Stock valuations on earnings versus cash flow.
Ma, K.C. ; Pace, R. Daniel ; Stryker, Jud 等
ABSTRACT
Stock prices are mainly affected by short-term earnings. This is
contrary to conventional wisdom in finance. However, we did find that
cash flow is also used primarily to price what we classify as negative
stocks or in distress times. This is consistent with the arguments of
rational bubbles. For stocks under strong public scrutiny, investors
tend to follow others' decisions and, for whatever reason, they
feel compelled to conform to the majority even though their private
information suggests otherwise.
JEL Classifications: G11, G12, G13
Keywords: cash flow; earnings; valuation; information cascade;
rational bubbles; behavioral finance
I. INTRODUCTION
At Berkshire Hathaway's 2002 annual shareholders meeting,
Buffett said "We'll never buy a company when the managers talk
about EBITDA. There are more frauds talking about EBITDA. That term has
never appeared in the annual reports of companies like Walmart, General
Electric, and Microsoft. The fraudsters are trying to con you or
they're trying to con themselves."
The most celebrated investor's message couldn't be
clearer. In terms of value, it is what you can take out of a business
that really counts, not the earnings reported by the company. A major
earnings-centric culprit is the equity analyst community, which has a
clear bias toward earnings when formulating forecasts. An examination of
the widely used IBES database indicates that only 15% of the equity
analysts reporting provide estimates on future cash flow, yet all of
them routinely make earnings forecasts. This evidence manifests the fact
that for public firms there is a disproportional emphasis on earnings.
One problem with earnings focus is that forecasts of future
earnings have been known to be overly optimistic. On September 21, 2001,
despite a negative cash event, Amazon.com was trading at an unreal
price/earnings ratio (P/E) of 2000 at time when its stock was $192. The
only way to justify such a lofty price level would be as if
Amazon's earnings were to grow at an annual rate of 80% for the
next 10 years. When its price peaked at $225, Amazon's market
capitalization of $52 billion was larger than the GDPs of 125 countries.
This exaggerated valuation has since been explained as an example of
"stock market myopia"--investors' fixating on short-term
earnings.
Furthermore, since 2002 there has been a new movement led by the
CEOs of top blue chip companies such as GE, Microsoft, and Intel to
voluntarily stop providing earnings guidance, with the goal to relieve
managers from being boxed into hitting short-term targets, and investors
from being misguided. The critics claim, rather, that the firms are
self-serving, especially since most of the firms that stopped issuing
earnings guidance had already experienced poor earnings and stock
performance. This is evident by a separation between public opinion and
stock prices. When surveying online regarding whether the practice of
earnings guidance should be stopped, the "blog" comments were
overwhelmingly supportive. Yet, market prices reacted negatively after
firms announced to stop earnings guidance. (8)
For the question at hand, two well-cited surveys produce
contrasting results. In Block's survey of AIMR members in 1999,
earnings was ranked as the most important variable than cash flow, book
value, and dividend in valuing a stock. However, according to the
Merrill Lynch Institutional Factor Survey, institutional investors used
an average of eight valuation factors in selecting stocks, and price to
cash flow was more widely used in investment practice than other value
measures during 1989-2001. On average, 46.1% of the respondents
consistently used price to cash flow. The inconsistency between the
above two surveys does not help resolve the question of what variable(s)
investors actually use in their valuation process. It is still puzzling
as to why the masses appear to know cash flow is the correct pricing
methodology, yet they continue to focus on earnings. This, however,
cannot be explained by irrationality given its ubiquity throughout the
stock market history.
Another duality is investors' drastically different approaches
to valuing publically traded stocks versus private equities, though the
lack of public information for private firms somewhat dictates the
obvious difference in thinking. By law, private firms are not required
to disclose information, except to the holders of debt instruments to
whom the relevant information is the change in cash flow that reflects
debt-servicing ability. It is not surprising that firms that turn
private also switch their focus on financial reporting from earnings to
cash flow. (9) Thus, to value private equities, at a minimum, it may be
a matter of necessity to use cash flow. (10)
In this paper, we seek to answer the question of why investors
focus more on earnings rather than cash flow in valuing stocks. The
practice of deviating from cash flow pricing can be explained by
rational herding. (11) In any society, it seems rational for people to
follow others before them even if the action is against their own
belief. We find evidence in this paper to indicate that stock prices
generally follow short-term earnings, but exceptions for cash flow
pricing are also ubiquitous. A likely and logical explanation is that
when current cash flow is a better predictor for future cash flow,
investors simply use it as the best instrument to derive the present
value of future cash flows. In the end, the choice to value stocks with
either earnings or cash flow is still a rational one.
Rational Bubbles
Considering the intense focus on reported earnings, we begin to
entertain some rational explanations as to why this behavior is so
prevalent. Since the behavior of earnings fixation may be a result of a
systematic, erroneous decision made by the entire market, we also
consider the possibility of "rational herding." An abbreviated
way to describe herding is that individuals behave similarly but not
because they receive similar information. Instead, people herd due to
the inaccurate information they receive, imperfect expectations they
form, or as discussed before, the suboptimal incentive package by which
they are compensated.
Therefore, whether to follow others' actions (i.e., using
earnings to value stocks) is a result of the evaluation of payoff
externalities. An externality, in layman's terms, is the public
impact of a private action. Actions made by decision makers will have a
spillover impact, positive or negative, on the others surrounding them.
This is referred to as "the neighborhood effect" (15). For
example, people who do not pay taxes receive the same benefits (e.g.,
roads, national security, etc.) as people who pay taxes.
Within this context, when performance measurement is conducted on a
relative basis, the decision of acquiring a piece of costly information
will also be determined on a relative basis. The payoff of a costly
information acquisition is thus evaluated based on the expectation or
the observation of what others are doing. Specifically, when investors
decide which type of information to acquire in their investment process,
they will consider the reaction of, or the lack of, other investors when
making their choice. (16) For instance, if no one uses cash flow in
valuation and stock prices do not react to this choice, there is no
payoff for investing in the acquisition of such information regarding
cash flow. Even though cash flow may be a "true" piece of
information, investors will not acquire it if it is costly given that no
other peers do. If they do choose to acquire the information, it will
not be used to differentiate the measurement of performance. (17)
IL EMPIRICAL PROCEDUES
For the purpose of the paper, we identify a sample of U.S. public
stocks for the time period 1970-2008. Firms included in this study must
be contained in CRSP, COMPUSTAT, and DataStream databases. The selection
process is intended to preserve as many firms as possible. The
components of the valuation metrics used in this study include earnings
per share, book value per share, dividend per share, sales per share,
and cash flow per share. Table 1 presents the total number of firms, the
actual number of firms used in this study, and the data availability of
each of the five valuation metrics over various sample sub-periods. For
example, during the period of 2000-2008, there were a total of 7,753
firms, live of dead, jointly covered by CRSP, COMPUSTAT, and DataStream,
7,125 firms with a least one of the five valuation metrics reported were
selected for this study, and the three databases included earnings per
share for 78% of the sample firms, book value per share 75%, sales per
share 72%, dividend per share 89%, and cash flow per share 65%. Since
the data availability implicitly reflects the bias of each valuation
metric, it is not surprising that next to dividend per share, earnings
per share has the most coverage, while cash flow per share has the
least.
Valuation Metrics
The fair stock price is usually modeled with valuation metrics such
as cash flow per share, earnings per share, book value per share, sales
per share, and dividend per share. Book value per share is included as a
control variable to account for the cross-sectional scale differences in
stock price levels. Assuming there are no changes in the degree of debt
financing, the stock price and the book value per share at time t can be
defined by the following:
[P.sub.t]=P/B([BPS.sub.t]) (1)
where [BPS.sub.t] = [BPS.sub.t-1] + [EPS.sub.t] - [DPS.sub.t], and
P/B is the market to book multiple paying for future growth. If a stable
P/B multiple is applied to a homogeneous group of stocks, the
cross-sectional difference in [P.sub.t] can be explained by its book
value per share as shown by Equation (1). Although the relationship
between [BPS.sub.t] and [P.sub.t] becomes a little messier if the debt
ratio varies over time or the fair P/B ratio is stochastic, the positive
relationship between [BPS.sub.t] and [P.sub.t] is still preserved.
Sales per share is often more meaningful than earnings per share in
terms of valuation for several reasons. Under economic distress,
top-line growth is considered more informative than bottom-line growth
as an indicator for predicting future economic activity. Furthermore,
the economically sensitive or cyclical industries are most affected by
the revenue growth outlook. There is a school of valuation models that
relies mainly on sales growth, and the sales franchise model is a good
example. The use of sales is also more relevant in homogeneous
industries, such as commodity, material, and basic industries, since
their profit margins are similar. Lastly, sales is also used over
earnings or cash flow as a matter of convenience. Negative fundamentals
do not compute well in a traditional valuation process and most
investors don't know how to deal with them. As a passive
alternative, when earnings or cash flow is negative, sales per share is
often used as a logical substitute.
The justification for using dividend in the process of valuation is
even more obvious. From an irrelevant dividend in the Modigliani-Miller
Proposition I, a bird-in-hand dividend, to dividend changes that signal
future earnings and cash flow, modern corporate finance theories are
mainly built around the different treatment of dividends. (18) In
summary, the following valuation metrics are tested in Equation (2):
[P.sub.it] = [[beta].sub.1][EPS.sub.it] +
[[beta].sub.2][BPS.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.3][SPS.sub.it] +
[[beta].sub.4][DPS.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.5][CFS.sub.it] (2)
and [summation] [[beta].sub.j] = 1, where [P.sub.it] is stock price
at time t; [EPS.sub.it] is earnings per share at time t; [BPS.sub.it] is
book value per share at time t; [SPS.sub.it] is sales per share at time
t; [DPS.sub.it] is dividend per share at time; [CFS.sub.it] is cash flow
per share at time t; and [[beta].sub.j]'s are the parameters to be
estimated.
To measure the relative impact of each value metric on stock price,
every variable in Equation (2) is first standardized conventionally by
subtracting the observed value from its mean and then divided by
standard deviation. Thus, the distribution of each value metric is
assumed to be normally distributed, with zero mean and unit variance.
The standardization procedure also eliminates biases resulting from the
scale differences in each variable. Using the lower case to denote the
standardized value for each variable and adding a disturbance term
([[epsilon].sub.it]), Equation (2) can be expressed as:
[P.sub.tt] = [[beta].sub.1][eps.sub.it] +
[[beta].sub.2][bps.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.3][sps.sub.it] +
[[beta].sub.4][dps.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.5][cfs.sub.it] +
[[epsilon].sub.it] (3)
The OLS regression on Equation (3) with the condition [summation]
[[beta].sub.j] = 1 provides an estimate of the parameter [[beta].sub.j]
that can be directly compared for its relative contribution power.
We first estimate Equation (3) on a cross-sectional basis for each
month in the sample period. The monthly estimates are averaged over 468
monthly OLS regressions. In Table 2(A), the mean estimates of
[[beta].sub.j] are presented. The results indicate that earnings per
share contributes 35%, the largest among all value metrics, in
determining stock price, while cash flow per share 21%, with both
significant at the 1% level. The chi-square test for the difference
among the estimates of [[beta].sub.j] is also significant at the 1%
level.
A reduced version of Equation (3) given by Equation (4) below
allows a comparison between the relative contribution of earnings and
cash flow:
[P.sub.it] =[[beta].sub.1][eps.sub.it]+[[beta].sub.5][cfs.sub.it]+[[delta].sub.it] (4)
The results of the estimation of Equation (4) are reported in Table
2(B). A statistically larger impact from earnings (68%), compared to
that from cash flow (32%), confirms the inference from Table 2(A). The
weight on earnings is almost twice as on cash flow. The above results
indicate that stock price was mainly affected by earnings per share over
the 34-year time period.
Although stock prices are generally determined by earnings, we find
many exceptions to the rule, that is stocks are at times priced based on
cash flow. However, we cannot resist the temptation to ask why average
investors choose to "go through the charade" of earnings
following. Why do they behave differently than their own beliefs say
they should? If the majority of market participants rely on earnings
during most time periods, should we reexamine the notion of pricing
stocks using the present value of cash flows? Of course, without a
direct, ex ante, laboratory cause-and-effect test, we cannot answer this
question. One encouraging aspect of this study, though, is that a
significant portion of stock pricing is based on cash flow, as predicted
by several rational explanations.
III. CONCLUSION
Stock prices are mainly affected by short-term earnings. However,
in this study we find that cash flow pricing is next frequently used--a
practice appears to collide with modern finance theories. It seems too
trivial to conclude that people are simply irrational. Instead, the
evidence is consistent with the argument that investors tend to follow
others' decisions, and for whatever reason, feel compelled to
conform to the majority even though their private information suggests
they behave otherwise. This may be a reflection of human's
fundamental need to belong in a society.
ENDNOTES
(1.) Fernandez (2013) uses Alpha Commerce as an example to show why
a company could have positive net income but negative cash flows.
(2.) See Hanke (2004).
(3.) See Ma (2009a).
(4.) Using a relative P/E model, the relationship between the
implied growth rate and the number of compounding years can be derived.
In this model, an annual growth rate of 80% for 10 years is the same as
an annual growth rate of 42% for 20 years.
(5.) For more information, see Mizik (2010).
(6.) See Yen (2008).
(7.) See Cheng, Subramanyam, and Zhang (2007).
(8.) Chen, Matsumoto, and Rajgopal (2009) find a -3.6% stock price
reaction during the three-day announcement period for firms stopping
earnings guidance.
(9.) See Ma (2009b).
(10.) This is also in line with what Warren Buffet was quoted as
saying at the beginning of this paper.
(11.) See Devenow and Welch (1996) for more information on rational
herding.
(12.) For example, Campbell and Shiller (1988).
(13.) See Ma (2009b).
(14.) Even though this may be a promising argument, a tempting, but
still unclear, question is who started the information cascade.
(15.) Another example of "the neighborhood effect" is
reported by Hong, Kubik, and Stein (2005) who discover that a mutual
fund manager is more likely to buy (or sell) a particular stock in any
quarter if other managers in the same city are buying (or selling) that
same stock.
(16.) The model developed by Hershleifer, Subrahmanyam, and Titman
(1994) implies that, under some conditions, investors will focus only on
a subset of stocks (herding), while neglecting other stocks with
identical exogenous characteristics.
(17.) See Brennan (1990) and Hirshleifer et al. (1994) for more
information.
(18.) See Modigliani and Miller (1963).
(19.) The evidence also suggests the need of a different valuation
model for stocks of negative fundamentals.
(20.) This is not the same as, at what level, the stock fair value
should be.
REFERENCES
Bikhchandani, S., D. Hirshleifer, and I. Welch, "A Theory of
Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Information
Cascades." Journal of Political Economy, 1992, 100(5), 992-1026.
Block, S., "A Study of Financial Analysts: Practice and
Theory." Financial Analysts Journal, July/August 1999, 55(4),
86-92.
Brennan, M.J., "Latent Assets." Journal of Finance, 1990,
45(3), 709-730.
Campbell, J. and R. Shiller, "Stock Prices, Earnings, and
Expected Dividends." Journal of Finance, 1988, 43(3), 661-676.
Chen, S., D. Matsumoto, and S. Rajgopal, "Is Silence Golden?
An Empirical Analysis of Firms that Stop Giving Quarterly Earnings
Guidance." Journal of Accounting and Economics, February 2011,
51(1&2), 134-150.
Cheng, M., K.R. Subramanyam, and Y. Zhang, "Earnings Guidance
and Managerial Myopia," working paper, 2007.
Damodaran, A., Investment Valuation: Tools and Techniques for
Determining the Value of any Asset. 2nd edition. Wiley Finance, 2002.
Devenow, A. and I. Welch, "Rational Herding in Financial
Economics." European Economic Review, 1996, 40(3-5), 603-615.
Fernandez, P., "Cash Flow is a Fact. Net Income is just an
Opinion," SSRN working paper, July 2013.
Hanke, S., "Where's the Cash," Forbes, 2004 (April
12), retrieved from http://www.forbes.com/forbes/2004/0412/230.html.
Hirshleifer, D., A. Subrahmanyam, and S. Titman, "Security
Analysis and Trading Patterns when Some Investors Receive Information
before Others." Journal of Financial Economics, 1994,49(5),
1665-1698.
Hong, H., J. Kubik, and J. Stein, "The Neighbor's
Portfolio: Word-of-mouth Effects in the Holdings and Trades of Money
Managers." Journal of Finance, 2005, 60(6), 2801-2824.
Ibbotson, R. Z. Chen, D. Kim, and W. Hu, "Liquidity as an
Investment Style." Financial Analysts Journal, 2013, 69(3), 1-15.
Ma, K. C., "Negative Earnings Stocks." Working paper,
2009a.
Ma, K. C., "How Do Private Firms Disclose Information?"
Working paper, 2009b, Stetson University.
Merrill Lynch & Co., Quantitative Viewpoint: Institutional
Factor Surveys. Global Securities, Research & Economics Group,
1989-2001.
Mizik, N., "The Theory and Practice of Myopic
Management." Journal of Marketing Research, August 2010, 47(4),
594-611.
Modigliani, F., and M. Miller, "Corporate Income Taxes and the
Cost of Capital: A Correction." American Economic Review, 1963, 53
(3): 433-443.
Porter, M.E., "Capital Choices: The Causes and Cures of
Business Myopia." Research Report to the U.S. Government's
Council on Competitiveness, 1992, Washington D.C.
Subramanyam, K. and M. Venkatachalam, "The Role of Book Value
in Equity Valuation: Does the Stock Variable Merely Proxy for Relevant
Past Flows?" Working paper, June 1998.
Yen, Airu, "The Influence of Myopic R&D Investment
Decisions on Earning Growth." Working paper, September 10, 2008.
K. C. Ma (a) (*), R. Daniel Pace (b), Jud Stryker (c)
(a) Stetson University, kcma@stetson.edu
(b) University of West Florida, dpace@uwf.edu
(c) Stetson University, jstryker@stetson. edu
(*) The author appreciates the discussions with comments from the
participants in the SOBA Research Seminar at Stetson University. The
author also gratefully acknowledges the support from the SOBA Foundation
of Stetson University. All disclaimers apply.
Table 1
Sample description and data availability
Time Average No. of Earnings Book Value Sales
Period No. US Stocks Per Share Per Share Per Share
Stocks (a) Used (b)
1970-1979 1,456 1,025 52% 48% 43%
1980-1989 4,218 3,172 67% 55% 51%
1990-1999 6,715 6,015 71% 67% 64%
2000-2008 7,753 7,125 78% 75% 72%
Time Dividend Cash
Period Per Share Flow Per
Share
1970-1979 67% 31%
1980-1989 72% 51%
1990-1999 81% 62%
2000-2008 89% 65%
(a) All US firms, live or dead, jointly covered by CRSP, COMPUSTAT, and
DATASTREAM.
(b) Firms with valid values for at least 1 of the 5 variables.
Table 2
Stock valuation metrics (1974-2008)
Tested [[beta].sub.1] [[beta].sub.2] [[beta].sub.3] [[beta].sub.4]
Sample
(A) 0.35 (a) 0.05 (a) 0.29 (a) 0.10 (a)
(.0007) (.0008) (.0008) (.0008)
(B) 0.68 (a) - - -
(.0007)
Chi-Square Tests: H0: [beta]1= [beta]2= [beta]3= [beta]4= [beta]5
H0: [beta]1= [beta]5
Tested [[beta].sub.5] F-Value R-Square N
Sample
(A) 0.21 (a) 2018 0.45 2845
(.0009)
(B) 0.32 (a) 1672 0.40 3517
(.0007)
(A) (a) [p.sub.it] = [[beta].sub.1][eps.sub.it]
+ [[beta].sub.2][bps.sub.it] + [[beta].sub.3][sps.sub.it] +
[[beta].sub.4][dps.sub.it] +[[beta].sub.5][cfs.sub.it] where
[[beta].sub.1] + [[beta].sub.2] + [[beta].sub.3] + [[beta].sub.4] +
[[beta].sub.5] = 1
(B) (b) [p.sub.it] = [[beta].sub.1][eps.sub.it] +
[[beta].sub.5][cfs.sub.it], where [[beta].sub.1] + [[beta].sub.5] = 1
(a) Significant at the 1% level; Mean standard errors are in the
parentheses.
(a) Equations (A) and (B) are first estimated cross-sectional on a
monthly basis. All beta coefficients are averaged across over the 456
monthly regressions. The statistics including F-value, R-square, number
of observations and the standard errors are means over each regression.
Note: The beta coefficient is significantly different from each other
at the 1% level.