The effect of the quality of rumors on market yields.
Spiegel, Uriel ; Tavor, Tchai ; Templeman, Joseph 等
I. INTRODUCTION
During the last decade the world has witnessed the opening of
literally countless websites, chat rooms and forums providing
information on financial markets. In most cases opinions, estimates and
predictions of investors and private analysts can best be described as
merely rumors and not necessarily as objective and reliable information
analyzed by experts.
A decade ago most rumors were purely speculative and unreliable
nevertheless their effect on stock prices and on abnormal returns was
often substantial. Sites deal with rumors of all kinds: true or false
(see Spiegel et al., 2010), single or multiple etc. Based on the wealth
of data that has become available in recent years we may provide answers
to additional questions: How much does each kind of rumor affect
abnormal returns prior to the event day (due to a "leakage
process"), on the event day, and afterwards. What is the different
impact of initial rumors that are later proven to be true and those that
have turned out to be untrue? These issues are discussed below where we
adopt an event study approach to examine them, based on data sets of the
Israeli stock market.
The common well-known approach regarding financial market
performance is the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) that states:
"Stock prices fully reflect all relevant up-to-date information at
any given time". However we find in our empirical study that
investors often find opportunities to achieve abnormal returns. Such
instances represent an anomaly in the market that contradicts the EMH.
In order to prove the existence of such anomalies we use data sets from
the most authoritative and important Israeli sites: spouser.co.il,
dbursa.com, and trading4living.com, since they are the largest financial
gossip and rumor sites in Israel. We focus on published rumors in those
sites and investigate their effects on the selected stocks'
performance using data sets of events prior to and after the rumor(s)
becoming public knowledge.
The latest literature deals with particular rumors transmitted by
way of the Internet, as discussed by Werner and Murray (2004). They
found that a positive rumor usually leads to a positive return on the
following trading day, while a negative message leads to a negative
return on the following trading day. Kiymaz (2001) examines good and bad
rumors and finds that the good rumors generate abnormal returns
beginning four days before their publication, while the effect of
negative rumors begins only after publication.
Wysocki (1999) found increasing returns and trade values the day
following the rumor, especially when it is published at night while
markets are closed. Tumarkin and Whitelaw (2001) examined the influence
of Internet financial announcements on stock yields and trade volume by
branches based on only one site. Their main conclusion is that we cannot
predict volume and yield by branch type.
In this sense we believe that our results are uniquely accurate
since we base our analysis and results on data sets that include three
different and independent sites for the years 2005-2007, a period during
which financial rumors had become very popular and widespread.
In our previous work (Spiegel et al., 2010), we explored the
financial market's response to reliable and true information as
well as false ones, and its impact on changes in yields before and after
the event. Here we continue the investigation by analyzing and
estimating the impact of a single rumor and multiple rumors on yields,
as well as the effects of initial and subsequent rumors on those yields.
II. SAMPLE DATA
On March 1st 2007 we looked at three sites: Sponsor, The Bursa, and
Trading for Living, searching for general rumors concerning various
stocks trading on the Israeli stock market. We selected rumors that
predicted higher expected prices than the current market price of those
stocks. These kinds of rumors are different from the rumors used by
Lerman (2011) who examines rumors regarding items of financial accounts
such as balance sheets, or periodic financial reports etc. and their
effect on investors. Those we classified as good or optimistic rumors.
We use only positive rumors in contrast to a recent work of Tetlock et
al. (2008) who analyzed published negative statements about companies
and their effect on performance. They used the printed media rather than
Internet sites and related to words such as risk or uncertainty that
were published in those news media. We checked 1021, 750, and 302 rumors
from Sponsor site, Bursa and Trading for Living, respectively, and
distinguished between 1227 initial (first time) published rumors that
had not been published during the previous 3 months and 846 repeat
(subsequent) rumors (472 out of the 846 were repeated at least twice).
The rumors appeared in the three sites between January 1, 2005 and March
1, 2007. Daily data are used for all companies in the sample.
The market portfolio index was composed of 958 stocks, where the
weight of each stock in the portfolio was determined by its market value
divided by the total market value of all 958 stocks. In three respects
our sample is unique. First, we used simultaneously three Internet sites
making it easier and more accurate to determine that a given rumor is
new, based on the dates that they appeared in those three sites. Second,
we used a very large sample of more than 2000 rumors.
Finally we used Israelis data that to the best of our knowledge was
not used previously by others. Israelis who live under a high degree of
risk and uncertainty in an unstable environment are big rumor consumers
of all kinds of rumors, including optimistic rumors, and the results
below confirm this.
III. THE METHODOLOGY OF ABNORMAL RETURNS
To examine the effect of a rumor on a stock's return we adopt
the old approach of "event study" also known as Residual
Analysis. In the classical literature the gap between the "Actual
Return" and the "Normal Return" is defined as Abnormal
Return (AR):
[AR.sub.it] = [R.sub.it] - [[alpha].sub.i] -
[[[beta].sub.i][R.sub.mt]] - [[xi].sub.it] (1)
where [AR.sub.it] is the abnormal return of stock i in day t,
[R.sub.it] is the actual return of stock i in day t, [R.sub.mt] is the
return of the market portfolio in period t, [[alpha].sub.i] and
[[beta].sub.i] are the regression parameters that have to be estimated
for each stock, and [[xi].sub.it] is the regression error of stock i at
period t.
One of the most popular techniques in analyzing stock behavior and
their responses to events or announcements over time is that of tracking
both the Average Abnormal Return (AAR) and the Cumulative Average
Abnormal Return (CAAR).
[AAR.sub.t] = [1/N] [[N.summation over (i=1)]] [AR.sub.it] (2)
where N represents the number of stocks in the sample.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
The CAAR is the summation of abnormal returns over a given period.
The period starts at point [T.sub.1] where information regarding the
site's opening occurs and ends at a time point [T.sub.n].
IV. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
During recent years the use of the Internet has accelerated and
today it plays an important role in our daily life as well as in that of
the financial markets, and therefore rumors published on the Internet
affect investor behavior. In this section we first examine the effect of
single rumors versus multiple rumors using the market model.
We study how the number of rumors affects market prices by checking
the price fluctuations of 755 companies where only one rumor was
published and compare those fluctuations to those of 472 companies with
multiple rumors.
Table 1, Table 2, and Figure 1 describe the returns for both kinds
of companies (i.e., companies with a history of only one rumor vs.
multi-rumor companies) for the sample days of (-29, 30), i.e., 29 days
before up until 30 days after the day of the event, based on the market
model.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
From the data set we see that in the first 24 days the AAR is not
significantly different from zero. During the following 5 days before
the rumor event the AAR is significantly higher without any significant
differences between the one rumor case and the multiple rumor case. This
shows that investors can achieve abnormal returns using internal
information in both the single and multiple rumors cases.
Prices also continue to rise on the day of the published rumor, and
the AAR also increases on the rumor day. The AAR increases for stocks
with one rumor by 2.117 (t=5.679) and in the case of multiple rumors by
2.555 (t=5.637). A day later the ARR continues to increase, in the
latter case by an additional 1.236 (t=2.728), while in the single rumor
case there is no change on the following day. In our view this indicates
the way investors evaluate and differentiate between types of rumors,
thus acquiring abnormal returns in the multiple rumors case. These
abnormal returns can occur as a result of an additional single rumor
that might be published later. In the following 29 days after the first
rumor comes out the CAAR remains more or less constant in the case of
multiple rumors, while for the single rumor case CAAR declines. This in
our opinion indicates an overreaction of investors to rumors before and
after the event, therefore since expectations decline we may expect a
reduction in the CAAR.
From the above we can conclude that investors respond significantly
over time to multiple rumors since multiple rumors generate expectations
for further information. In some sense our results are similar to
several recent works such as: Sabherwal et al. (2008) who show the
positive effects of quantities of rumors on stocks prices, or the work
of Barber and Odean (2008) where they show positive effects of rumors
and public adverting on the willingness of investors to buy stocks. On
the other hand we find works of Hirshleifer et al. (2008) and Malmendier
and Shanthikumar (2007) who claim that information published in several
networks had no significant influences on investors' decisions. The
second comparison deals with Initial Rumors versus Subsequent Rumors.
The influence of a rumor depends very strongly on its timeliness
and content (i.e., whether it contains new information or not). Thus an
initial rumor being new and in some cases innovative, may generate a
stronger effect than a subsequent rumor, whose influence may be weaker.
The comparison between the "initial" rumor and the
"subsequent" rumor is discussed in this section for days (-29,
+30) based again on the market model.
The results introduced and illustrated in Table 3, Table 4, and
Figure 2 are based on 1227 new rumors vs. 472 subsequent rumors that are
compared in terms of the returns behavior of CAAR. We find that
"initial" rumors were leaked about 5 days before the
publicized rumor (4.413) (t=4.889) while the leakage in the case of
subsequent rumors occurs about two days before (1.811) (t=2.824).
Insiders also respond to initial rumors, since on the day of the rumor
AAR increases by 2.354 (t=5.831), while in the case of a subsequent
rumor AAR increases by 1.918 (t=4.233).
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The difference therefore is not significant between the two types
of rumors on the day of the event. However, a day after the initial
rumor the AAR does not change, while in the other case the AAR is
reduced by -0.887 (t=1.957). In the following 29 days no difference can
be observed, which indicates that only on the day of the event does the
subsequent rumor generate an over-reaction on the part of investors, and
therefore a day later price reductions can already be observed. This
does not occur in the case of an initial rumor, which means that from
the investors' point of view an initial rumor contains more
reliable information than a subsequent rumor.
V. CONCLUSIONS
In comparing between a many rumors company (a company with more
than one rumor concerning a future event relating to the company) and a
single rumor company (a company with only one rumor as to a future
event) we can say that there is no significant difference between the
two cases in the period before the event. This continues to be the case
on the day that the rumor enters the domain of general public knowledge.
However, the day after the rumor becomes generally known we observe an
increase in the AAR for the many rumors case but no change for the
single rumor case. This shows that after the rumor is published
investors are able to differentiate between the rumors and thereby
acquire an abnormal return in the multi-rumor case. A possible
explanation for this might be the expectations generated in the minds of
investors regarding the possibility that additional rumors might also be
published in the future.
Over the next 29 days we see that the CAAR is maintained for the
multi-rumor firms but declines for the single rumor firms. The decline
of the CAAR for the single rumor firms indicates an overreaction on the
part of investors with respect to the period prior to the event as well
as a decline in expectations that the rumor will in fact be actualized.
We can conclude that over time investors react more strongly in the
multi-rumor case due to the expectation of receiving further information
in the future.
We also investigated the differences between a first and second
rumor. The results show that a first rumor tends to leak five days
before the event, while a second rumor started leaking only two days
before the event. From this it can be concluded that investors with
access to inside information react more vigorously to initial
information than to further information that comes later. By comparing
the two types of rumors we conclude that the initial or first rumors are
of higher quality i.e., contain more new information than subsequent or
second rumors.
These results are important and useful for asset holders, as well
as for financial and portfolio managers, since it gives them the tools
to understand and weigh how the rumors that reach their ears will tend
to play out in terms of the possible responses of the investing public.
It will also enable them to differentiate between the impacts of
multiple vs. single rumors and to take into account the probable
immediate price fluctuations that these rumors will cause as well as
possible follow up price fluctuations. The money manager will therefore
have a good tool for deciding whether to swim with the tide and follow
the crowd or whether it might be better to swim upstream against the
crowd. Thus the results of our research are interesting both from the
theoretical/academic point of view as well as being very useful from a
practical point of view.
REFERENCES
Barber B.M., T. Odean, 2008, "All That Glitters: The Effect of
Attention and News on the Buying Behavior of Individual and
Institutional Investors", Review of Financial Studies 21(2):
785-818.
Hirshleifer, D., J.N. Myers, L.A. Myers, and S.H. Teoh, 2008,
"Do Individual Investors Cause Post-Earnings Announcement Drift?
Direct Evidence from Personal Trades", The Accounting Review 83(6):
1521-1550.
Kiymaz H., 2001, "The Effects of Stock Market Rumors on Stock
Prices: Evidence from an Emerging Market", Journal of Multinational
Financial Management, 11(1), 105-15.
Lerman A., 2011, "Individual Investors' Attention to
Accounting Information: Message Board Discussions", working paper.
Malmendier, U. and D. Shanthikumar, 2007, "Are Small Investors
Naive about Incentives?" Journal of Financial Economics, 85(2):
457-489.
Sabherwal S., S. K. Sarkar, and Y.Zhang, 2008, "Online Talk:
Does It Matter?" Managerial Finance, 34(6), 423-436.
Spiegel, U., T.Tavor, and J. Templeman, 2010, "The Effects of
Rumors on Financial Market Efficiency", Applied Economics Letters,
17(15), 1461-1464.
Tetlock, P.C., Saar-Tsechansky, M & Macskassy, S., 2008,
"More than Words: Quantifying Language to Measure Firms'
Fundamentals", Journal of Finance, 63, 1437-1467.
Tumarkin R, and R. F. Whitelaw, 2001, "News or Noise? Internet
Message Board Activity and Stock Prices", Financial Analysts
Journal, 57, 41-51.
Werner A. and F. Murray Z., 2004, "Is All That Talk Just
Noise? The Information Content of Internet Stock Message Boards",
Journal of Finance, 59(3), 1259-94.
Wysocki P., 1999, "Cheap Talk on the Web: The Determinants of
Postings on Stock Message Boards", Working Paper, University of
Michigan Business School, November 1999.
Uriel Spiegel (a), Tchai Tavor (b), Joseph Templeman (c)
(a) Department of Management, Bar-Ilan University, and Visiting
Professor Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania spiegeu@biu. ac. il
(b) Department of Economics and Management, Yisrael Valley College,
Israel tchai2000@yahoo. com
(c) The College of Business Administration, Rishon LiTzion, Israel
ytempelh@013net.net
Table 1
AAR and CAAR behavior for 755 single rumors
Time Interval AAR (%) PAAR (%) TAAR CAAR (%) TCAAR
-29,-6 -0.047 46 -0.125 -1.119 -0.613
-5,-1 0.795 61 2.132 3.974 4.768
-3 0.567 61 1.521 0.567 1.521
-2 0.867 70 2.327 0.867 2.327
-1 2.124 80 5.698 2.124 5.698
0 2.117 81 5.679 2.117 5.679
+1 0.063 51 0.169 0.063 0.169
+1,+30 -0.126 46 -0.339 -3.793 -1.858
Table 2
AAR and CAAR behavior for 472 multi rumors
Time Interval AAR (%) PAAR (%) TAAR CAAR (%) TCAAR
-29,-6 -0.037 48 -0.081 -0.884 -0.398
-5,-1 0.889 64 1.961 4.443 4.384
-3 0.933 65 2.060 0.933 2.060
-2 1.091 74 2.408 1.091 2.408
-1 2.146 76 4.736 2.146 4.736
0 2.555 86 5.637 2.555 5.637
+1 1.236 63 2.728 1.236 2.728
+1,+30 0.049 43 0.109 1.476 0.594
Table 3
AAR and CAAR behavior for 1227 initial rumors
Time Interval AAR (%) PAAR (%) TAAR CAAR (%) TCAAR
-29,-6 -0.059 47 -0.147 -1.426 -0.721
-5,-1 0.883 62 2.186 4.413 4.889
-3 0.749 63 1.855 0.749 1.855
-2 0.958 71 2.373 0.958 2.373
-1 2.135 78 5.289 2.135 5.289
0 2.354 83 5.831 2.354 5.831
+1 0.563 55 1.395 0.563 1.395
+1,+30 -0.046 45 -0.114 -1.375 -0.622
Table 4
AAR and CAAR behavior for 472 subsequent rumors
Time Interval AAR (%) PAAR (%) TAAR CAAR (%) TCAAR
-29,-6 -0.009 44 -0.020 -0.213 -0.096
-5,-1 0.453 53 0.999 2.264 2.234
-3 0.547 56 1.206 0.547 1.206
-2 0.899 59 1.983 0.899 1.983
-1 0.912 63 2.011 0.912 2.011
0 1.918 68 4.233 1.918 4.233
+1 -0.887 42 -1.957 -0.887 -1.957
+1,+30 -0.089 46 -0.197 -2.676 -1.078