301, 47-68.
Buckley, P. & M.C. Casson (1976). The future of the
multinational enterprise. London: Macmillan.
Burrell, G. & G. Morgan (1979). Sociological paradigms and
organizational analysis. London: Heinemann.
Chandler, A.D. (1962). Strategy and structure. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Dicken, P. (1992). Global shift. London: Harper and Row.
Dobson, J. (1992). Ethics in the transnational corporation: The
"moral buck" stops where? Journal of Business Ethics, 11,
21-27.
Doz, Y. & C.K. Prahalad (1991, Summer). Managing DMNCs: A
search for a new paradigm. Strategic Management Journal, 12, 145-164.
Drucker, P. (1986). The changed world economy. Foreign Affairs, 64,
768-791.
Dunning J.H. (1980, Spring/Summer). Toward an eclectic theory of
international production: Some empirical tests. Journal of International
Business Studies, 11, 9-30.
Dunning, J.H. (1988). The eclectic paradigm of international
production: A restatement of some possible extensions. Administrative
Science Quarterly, 22, 248-263.
Franko, L.G. (1976). The European multinationals: A renewed
challenge to American and British big business. Gordon & Breach,
Philadelphia.
Ghoshal, S. (1987). Global strategy: An organizing framework.
Strategic Management Journal, 8, 425-440.
Ghoshal, S. & C. A. Bartlett (1990). The multinational
corporation as an inter-organizational network. Academy of Management
Review, 15(4), 603-625.
Ghoshal, S. & N. Nohria (1989). Internal differentiation
between multinational corporations. Strategic Management Journal, 10,
323-337.
Graham, E.M. (1991). Strategic management and transnational firm
behavior: A formal approach. In Pitelis, C.N. & R. Sugden (Eds.),
The Nature of the Transnational Firm (pp. 155-167). London: Routledge.
Green, D.G. (1987). The New Right. Wheatsheaf.
Gupta, A.K. & V. Govindarajan (1991). Knowledge flows and the
structure of control within multinational corporations. Academy of
Management Review, 16(4), 768-792.
Hall, D. & M. Salas (1980). Strategy follows structure!
Strategic Management Journal, 1, 149-163.
Hamel, G. (1991). Competition for competence and inter-partner
learning within international strategic alliances. Strategic Management
Journal 12 (Summer 1991 Special Issue): 83-104.
Harris, P. (2002). Global strategic planning: Cultural perspectives
for profit and non-profit organizations, European Business Review,
14(1): 64-65.
Hennart, J.F. (1991). The transaction cost theory of the
multinational enterprise. In Pitelis, C.N. & R. Sugden (Eds.) The
Nature of the Transnational Enterprise (pp. 81-116). London: Routledge.
Hymer, S. (1976). The international operations of national firms: A
study of direct foreign investments. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Keohane, R.O. (1984). After hegemony: Cooperation and discord in
the world political economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Jarillo, J. C. & J. I. Martinez (1990). Different roles of
subsidiaries: The case of multinational corporations in Spain. Strategic
Management Journal, 11, 501-512.
Marglin, S.A. (1974). What do bosses do? The origin and function of
hierarchy in capitalist production. Review of Radical Political
Economics, 6.
Martinez, J. I. & J. C. Jarillo (1989, Fall). The evolution of
research on coordination mechanisms in multinational corporations.
Journal of International Business Studies, 20(3), 489-514.
Melin, L. (1989). The field of force metaphor. In T. Cavusgil
(Eds.), Advances in International Marketing, 3, 161-179. Greenwich, CT:
JAI Press.
Melin, L. (1992). Internationalization as a strategy process.
Strategic Management Journal, 13, 99 118.
Nohria, N. & S. Ghoshal (1994). Differentiated fit and shared
values: Alternatives for managing headquarter-subsidiary relations.
Strategic Management Journal, 15(6), 491-502.
Ohmae, K. (1990). The Borderless World. New York.
Perlmutter, H.V. (1969). The tortuous evolution of the
multinational corporation, Columbia Journal of World Business, 9-18.
Peters, T. (Spring 1984). Strategy follows structure: Developing
distinct skills. California Management Review, 111-125.
Pitelis, C. (1991). Beyond the Nation-State? The transnational firm
and the Nation-State. Capital and Class, 43, 131-152.
Pooler, S. (1991). The state rules, OK? The continuing political
economy of Nation-States. Capital and Class, 43, 65-82.
Porter, M.E. (1990). The competitive advantage of nations. London:
Macmillan.
Poulantzas, N. (1978). Classes in contemporary capitalism. London:
Verso.
Prahalad C.K. (1990, May-June). Core competence of the corporation.
Harvard Business Review, 79-91
Pratt, C.B. (1991). Multinational corporate social policy process
for ethical responsibility in Sub Saharan Africa. Journal of Business
Ethics, 10, 527-541.
Resnick, S.A. & R. D. Wolff (1987). Knowledge and class: A
Marxian critique of political economy. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Ruccio, D., S. Resnick & R. Wolff. (1991, Spring). Class beyond
the Nation-State. Capital and Class, 25-41.
Scherer, F.M. & D. Ross (1990). Industrial market structure and
economic performance. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Stigler, G. (1968). The Organization of Industry. Homewood, IL
Richard Irwin Inc.
Stigler, G. (1988, January). The effect of government on economic
efficiency. Business Economics.
Stopford, J.M. & L.T. Wells (1972). Managing the multinational
enterprise. New York: Basic Books.
Van Gelder, S. (2004). Global brand strategy. Journal of Brand
Management, 12 (1): 39-48.
Weyl, W.E. (1917). American World Policies. New York: Macmillan.
Williamson, O.E. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism.
New York: The Free Press.
Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies. New York: The
Free Press.
Raza Mir, William Paterson University
Ali Mir, William Paterson University
Mehdi Hussain, North-South University