Are competitors advantageous or disadvantageous in consolidated versus fragmented industries?
Wright, Peter ; Ferris, Stephen P. ; Vaughan, Mary Jo 等
ABSTRACT
We contend that competitors may be mutually disadvantageous in
fragmented industries. Consequently, we expect that announcements of
firm distress will be associated with positive implications for
non-distressed competitors in fragmented industries. Alternatively we
speculate that, in consolidated industries, rivals may be advantageous
because they may offer net mutual benefits to each other. Thus, we
predict that the announcement of distress by a firm in a consolidated
industry will be received as negative news by its rivals since the
contribution of that firm to the industry may cease. We utilize the
event-study methodology to empirically test our hypotheses.
INTRODUCTION
While some senior executives may view the existence of rivals as
advantageous, others tend to perceive competitor firms as detrimental to
the interests of their own enterprises. We contend that whether
competitors are advantageous or detrimental may be situational. Our
conjecture is that in fragmented industries rivals may ordinarily be a
threat; whereas, in consolidated industries they may be beneficial. That
is because in fragmented industries competitors tend to be
confrontational but in many consolidated industries enterprises can be
non-confrontational and mutually advantageous in their rivalry. Whether
the presence of rivals is advantageous or disadvantageous to a firm may
be related to a variety of theories across a number of disciplines. We
discuss the implications of these theories in the context of two
settings--fragmented versus consolidated industry settings.
For reasons that we will subsequently provide, our premise is that
in fragmented industries competing enterprises may be reciprocally
detrimental. In consolidated industries, however, we presume that rivals
can be mutually beneficial. Yet whether firms in distinct industries
offer net mutual advantages or disadvantages to each other remains an
empirical question. If a firm is a threat to its rivals, its distress
should be good news for these rival firms. Alternatively, if the firm
can make a positive contribution to the industry, then its potential
demise should be seen as an unfavorable event.
The focus of our research is on exploring whether market values of
firms respond negatively or positively to announcements of distress by a
competitor, contingent on their industry affiliation. More specifically,
we examine how announcements of bankruptcy impact the equity values of
non-bankrupt competitors in consolidated and fragmented industries. An
event-study methodology, more completely described later in this study,
is used to accomplish the empirical analysis. If an announcement of a
firm's bankruptcy within an industry has adverse economic
implications for its non-bankrupt competitors, then their stocks should
suffer negative returns. Alternatively, if the announcement of a
bankruptcy benefits rivals, their stocks should experience positive
returns.
We organize this study into several sections. In the following
section we provide a literature review and present our hypotheses. We
then present our empirical analysis, describing both the sample
construction procedure and our application of the event-study
methodology. Finally, we report our findings and offer a discussion of
their interpretation.
RELATED LITERATURE AND HYPOTHESES
Traditionally, advocates of determinism have assigned to
organizations limited discretion within their environments. For
instance, industrial organization theorists have explained firm conduct
and performance as reflections of the structure of industry environment
(Bain, 1956; Mason, 1939). Conversely, in the past, proponents of
strategic choice have credited organizations with significant
proactivity within their environments (Andrews, 1971; Chandler, 1962).
More recently, however, advocates of determinism as well as strategic
choice have begun to move closer together. Strategic choice theorists
have recognized that the external environment may play a critical role
in a firm's quest for survival (Hambrick, 1983; Hrebiniak &
Joyce 1985). Alternatively, industrial organization theory has given
increased credence to firm strategy which may not only affect the
strategy of rivals but may also modify the structure of an industry
(Fudenberg & Tirole, 1984; Porter, 1980, 1985; Tirole, 1988).
The preceding discussion, however, provides different implications
for prospects of firms operating in fragmented industries versus those
in consolidated industries. In our view, firms competing in fragmented
industries may be externally constrained in their capability to
structure non-adversarial interrelationships. Note that due to low entry
(Baumol, Panzar, & Willig, 1982; Scherer & Ross, 1990) and
mobility barriers (Caves & Porter, 1977; Waring, 1996), many
enterprises with smaller market shares operate in fragmented industries.
In effect, numerous firms in such industries are forced to compete
toe-to-toe for resources and customers in overlapping industry niches.
Consequently, the proactive struggle for gains by any one firm, in this
setting, will likely be made at the expense of other enterprises
(Stigler, 1957). The ramification of these contentions is that as the
number of firms increase in an industry, so should the probability that
they may become detrimentally interrelated.
The notion that with a higher number of enterprises adversarial interactions may be promoted is consistent with the implications of
other works, such as Cournot's equilibrium pricing model (Cournot,
1971; Dixon, 1986; Novshek, 1980), research in game theory (Axelrod,
1984; Brandenburger & Nalebuff, 1995, 1996; Hill, 1990; Rappoport
& Chammah, 1965), as well as institutional (DiMaggio & Powell,
1983; Meyer & Rowen, 1977) and population ecology works (Baum, 1996;
Hannan & Carroll, 1992; Hannan & Freeman, 1977). According to Cournot's model, numerous firms in the industry--characteristic of
fragmented industries--are related to a more intense competition and
reduced profitability. That is because as the number of rivals increases
in an industry, the equilibrium price declines until it approaches the
product's marginal cost (Cournot, 1971; Dixon, 1986; Novshek,
1980).
Game theory also provides implications for enterprises in
fragmented industries. This theory, initially developed by von Neumann and Mortenstern (1944), has been applied to the study of negative-sum
and zero-sum-game circumstances (e.g., Axelrod, 1984; Brandenburger
& Nalebuff, 1995, 1996; Hill, 1990; Rappoport & Chammah, 1965).
In a zero-sum-game situation, competitors are constrained from being
non-adversarial. Instead, they tend to be confrontational because the
gain of one rival is only possible at a cost to another. In a
negative-sum-game context, rivals are also forced to be mutually
detrimental because for one competitor just to keep what it has requires
that another lose. Given our deliberation so far, both negative-sum and
zero-sum-game situations are characteristic of fragmented industry
circumstances, where firms proactively compete head-on for resources and
customers.
The conjecture that an increase in the number of enterprises may
promote adversarial interactions is also addressed in institutional
theory. For instance, DiMaggio and Powell (1983) suggest that as the
number of organizations that are competitively interrelated expands,
they are more likely to be mutually detrimental. Meyer and Rowan (1977)
similarly propose that as more organizations become competitively
interconnected, they will be increasingly confrontational. These
arguments are likewise compatible with the premise of population ecology
theory. Several population ecologists have suggested that as
organizations grow in number within sub-populations, they assume
correspondingly more adversarial roles, presumably because the
environment's carrying capacity limit is approached (Baum, 1996;
Hannan & Carroll, 1992; Hannan & Freeman, 1989).
Consistent with the previous discussion as well as the arguments of
Miles, Snow, and Sharfman (1993), we contend that toe-to-toe
competition, characteristic of a fragmented industry, not only may be
harmful for each enterprise but also such rivalry may undermine the
health of the industry. That is because intense rivalry tends to lower
profitability, inhibiting investments that could enhance product
performance or industry efficiencies. Under these circumstances, since
the existence of rivals tends to be disadvantageous, the potential exit
of a firm from a fragmented industry may be beneficial to other
enterprises because a reduction in the number of rivals may lessen the
intensity of competition. More specifically, a firm's distress and
its potential bankruptcy may be fortunate for survivors since they may
subsequently face fewer rivals in their jockeying for resources and
customers. Thus, we offer the following hypothesis:
H1: In fragmented industries, announcements of bankruptcy will be
associated with positive abnormal returns for non-bankrupt competitors
because the existence of rivals is disadvantageous.
Alternatively, a limited number of firms, but with larger market
shares, are contained in consolidated industries due to high entry
(Baumol, et al., 1982; Scherer & Ross, 1990) and mobility barriers
(Caves & Porter, 1977; Waring, 1996). In these industries, since
there are fewer rivals, enterprises tend to have the discretion to
compete in non-overlapping environmental niches, potentially avoiding
head-on competition for resources and customers (Baumol, et al., 1982;
Scherer & Ross, 1990; Tirole, 1988). In consolidated industries,
therefore, firms need not establish mutually detrimental
interrelationships. Indeed, enterprises may deliberately avoid
confrontational strategies in order to offset the possibility of
retaliation by others. The reason is that even though enterprises in
such industries may operate entirely independently, they recognize their
interdependence since any one rival's move has considerable effect
on others (Chamberlin, 1929; Machlup, 1952). Each firm, consequently,
may be hesitant to implement an adversarial strategy which, when
countered, would ultimately leave all industry members worse off.
These contentions are in conformance with other implications
inherent in Cournot's equilibrium pricing model (Cournot, 1971;
Dixon, 1986; Novshek, 1980), research in game theory (Axelrod, 1984;
Brandenburger & Nalebuff, 1995, 1996; Hill, 1990; Rappoport &
Chammah, 1965), as well as select strategy arguments (Buzzell &
Gale, 1987; Miles & Snow, 1986). According to Cournot's model,
fewer firms in an industry--characteristic of consolidated
industries--are associated with reduced confrontations and consequently
enhanced profitability, presumably because limited adversarial interfirm
behavior allows for the equilibrium price to be higher in an industry.
Alternatively, according to game theory, in positive-sum-game
situations, all players can win without resorting to destructive
interfirm behavior. Positive-sum-game situations are more applicable to
consolidated industry circumstances, where fewer rivals may operate in
non-overlapping industry niches; consequently, they need not proactively
compete head-on for resources and customers.
The speculation that fewer organizations in a sub-population of
enterprises may be non-confrontational is also recognized in
institutional and population ecology theories (Baum, 1996; Carroll,
1984; DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; Hannan & Freeman, 1977).
Accordingly, given that fewer firms may not impose on the
environment's carrying capacity limit, they need not resort to
adversarial inter-firm behavior. In these theories it is further
proposed that organizations could be advantageously interconnected
(Carroll, 1984; Gould, 1977; Hannan & Carroll, 1992; Hawley, 1968;
Meyer & Rowan, 1977). Consider, for instance, that the R & D
efforts of some firms may spill-over and benefit the other firms in the
industry. Alternatively, advertising by some enterprises may increase
the demand for the outputs of all organizations in the industry.
Consequently, the legitimacy of select firms (and their industry) may in
the preceding ways be enhanced vis-a-vis firms in substitute industries.
In a number of strategy related works, it is also argued that firms may
be beneficially interconnected as they adopt various strategies within
select industries that may require divergent resources. Moreover,
clusters of firms may address the particular needs of various groups of
customers, while obviating confrontational interfirm behavior (Buzzell
& Gale, 1987; Miles & Snow, 1986). Because the needs of various
customer groups may be more effectively met by different clusters of
firms addressing their unique needs, the long-term viability of an
entire industry may be enhanced, implying beneficial outcomes for all
firms operating in the industry. Note that fewer firms, potentially
adopting non-confrontational strategies, are more applicable to
circumstances prevailing in consolidated industries.
Further, the existence of different firm strategies, in the context
of consolidated industries, not only is advantageous because it obviates
competition for the same resources and customers, but can also provide
industrywide benefits because healthy industries may require a diversity
of complementary strategies. On this subject, Miles and Snow (1978,
1986) as well as Miles, Snow, and Sharfman (1993) argue that in some
industries there is an implicit complementary interdependence among
firms and that each enterprise with a different strategy may have a
synergistic role to play with its rivals for the industry to maintain a
long-run viability. Thus, the performance of each firm as well as the
industry's aggregate performance may suffer if any of the current
competitors potentially exit (Miles, Snow, & Sharfman, 1993). Under
these circumstances, a firm may create value for its rivals as it
creates value for itself. Thus, with mutually beneficial
interrelationships, the potential exit of a firm will eliminate the
benefit provided to competitors. Brandenburger and Nalebuff explain as
follows:
"In business, what does a particular player bring to the game? To
find the answer, look at the value created when everyone is in the
game, and then pluck that player out and see how much value the
remaining players can create. The difference is the removed
player's added value" (1995: 58).
Based upon the preceding discussion, we speculate that the
potential exit of a firm may be detrimental to rivals in consolidated
industries. Consequently, we propose the following hypothesis:
H2: In consolidated industries, announcements of bankruptcy will be
associated with negative abnormal returns for non-bankrupt rivals
because the existence of competitors is advantageous.
SAMPLE CONSTRUCTION AND METHODOLOGY
Over the period of one decade--January 1980 through December
1989--we identify 841 bankruptcy announcements through a search
utilizing the Dow Jones News Retrieval Service. We eliminate from this
sample any firms that report other potentially contaminating events
(e.g., earnings reports, management turnover, strikes, capital
expenditures, restructuring) in the period surrounding the bankruptcy
announcement. We also exclude firms from further consideration if they
are not listed on the New York (NYSE), American (AMEX), or Over the
Counter (OTC) stock exchanges, if they have announcements of
bankruptcies following their delisting from an exchange, if they lack
common stock returns on the day of the announcement (day 0), or have
less than 50 daily stock returns over the estimation period (day -265 to
day -16). Our final sample consists of bankruptcy announcements for 274
firms, with 113 listed on either the NYSE or AMEX and the remaining 161
listed as OTC issues. The non-bankrupt competitor sample is formed by
selecting firms in the same four-digit Standard Industry Classification
(SIC) code industries as those firms announcing bankruptcies. Each
bankrupt firm averages over 9 competitors and results in a total sample
of 2,563 competitor firms.
To assess the impact of a bankruptcy announcement, we separately
examine the abnormal returns to the NYSE/AMEX and OTC-listed competitors
of the bankrupt firms. The reason for a separate analysis, based on
exchange listing, is to test for possible industry concentration
effects. NYSE/AMEX bankruptcies typically represent consolidated
industries with fewer firms that have larger market shares, while those
on the OTC generally reflect bankruptcies in fragmented indus-tries with
more numerous companies that have smaller market shares (Scherer &
Ross, 1990; Tirole, 1988). This is indicated by the values for
Herfindahl-Hirschman (HH) Index, calculated as the sum of the squared
market shares of companies with the same four-digit SIC codes as the
firm filing for Chapter 11. Thus the HH Index can be interpreted as a
measure of industry concentration, with higher values indicating greater
consolidation, and by implication, fewer but larger individual firms.
The mean HH index value for the NYSE/AMEX-listed companies is 0.32 while
the corresponding value for OTC-listed firms is 0.06.
We emphasize that some competing firms within an industry may be
listed on different exchanges. Yet, this does not distort our results.
By separately calculating CARs accruing to non-bankrupt competitors
listed on the exchanges over the period surrounding an announcement of
bankruptcy (Table 1), we assure that the abnormal returns are
attributable to the impact of the bankruptcy rather than any
idiosyncratic characteristic of the exchange. Specifically, we employ
the market model event methodology which analyzes a daily series of mean
excess returns, calculated by equally weighting returns across the
samples of non-bankrupt competitor firms (Brown & Warner, 1985).
Additionally, we sum these daily excess returns to obtain a cumulative
abnormal return (CAR), which provides a more comprehensive measure of
the event's unanticipated impact on equity values. To enhance
robustness, we provide our analysis for several CAR reporting periods or
windows.
Although there are other empirical models available to test
abnormal stock performance, we elect to use the market model for two
reasons. First, the market model has been widely used in empirical
studies to estimate measures of excess return beginning with the first
event study by Fama, Fisher, Jensen and Roll (1969) and continuing to
the present. Indeed, the Brown and Warner (1985) review of event
methodology reports that the market model is more powerful in terms of
its ability to identify abnormal performance than other models that are
available. This suggests the second reason for our use of the market
model. Unlike the CAPM or the empirical market line, the market model is
not vulnerable to Roll's (1977) criticism. Hence, the abnormal
return analysis provided by the market model estimates in this study are
not subject to the mathematical criticisms originally noted by Roll and
now generally recognized as compelling in the related literature.
One of the possible biases that may be present in an event study
results from the thin trading of the firm's securities.
Specifically, thin or reduced trading of a firm's equities may
result in serial correlation between observed security and index returns
and a consequent bias in ordinary least square (OLS) estimates of the
systematic risk (beta) coefficient. An econometric approach to solving
this potential problem is the use of the Scholes-Williams (1977)
technique for beta estimation. The Scholes-Williams beta coefficient
results from weighting a series of beta estimates for a security that
have been calculated against both synchronous and non-synchronous market
return data. We find that the reestimation of our event residuals using
the Scholes-Williams betas do not qualitatively change our results and
leave our conclusions the same. Hence, we conclude that thin trading
volume is not present in our sample of firms and that our excess return
estimates are statistically unbiased.
It is important to note that the event methodology controls for
macroeconomic activity that may influence the level of stock returns and
thereby distort our estimate of bankruptcy's impact upon equity
returns (Brown & Warner, 1985). Thus, if one observes a negative
abnormal rate of return for a non-bankrupt competitor's stock
surrounding an announcement of bankruptcy, the event methodology allows
us to attribute it to the bankruptcy event rather than to other factors
(e.g., changes in gross domestic product, shifts in the structure of
industries, expansion or contraction in specific industries,
technological innovations in substitute industries).
Moreover, the event methodology is based on an assumption of
capital market efficiency that requires investors to revise their
expectations about a firm's prospects only upon the announcement of
new, economically relevant information. If an announcement does not
affect a firm's economic prospects, one should not observe
significant abnormal returns at the time of its release. Likewise, there
should be no significant abnormal returns at the time of the
announcement if the details of the bankruptcy have been anticipated or
leaked in advance.
In this context, we should also emphasize that some observers
suggest that a bankruptcy is a downward spiral that may be predictable
several years in advance (Hambrick & D'Aveni, 1988). For such
bankruptcies, we do not anticipate significant abnormal returns on the
announcement date. Not all downward spirals, however, will ultimately
result in bankruptcy. For instance, some downward spirals may be
reversed through a turnover in top management (Tushman, Newman, &
Romanelli, 1986; Tushman & Romanelli, 1985; Warner & Watts,
1988) or through retrenchment (Blackwell, Marr, & Spivey, 1990) or
through voluntary, internal restructuring (Brickley & Van Drunen,
1990; Donaldson, 1990; John, Lang, & Netter, 1992). We apply the
event methodology to our sample, presuming bankruptcies were
unanticipated by the market. Specifically, such bankruptcy announcements
would not have been anticipated by investors, either because downward
spirals were not evident or because projected results were previously
expected to be offset by such measures as senior manager turnover,
retrenchment, or voluntary restructuring. To the extent that
bankruptcies are anticipated, CARs of competitor firms will necessarily
be less significant. That is because an efficient capital market will
have already capitalized its response to the news of the bankruptcy
announcement in the share prices of competitors, resulting in only an
insignificant price change for rivals at the time of the actual
announcement.
Finally, our event methodology results are not significantly
effected by the presence of more asset diverse corporations. That is,
one may argue that a bankruptcy announcement in a given industry may
have a lesser impact on the equity value of conglomerate-like rivals.
Such a situation would bias our methodology against finding significant
returns, as opposed to observing significant negative abnormal returns
accruing to non-bankrupt competitors.
In addition to the loss of contributions provided by a competitor,
a bankruptcy may negatively affect the returns of a non-bankrupt rival
for an alternative reason, provided by contagion theory. The contagion
theoretical reason is based on the presumption that if one firm in an
industry is distressed, then others in the industry may confront similar
distresses. Known as the contagion effect (Altman, 1984; Bernanke, 1983;
Lang & Stulz, 1992), accordingly, non-bankrupt firms may be
negatively impacted by a bankruptcy announcement since it may signal
that an entire industry is threatened, with consequent negative
implications for the asset values of the remaining firms.
The contagion theory appears to most directly apply to entropic
firms lacking growth opportunities (Altman, 1984; Lindenberg & Ross,
1981). Firms lack growth opportunities because their internal resources
are not valuable or because of their position in declining industries
(Barney, 1991; Lado, Boyd, & Wright, 1992; Lindenberg & Ross,
1981; Wright, Ferris, Sarin, & Awasthi, 1996). The contagion impact
is based on the assumption that the distress of one firm and its steady
deterioration implies that its competitors may have similar difficulties
because of internal vulnerabilities or external threats associated with
the lack of growth opportunities (Altman, 1984; Barney, 1991; Lado, et.
al., 1992; Lindenberg & Ross, 1981). In Schumpetarian (1934) terms,
the contagion effect suggests that the distress of a single firm may
imply an industrywide threat as enterprises external to the industry
develop new technologies which render the outputs of existing firms less
desirable or possibly obsolete, suggesting lack of growth prospects for
these firms.
Lindenberg and Ross (1981) and Wright and colleagues (1996) propose
that individual firm values of Tobin's q ratio can proxy for the
existence of growth opportunities. Tobin's q is defined as the
market value of a firm standardized by the replacement cost of its
assets. Consequently, firms with q's of unity or less can be judged
as overinvested and lacking growth prospects. Lindenberg and Ross (1981)
and Wright and colleagues (1996) explain that the absence of growth
opportunities for firms may be due to inefficiency, technological
inferiority, locational disadvantages or declining industries.
Alternatively, firms with q's in excess of unity may be viewed as
under-invested, whose value is largely driven by the existence of growth
opportunities. Such firms may possess valuable resources and operate in
profitable industries. Thus, to control for a possible contagion effect,
we separately examine the abnormal returns of firms based on the value
of their Tobin's q ratio. If contagion does exist, then firms which
lack growth opportunities (i.e., low-q firms) should be most negatively
impacted by an announcement of a competitor's bankruptcy since they
are less capable of exploiting subsequent business opportunities.
Conversely, high-growth firms (i.e., high-q firms) should be less
adversely affected by such bankruptcy announcements since they are
likely to possess the resources and competencies to exploit their
competitors' misfortunes.
Through the use of Tobin's q, we can test for the existence
and relative dominance of the contagion versus the advantageous
competition effects. The subsample of low-q firms are those firms with
an unfavorable market valuation of the future earnings capability of
their assets within their industries. These firms lack attractive
investment options in their industry and are unlikely to generate growth
in their corporate cashflows. Because of this, these firms are less
capable of attracting new investment capital or exploring new
technologies and projects within their industries. The high-q subsample,
however, represents a set of firms with a favorable market valuation of
their future growth opportunities within their industries. These firms
possess a set of profitable investment opportunities. As such, they are
financially resilient and have the greater access to external capital
markets. They have more resources, both actual and potential, with which
to develop new technologies or extend operations into new markets.
Consequently, we contend that on a relative basis, high-q
enterprises are less likely to suffer from an industry contagion than
the low-q companies. This is an important, yet subtle point in our
argument. Although high-q firms may suffer negative returns from an
industry contagion, they will suffer less than the low-q firms. The
reason is that such firms have greater resources with which to address
adverse developments. Thus, the potential existence of the contagion
effect requires that we compare the magnitudes of the CARs for the two
q-based subsamples. As discussed subsequently, we find that based upon
an economic interpretation of Tobin's q, the high-q firms are more
negatively impacted by the news of a rival's bankruptcy than the
low-q firms. We conclude that this is inconsistent with the impact of an
industry contagion on share prices in a rational capital market.
RESULTS AND A FURTHER TEST
In Table 1, we provide CARs for impacts of bankruptcies listed on
the various exchanges. Non-bankrupt competitors of larger
NYSE/AMEX-listed firms that announce bankruptcies experience negative
CARs. Note that these negative CARs are statistically significant for
the standard two-day event window of (-1, 0) whether non-bankrupt
competitors are listed on either the NYSE/AMEX or the OTC exchange. The
negative CARs are not only indicative that non-bankrupt firms are worse
off with a potential demise of a member firm, but also that these firms
are not beneficiaries of a lesser competitive intensity. That is because
the loss to the firm announcing bankruptcy is not a gain to its
non-bankrupt rivals. If the competitive effect were present, we would
expect to witness positive CARs in response to a bankruptcy announcement
instead of negative CARs.
Regarding the possibility of competitive effect, Altman (1984) as
well as Lang and Stulz (1992) suggest that the potential demise of a
firm may favorably impact its rivals if a redistribution of wealth (or
resources) from the bankrupt firm to its competitors can be anticipated.
For instance, suppliers and customers may be reluctant to do business
with a firm announcing bankruptcy. Thus, their business activity will be
switched to various non-bankrupt competitors. In this way, the value of
the firm announcing bankruptcy would be lowered while the value of its
rivals may be enhanced, reflecting the anticipated redistribution of
wealth from the bankrupt firm to its rivals.
Note that the CARs for competitors are insignificant, however, when
the bankruptcy announcements are made by a smaller OTC-listed firm.
These results are consistent with hypothesis H2, but not H1. We
emphasize that the CARs for the smaller and larger firms in our sample
are unbiased. That is because we employ the widely cited market model
(Fama, 1976) to estimate the abnormal returns reported in our study. The
market model contains a market risk adjustment as well as an adjustment
for non-market risk factors. We empirically accomplish this through the
estimation of a series of linear regression models between the
market's returns and those of the sample firms over a 250-day
estimation period that precedes the days of the event periods. This
provides us with estimates of an intercept term (alpha) and a slope
(beta) coefficient. These parameters are then used to net an expected
return from the realized returns to generate the abnormal return. These
abnormal returns are then cross-sectionally averaged and summed to
obtain the CARs. Thus, whatever impact average firm size may exert on a
firm's returns is incorporated in the alpha term, leaving the
abnormal returns unbiased. This approach represents a standard
application of the event-study methodology to examine the valuation
impact of an unanticipated event.
In Table 2 we present the CARs of firms separated into low- and
high-q portfolios. The high-q firms are significantly and negatively
affected (while the low-q firms are insignificantly impacted) by the
news of a rival's bankruptcy. Moreover, the results are fairly
dramatic as high-q firms experience negative CARs over two different
event windows. Alternatively, the low-q firms experience CARs that are
insignificantly different from zero. This is inconsistent with the
impact of a contagion effect on share prices in an efficient capital
market. Thus, the equity price reaction by firms to a rival's
bankruptcy announcement does not indicate that rivals face similar
troubles due to common external threats or internal vulnerabilities.
These results are further supportive of hypothesis H2.
Why is hypothesis H1 not supported? That is, why are the CARs
insignificant when a smaller firm in a fragmented industry announces a
bankruptcy? Two reasons may explain this lack of significance. First,
one may argue that the potential demise of a troubled firm will not
impact its rivals if other organizations can easily replace it. We
speculate that the probability of other enterprises replacing the
activities of a small firm located in a fragmented industry that may
fail is higher. That is because fragmented industries have lower entry
(Baumol, et al., 1982; Scherer & Ross, 1990) and mobility barriers
(Caves & Porter, 1977; Waring, 1996). Low barriers facilitate the
entry of new firms into an industry, thus making it possible for new
competitors to replace the activities of the bankrupt firm.
Second, bankruptcies of smaller firms may be due to the inherent
liability of small-scale operations or their newness (Hambrick &
D'Aveni, 1988, 1992; Stinchcombe, 1965). These fac-tors are
idiosyncratic to the circumstances of smaller troubled firms and hence
are likely to have little impact on rivals. Alternatively, however, the
probable impact on surviving firms due to the failure of a larger
troubled competitor in a consolidated industry is likely to be
significant. Consolidated industries have higher entry (Baumol, et al.,
1982; Scherer & Ross, 1990) and mobility barriers (Caves &
Porter, 1977; Waring, 1996). These barriers preclude the easy entrance
of new rivals that can substitute for the activities of the larger
failed firm.
Indeed, in aggregate, we expect that the significant impact on
share prices of rivals due to larger firms announcing bankruptcies will
dominate the insignificant impact on stock prices of competitors in
response to smaller enterprises announcing bankruptcies. To test this,
we analyze the effect of all bankruptcy announcements in our sample on
share prices of non-bankrupt rivals. As shown in Table 3, we present a
time series of daily abnormal returns to the portfolio of competitors of
all firms announcing a Chapter 11 filing. Although these daily abnormal
returns vary, most observations are negative. The significant finding
occurs in the standard two-day window of (-1, 0) where the cumulative
abnormal return is -0.39% and statistically significant at the 0.05
level. This finding is consistent with our expectation.
DISCUSSION AND IMPLICATIONS
The contentions of our study are consistent with the theoretical
implications of the arguments of diverse scholars (e.g., Axelrod, 1984;
Baumol, et al., 1982; Brandenburger & Nalebuff, 1995, 1996; Caves
& Porter, 1977; Chamberlin, 1929; Cournot, 1971; DiMaggio &
Powell, 1983; Hannan & Carroll, 1992; Machlup, 1952; Miles &
Snaw, 1978, 1986; Miles, Snow, & Sharfman, 1993; Scherer & Ross,
1990; Stigler, 1957; Tirole, 1988; Waring, 1996). Based on the related
literature, we have speculated that competing enterprises in fragmented
industries may be reciprocally disadvantageous. Although our speculation
may be intuitively appealing, the empirical findings do not
unambiguously support such a speculation potentially because of easy
entry of new firms into frag-mented industries (Caves & Porter,
1977; Scherer & Ross, 1990; Waring, 1996) as well as factors which
may be idiosyncratically relevant to the circumstances of smaller
enterprises (Hambrick & D'Aveni, 1988, 1992; Stinchcombe,
1965). Nevertheless, we surmise that managers in fragmented industries
may be justified to view their rival firms as a threat. A paradoxical
implication of frag-mentation, however, is that such industries can
represent a unique strategic opportunity. While fragmented industries
with low barriers are unattractive because their firms are mutually
disadvantageous, it is possible for a firm to advantageously consolidate
some of these industries. Indeed, "the payoff to consolidating a
fragmented industry can be high because the costs of entry into it are
by definition low, as there tend to be small and relatively weak
competitors who offer little threat of retaliation" (Porter, 1980:
200).
Our results, however, tend to be in contrast to the view of those
senior executives who may perceive their rivals as primarily a threat in
consolidated industries. Such managers typically do not assume that
competitors can contribute to the long-term viability of either the
industry or their own firm. Our findings are consistent with the notion
that competitors may beneficially contribute to each other in
consolidated industries. Consequently, the performance of firms may
suffer in such industries if the contributions of their rivals are
temporarily or permanently withdrawn through an announcement of
bankruptcy (Brandenburger & Nalebuff, 1995, 1996; Miles, Snow, &
Sharfman, 1993).
An implication of the preceding discussion is that in consolidated
industries a constructive approach to rivalry may create opportunities
for mutually beneficial strategies. Additionally, an implication of our
work may be that viewing rivals as advantageous in consolidated
industries may become even more important in the future. As the pressure
for enhanced efficiency and innovation increases, more firms may find it
necessary to view their rivals as a constructive force and a poten-tial
ally. Indeed, recent trends suggest that even the most vigorous
competitors can form beneficial strategic interconnectedness (Templin,
1995).
REFERENCES
Altman, E. (1984). A further investigation of the bankruptcy cost
question. Journal of Finance, 39: 1067-1089.
Andrews, K.R. (1971). The concept of corporate strategy. Homewood:
Dow Jones Irwin.
Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic
Books.
Bain, J. (1956). Barriers to new competition. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press.
Barney, J.B. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive
advantage. Journal of Management, 17: 99-120.
Baum, J.A.C. (1996). Organizational ecology. In Clegg, S.R., Hardy,
C., & Nord, W.R. Handbook of Organization
Studies. London: SAGE Publications, 77-114.
Baumol, W.J., Panzar, J.C. & Willig, R.D. (1982). Contestable
markets and the theory of industry structure. New York: Harcourt Brace
Jovanovich.
Bernanke, B.S. (1983). Nonmonetary effects of the financial crisis.
American Economic Review, 73: 257-276.
Blackwell, D.W., Marr, M.W. & Spivey, M.F. (1990).
Plant-closing decisions and the market value of the firm. Journal of
Financial Economics, 26: 277-288.
Brandenburger, A.M., & Nalebuff, B.J. (1995). The right game:
Use game theory to shape strategy. Harvard Business Review, 73(4):
57-71.
Brandenburger, A.M. & Nalebuff, B.J. (1996). Co-opetition. New
York: Currency/Doubleday.
Brickley, J.A. & Van Drunen, L.D. (1990). Internal corporate
restructuring: An empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting and
Economics, 12: 251-280.
Brown, S.J. & Warner, J.B. (1985). Using daily stock returns:
The case of event studies. Journal of Financial Economics, 14: 3-31.
Buzzell, R.D. & Gale, B.T. (1987). The PIMS principles: Linking
strategy to performance. New York: The Free Press
Carroll, G.R. (1984). The specialist strategy, in G. Carroll &
D. Vogel (Eds.), Strategy and or-ganization: A west coast perspective.
Boston: Pitman: 117-128.
Caves, R.E. & Porter, M.E. (1977). From entry barriers to
mobility barriers: Conjectural decisions and contrived deterrence to new
competition. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 91: 241-262.
Chamberlin, E.H. (1929). Duopoly: Value where sellers are few.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 43: 63-100.
Chandler, A.D. (1962). Strategy and structure: Chapters in the
history of American industrial enterprise. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Cournot, A.A. (1971). Research into the mathematical principles of
the theory of wealth. Translated by N.T. Bacon. New York: Augustus M.
KeRlley, Publisher.
Dixon, H. (1986). The Cournot and Bertrand outcomes as equilibria
in a strategic metagame. Economic Journal, 96: 59-70.
DiMaggio, P.J. & Powell, W.W. (1983). The iron cage revisited:
Institutional isomorphism and col-lective rationality in organizational
fields, American Sociological Review, 48: 147-160.
Donaldson, G. (1990). Voluntary restructuring: The case of General
Mills. Journal of Financial Economics, 27: 117-141.
Fama, E.F. (1976). Foundations of Finance. New York: Basic Books,
Inc.
Fama, E.F., Fisher, L., Jensen, M.C. & Roll, R. (1969). The
adjustment of stock prices to new in-formation. International Economic
Review, 10: 1-21.
Fudenberg, D. & Tirole, J. (1984). The fat cat effect, the
puppy dog ploy and the lean hungry look. American Economic Review, 74
(May): 361-368.
Gould, S.J. (1977). Ever since Darwin. New York: Norton Press.
Hambrick, D.C. & D'Aveni, R.A. (1988). Large corporate
failures as downward spirals. Administrative Science Quarterly, 33:
1-23.
Hambrick, D.C. (1983). High profit strategies in mature capital
goods industries: A contingency approach. Academy of Management Journal,
26: 687-707.
Hannan, M.T. & Carroll, G.R. (1992). Dynamics of organizational
populations: Density, legitima-tion and competition. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Hannan, M.T. & Freeman, J.H. (1977). The population ecology of
organizations, American Journal of Sociology, 82: 929-964.
Hawley, A. (1968). Human ecology, in Sills, D.L. (Ed.),
International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences. New York: Macmillan.
Hill, C.W.L. (1990). Cooperation, opportunism, and the invisible
hand: Implications for transaction cost theory. Academy of Management
Review, 15: 500-513.
Hrebiniak, L.G. & Joyce, W.F. (1985). Organizational
adaptation: Strategic choice and environ-mental determinism.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 30: 336-349.
John, K., Lang, L.H.P. & Netter, J. (1992). The voluntary
restructuring of large firms in response to performance decline. Journal
of Finance, 47: 891-917.
Lado, A.A., Boyd, N.G. & Wright, P. (1992). A competency-based
model of sustained competitive advantage: Toward a conceptual
integration. Journal of Management, 18: 77-91.
Lang, L.H.P. & Stulz, R.M. (1992). Contagion and competitive
intra-industry effects of bankruptcy announcements: An empirical
analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 32: 45-60.
Lindenberg, E. & Ross, S. (1981). Tobin's q ratio and
industrial organization. Journal of Business, 54: 1-32.
Machlup, F. (1952). The political economy of monopoly. Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins Press.
Mason, E.S. (1939). Price and production policies of large-scale
enterprises. American Economic Review, 29: 61-74.
Meyer, J.W. & Rowan, B. (1977). Institutional organizations:
Formal structure as myth and ceremony, American Journal of Sociology,
83, 340-363.
Miles, G., Snow, C.C. & Sharfman, M.P. (1993). Industry variety
and performance. Strategic Management Journal, 14: 163-177.
Miles, R.E. & Snow, C.C. (1978). Organizational strategy,
structure, and process. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company.
Miles, R.E. & Snow, C.C. (1986). Organizations: New concepts
for new forms. California Management Review, 28: 62-73
Novshek, W. (1980). Cournot equilibrium with free entry, Review of
Economic Studies, 47: 473-486.
Porter, M.E. (1980). Competitive strategy: Techniques for analyzing
industry and competitors. New York: The Free Press.
Porter, M.E. (1985). Competitive advantage: Creating and sustaining
superior performance. New York: The Free Press.
Rappoport, A. & Chammah, A.M. (1965). Prisoner's dilemma.
Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.
Roll, R. (1977). A critique of the asset pricing theory's
tests; Part I: On past and potential testability of theory. Journal of
Financial Economics, 4: 129-176.
Scherer, F.M. & Ross, D. (1990). Industrial market structure
and economic performance. Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company.
Scholes, M. & Williams, J. (1977). Estimating betas from
non-synchronous data. Journal of Financial Economics, 5: 309-327.
Schumpeter, J.A. (1934). The theory of economic development.
Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Stigler, G.J. (1957). Perfect competition historically
contemplated. Journal of Political Economy, 65: 1-17.
Stinchcombe, A.L. (1965). Social structure and organizations. In
March, J.G. (Ed.). Handbook of organizations. Chicago: Rand McNally.
Templin, N. (1995). Strange bedfellows: More and more firms enter
joint ventures with big competitors. Wall Street Journal, November 1, A1
and A12.
Tushman, M., Newman, W.H. & Romanelli, E. (1986). Convergence
and upheaval: Managing the unsteady pace of organizational evolution.
California Management Review, 29: 29-44.
Tushman, M. & Romanelli, E. (1985). Organizational evolution: A
metamorphosis model of convergence and reorientation. In Cummings, L.L.,
& Staw, B.M., (Eds.), Research in Organizational Behavior,
Greenwich: JAI Press.
von Neumann, J. & Mortenstern, O. (1944). Theory of games and
economic behavior. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Waring, G.F. (1996). Industry differences in the persistence of
firm-specific returns. American Economic Review, 86: 1253-1265.
Warner, J.B. & Watts, R. (1988). Stock prices and top
management changes. Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 461-492.
Wright, P., Ferris, S.P., Sarin, A. & Awasthi, V. (1996).
Impact of corporate insider, blockholder, and institutional equity
ownership on firm risk taking. Academy of Management Journal, 39:
441-463.
Peter Wright, University of Memphis
Stephen P. Ferris, University of Missouri at Columbia
Mary Jo Vaughan, Mercer University
William T. Jackson, University of Texas of the Permian Basin
Table 1: Cumulative Abnormal Returns of Competitors Listed By
Their Exchanges for Select Windows
Bankrupt Firm Listing
NYSE/AMEX OTC
Competitor Firm
Listing
Window CAR T-Stat CAR T-Stat
NYSE/AMEX -1, 0 -0.0059 -2.00 * -0.028 -0.99
-1, +1 -0.0082 -2.28 * -0.0018 -0.52
OTC -1, 0 -0.0047 -1.88 ([dagger]) -0.0020 -0.90
-1, +1 -0.0049 -1.61 -0.0019 -0.70
([dagger]) p < .10
* p < .05
Table 2: Cumulative Abnormal Returns to Competitors Sorted by
Tobin's q Ratio
Windows Firms with q > 1 Firms with q =1
-1, 0 -0.0028 * 0.0011
-2.150 1.201
-1, +1 -0.0030 * 0.0017
-1.992 0.967
* p< .05
Table 3: Daily Abnormal Returns (ABRET for Competitors of Firms
Announcing Chapter 11 Filings (1979-1989)
Daily Stock Price
Day Reaction (ABRET) T-Statistic
-15 -0.0018 -0.789
-14 -0.0003 -0.172
-13 -0.0003 -0.560
-12 -0.0010 -2.004 *
-11 -0.0000 -0.561
-10 -0.0010 -0.152
-9 0.0003 0.512
-8 -0.0016 -1.041
-7 -0.0005 -0.340
-6 -0.0012 -1.824 ([dagger])
-5 -0.0009 -0.069
-4 -0.0006 -0.513
-3 -0.0010 -0.098
-2 -0.0038 -3.434 **
-1 -0.0015 -0.714
0 -0.0025 -1.232
1 0.0005 0.848
2 0.0005 0.831
3 0.0002 0.871
4 -0.0005 -0.382
5 -0.0016 -0.336
6 -0.0016 -0.638
7 -0.0007 -0.126
8 0.0008 1.323
9 -0.0010 -0.252
10 0.0002 0.663
11 0.0011 1.535
12 -0.0014 -0.181
13 -0.0016 -1.871 ([dagger])
14 0.0004 1.060
15 -0.0012 -0.073
Cumulative Abnormal Returns (CARS of Competitors for Select Windows
Windows CAR Z-Statistic
(-1, 0) -0.0039 -2.05 *
(-1, +1) -0.0034 -1.47
(-5, +5) -0.0034 -0.76
(-10, +10) -0.0074 -1.20
([dagger]) p < .10
* p < .05
** p < .01