An intertemporal capital asset pricing model under incomplete information.
Bellalah, Mondher ; Wu, Zhen
I. INTRODUCTION
The capital asset pricing model of Sharpe-Lintner-Mossin, CAPM, is
regarded as one of the most common developments in modern capital market
theory. The CAPM model is still subject to theoretical and empirical
criticism. In fact, since the model assumes the mean-variance criterion,
it is subject to all the well-known theoretical objections to this
criterion.
Merton (1973) develops an equilibrium model of the capital market.
He shows that portfolio behavior for an intertemporal maximizer will be
different when he faces a changing investment opportunity set instead of
a constant one. Merton's intertemporal model is based on consumer
investor behavior and captures effects, which would never appear in a
static model. These effects cause significant differences in
specification of the equilibrium relationship among asset yields that
appears in this model and the classical model.
By relaxing the main assumptions used in the CAPM, the model has
been extended to more general economies. Merton's (1973) model
states that the expected excess return on any asset is given by a
"multi-beta" version of the CAPM with the number of betas
being equal to one plus the number of state variables.
In the same context, Breeden (1979) shows that Merton's
multi-beta pricing equation can collapse into a single beta equation where the expected excess return on any security, is proportional to its
beta, with respect to aggregate consumption alone. Since the acquisition
of information and its dissemination are central activities in finance,
and in capital markets, Merton (1987) develops a model of capital market
equilibrium with incomplete information, CAPMI, to provide some insights
into the behavior of security prices. He also studies the equilibrium
structure of asset prices and its connection with empirical anomalies in
financial markets.
Merton's (1987) model is a two period model of capital market
equilibrium in a costly economy where each investor has information
about only a subset of the available securities. The key behavioral
assumption is that an investor considers including security S in his
portfolio only if he has some information on this security. Information
costs have two components: the costs of gathering and processing data,
and the costs of information transmission. This problem is related to
the literature on the principal-agent problem, to the signaling models,
to the differential information models and to the theory of generic and
neglected stocks.
Merton's model, the CAPMI, is an extension of the CAPM to a
context of incomplete information. As Merton explains "Even modest
recognition of institutional structures and information costs can go a
long toward explaining financial behavior ...", the model also
gives a general method for discounting future cash flows under
uncertainty. Note that under complete information, the CAPMI model
reduces to the standard CAPM.
Financial models based on complete information might be inadequate
to capture the complexity of rationality in action. Some factors and
constraints, like entry into the dealer business are not costless and
may influence the short run behavior of security prices. Hence, most
models developed in financial economics do not explicitly provide a
functional role for the complicated and dynamic system of dealers,
market makers and traders.
Besides, the treatment of information and its associated costs play
a central role in capital markets. If an investor does not know about a
trading opportunity, he will not act to implement an appropriate
strategy to benefit from it. However, the investor must determine if
potential gains are sufficient to warrant the costs of implementing the
strategy.
From Merton's model (1987), it appears that taking into
account the effect of incomplete information on the equilibrium price of
an asset is similar to applying an additional discount rate to this
asset's future cash flows. In fact, the expected return on the
asset is given by the appropriate discount rate that must be applied to
its future cash flows.
In that context, the investor's set is incomplete when it does
not contain full information on expected rate of return and return
variability. In the Merton's framework, no stock is held on which
the investor does not have complete information. This has the potential
to explain why individual and institutional investors do spend huge
amounts of money in research and development activities, securities and
information analysis before deciding to include an asset in their
portfolios.
Merton (1987) adopts most of the assumptions of the original CAPM
and relaxes the assumption of equal information across investors.
Besides, he assumes that investors hold only securities of which they
are aware. This assumption is motivated by the observation that
portfolios held by actual investors include only a small fraction of all
available traded securities.
In Merton's (1987) model, the expected returns increase with
systematic risk, firm-specific risk, and relative market value. The
expected returns decrease with relative size of the firm's investor
base, referred to in Merton's model as the "degree of investor
recognition".
The model shows that an increase in the size of the firm's
investor base will lower investors' expected return and, all else
equal, will increase the market value of the firm's shares. The
main distinction between Merton's model and the standard CAPM is
that investors invest only in the securities about which they are
"aware". This assumption is referred to as incomplete
information. However, the more general implication is that securities
markets are segmented.
Merton's model is based on the assumption that there are
several factors in addition to incomplete information that may explain
this behavior for individuals and institutions. Hence, the presence of
prudent-investing laws and traditions and other regulatory constraints
can rule out investment in a particular firm by some investors. Using
this assumption, Merton shows that the expected return depend on other
factors in addition to market risk.
The main intuition behind this result is that the absence of a
firm-specific risk component in the CAPM comes about because such risk
can be eliminated (through diversification) and is not priced. It
appears from Merton's model that the effect of incomplete
information on expected returns is greater the higher the firm's
specific risk and the higher the weight of the asset in the
investor's portfolio. The effect of Merton's non-market risk
factors on expected returns depend on whether the asset is widely held
or not.
The intuition behind Merton's model is that investors consider
only a part of the opportunity set, and that full diversification is not
possible and that firm specific risk is priced in equilibrium. (1)
We describe in this paper the Capital market structure, asset value
and the economic model. We use the classical dynamic programming
principle to obtain the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation. This allows to
derive the equilibrium market equation for all investors. Two cases are
studied: the constant investment opportunity set and the general case.
Our analysis derives the extended equilibrium market equation and
the security market line of the classical capital asset pricing model of
Merton (1987) in continuous time. We provide the continuous time analog
to Merton's (1987) security market line. The assumption of a
constant investment opportunity set represents a sufficient condition
for investors to behave as if they were single-period maximizers. It is
also sufficient for the equilibrium return relationship specified by
Merton's (1987) simple capital asset pricing model to obtain. We
show that a generalization of Merton's (1973)
'multi-beta' asset pricing model obtains in this economy in
the presence of shadow costs of incomplete information.
We derive the corresponding equilibrium market equation and the
continuous time security market line of the intertemporal capital asset
pricing model with incomplete information.
Our analysis provides two central results. The first result
indicates that in the presence of a riskless asset and information costs
regarding the n risky assets in the economy, (i) there exists a unique
pair of efficient portfolio known as mutual funds, and (ii) the return
distribution on the risky fund is log-normal.
The second result is a "Three Funds" theorem. It shows
that all individuals in our economy within information uncertainty,
regardless of their preferences, may attain their optimal portfolio
positions by investing in at most 3 funds. These funds may be chosen to
be: (i) the instantaneously riskless asset; (ii) the asset having the
highest correlation with the state variable; and (iii) the market
portfolio.
The structure of the paper is as follows. Section II presents our
intertemporal model and the optimal portfolio under incomplete
information. Section III provides some explicit optimal solutions for
the case of CRRA utility functions.
II. THE ECONOMIC MODEL AND THE OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO UNDER INCOMPLETE
INFORMATION
A. Capital Market Structure, Asset Value and the Economic Model
The model is based on the standard assumptions of a perfect market
and continuous trading. Prices of assets follow Ito processes
(continuous and not differentiable). Under the assumptions of continuous
trading and a Markov structure, the first two moments of the
distributions are sufficient statistics. It is assumed that there are n
risky assets and one "instantaneously risk-less" asset. The
riskless asset corresponds to the borrowing and lending rate on short
government bonds.
The model in this paper is very similar in spirit to the models in
Merton (1971, 1973), Breeden (1979), Adler and Dumas (1983) and Bellalah
and Bellalah (2003). In the interest of brevity, common facets of this
model will only be sketched. The unfamiliar reader may refer to those
early developments of the model. Investors are price takers in perfectly
competitive capital markets. They can trade continuously and trading
takes place only at equilibrium prices. In terms of Merton (1973)
terminology, the investment opportunity set may be stochastic. The state
variables need not be restricted in number.
As usual, to be consistent with general equilibrium, prices must be
recognized to be endogenously determined using supply and demand. All
random shocks may affect both the supplies and demands for assets. All
these shocks to the economy are captured as elements of the state
vector. This vector describes the state of the world. For example asset
prices and dividends can depend on time and the state variables.
We consider an economy in which there are K investors in the
markets. Each investor can invest his wealth in n risky assets,
(stocks). The prices of these assets satisfy the following dynamics
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)
There is a riskless asset, (a bond) whose price satisfies the
following dynamics:
d[P.sub.0(t)](t) = r[P.sub.0](t)dt, [P.sub.i](0) = [p.sub.0] (2)
where [b.sub.i] represents the instantaneous expected rate of
return for different stocks, [[lambda].sub.i] is the information cost of
asset i. The term [[sigma].sub.i] is the instantaneous volatility and
[gamma] is the interest rate. They are all assumed to be bounded. The
terms [B.sub.1](t), [B.sub.2](t), ..., [B.sub.n](t) are n
one-dimensional mutually dependent Brownian motions. They represent the
external sources of uncertainty in the markets with correlation
coefficients [[rho].sub.i,j], for i,j = 1,2, ... n.
At each moment, the k th investor, K = 1, 2, ..., k can invest his
money in the various assets. We denote by [W.sup.k](t) his wealth and by
[x.sup.k.sub.i], i = 1,2, ..., n the proportion of his wealth in i th
stock. The term [c.sup.k](t) is the consumption rate, so the wealth of
the k th investor satisfies the following accumulation equation:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
As in Breeden (1979), it is possible that fluctuations in some of
the elements of the state vector do not affect any individual's
expected utility of lifetime consumption, given the individual's
wealth. A distinction can be made between state variables that affect at
least one individual's expected utility, given his wealth. In this
case, we define the state vector, s that contains those state variables
that do affect at least one individual's expected utility given his
wealth. Each individual's expected utility of lifetime consumption
may be written as a function of his wealth, the vector of state
variables, and time. The state variables are referred to as the state
vector or as the vector of state variables.
We introduce one relevant state variable S, whose dynamic is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (4)
where B(t) is one-dimensional Brownian motion which is dependent on
[B.sub.i](t) with correlation coefficients [[rho].sub.0,i], for i = 1,
2, ... n.
In this standard literature, each investor is assumed to maximize
the expected value at each instant of a time additive and
state-independent von Newmann-Morgenstern utility function for lifetime
consumption. A quasi-concave utility and bequest functions of
consumption and terminal wealth are used. At each instant, the
individual k chooses an optimal rate of consumption and an optimal
portfolio of risky assets.
The investor chooses his portfolio and consumption rate to maximize
the following expected utility function
E[[[integral].sup.T.sub.0][U.sup.k]([c.sup.k](t), S(t),t)dt + h)
([W.sup.k](T),S(T)] (5)
We denote by [J.sup.k]([W.sup.k], S,t) the maximum expected utility
of lifetime consumption that is obtainable with wealth and opportunities
S at time t.
From the classical dynamic programming principle, we can obtain the
Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6)
From n + 1 first-order conditions, we have the equations for the
optimal [c.sup.k] = [c.sup.k] ([W.sup.k],S,t) and [x.sup.k.sub.i] =
[x.sup.k.sub.i] ([W.sup.k],S,t), i = 1,2, ... n. In fact, first order
conditions for an interior maximum may be stated as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
The first equation is the usual intertemporal envelope condition to
equate the marginal utility of current consumption to the marginal
utility of future consumption (wealth). The second equation shows the
linearity in the portfolio demands.
We denote the kth investor's demand function as
[d.sup.k.sub.i] = [x.sup.k.sub.i][W.sup.k], so we have
[d.sup.k.sub.i] = [x.sup.k.sub.i][W.sup.k] = [A.sup.k][n.summation over (j=1)][v.sub.i,j]([b.sub.j] + [[lambda].sub.j] - r) + [H.sup.k]
[n.summation over (j=1)][[sigma].sub.j][sigma]S[[rho].sub.0,j],
[v.sub.i,j], i=1,2, ..., n (8)
where the [v.sub.i,j] are the elements of the inverse matrix of the
instantaneous variance-covariance matrix of return, [OMEGA] =
([[sigma].sub.i,j]), [[sigma].sub.i,j] =
[[rho].sub.i,j][[sigma].sub.i][[sigma].sub.j] and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (9)
Equation (8) can be used to show that all investors' optimal
portfolios can be represented as a combination of some portfolios or
mutual funds. Condition (8) provides the individual's optimal risky
asset portfolio in the presence of information uncertainty. The
conditions provide the individual's optimal risky asset portfolio.
They state that the indirect marginal utility of another unit of
consumption must equal the indirect marginal utility of wealth for an
optimal policy. Using these expressions for [A.sup.k] and [H.sup.k], the
demand function in equation (8) can be seen as having two components.
The first term [A.sup.k][[summation].sup.n.sub.j=1][v.sub.i,j]([b.sub.j]
+ [[lambda].sub.j] - r) is the standard demand function for a risky
asset by a single period mean-variance maximizer. The term A indicates
the reciprocal of the investor's absolute risk aversion. The second
term [H.sup.k][[summation].sup.n.sub.j=1][[sigma].sub.j][sigma]S[[rho].sub.0,j] [v.sub.i,j] indicates the investor demand for an asset as a
vehicle to hedge against "unfavorable" shifts in the
investment opportunity set.
Some further results could be gained by restricting the class of
utility functions. We can also add some simplifying assumptions to
restrict the structure of the opportunity set.
In the following analysis, we derive the equilibrium market
equation for all investors. We consider two cases: the constant
investment opportunity set and the general case
First case: the case of a constant investment opportunity set
In this situation, the distribution of prices is lognormal for all
assets. The assumption of a constant investment opportunity set is a
sufficient condition for investors to behave as if they were single
period maximizers. It is also a sufficient condition for the equilibrium
return relationship specified by the CAPMI of Merton (1987) to obtain.
We assume that all risky assets are independent of preference, i.e.
the state variable, at this case, [[rho].sub.0,j]=0, j=1,2, ... n. So
equation (8) indicating the demand for the i th asset by the k th
investor reduces to
[d.sup.k.sub.i] = [x.sup.k.sub.i][W.sup.k] = [A.sup.k][n.summation
over (j=1)][v.sub.i,j]([b.sub.j] + [[lambda].sub.j] - r), i = 1,2, ...,
n (10)
This demand corresponds also to the same demand that a one-period
risk-averse mean-variance investor would have. In the presence of
homogeneous expectations, about the opportunity set, the ratio of the
demands for risky assets will be independent of preferences, and the
same for all investors. Further, similar to the Theorem 1 in Merton, we
have the following theorem:
Theorem 1: Consider an economy with n risky assets whose returns
are log-normally distributed. In the presence of a riskless asset and
information costs regarding the n risky assets, we have the following
results: (i) there exists a unique pair of efficient portfolios known as
mutual funds: the first one contains only the riskless asset and the
second comprises only risky assets. These portfolios are independent of
preferences, wealth distribution, or time horizon. All investors will be
indifferent between choosing portfolios from among the original (n + 1)
assets or from these two funds in the presence of incomplete
information; (ii) the return distribution on the risky fund is
log-normal; and (iii) the weight of the risky fund's assets
invested in the [k.sub.th] asset is given by the following expression:
[[summation].sup.n.sub.j=1][v.sub.k,j]([b.sub.j] + [[lambda].sub.j]
- r)/ [[summation].sup.n.sub.i=1]
[[summation].sup.n.sub.j=1][v.sub.i,j]([b.sub.j] + [[lambda].sub.j] - r)
(k = 1,2, ..., n).
This theorem represents a continuous-time version of the separation
theorem in Markowitz-Tobin and Merton (1987). The holdings in the risky
portfolio indicate the optimal combination of risky assets. Then we let
the aggregate demand functions [D.sub.i] =
[[summation].sup.k.sub.k=1][d.sup.k.sub.i], and A =
[[summation].sup.k.sub.k=1] [A.sup.k], [x.sub.i] = [D.sub.i]/M, where M
is the (equilibrium) value of all assets i.e. the market value, so
[x.sub.i] M = [D.sub.i] = A [n.summation over (j=1)][v.sub.i,j]
([b.sub.j] + [[lambda].sub.j] - r), i = 1,2, ..., n
and we have
[b.sub.i] + [[lambda].sub.i] - r = M/A [n.summation over
(j=1)][x.sub.j] [[sigma].sub.i][[sigma].sub.j][[rho].sub.i,j], 1 = 1,2,
..., n (11)
We define [b.sub.M] = [[summation].sup.n.sub.i=1] [x.sub.i]
([b.sub.i] - r) as the expected return rate on the market portfolio,
[[lambda].sub.m] = [[summation].sup.n.sub.i=1] [x.sub.i][[lambda].sub.i]
as the information cost rate on the market and [[sigma].sub.i,M] =
[[summation].sup.n.sub.i=1]
[x.sub.j][[sigma].sub.i][[sigma].sub.j][[rho].sub.i,j] as the covariance of the return on the i th stock with the return on the market portfolio,
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.M] = [n.summation over (j=1)]
[x.sub.j][[sigma].sub.j,M] as the variance of the market portfolio
respectively. Then we have
[b.sub.i] + [[lambda].sub.i] - r = M/A[[sigma].sub.i,M], i = 1,2,
..., n (12)
Using the condition that the market portfolio is efficient in
equilibrium, we can show that the equilibrium returns will satisfy
"Merton's (1987)" simple model of capital market
equilibrium with incomplete information.
Multiplying (12) by [x.sub.i] and summing gives:
[b.sub.M] + [[lambda].sub.M] - r = M/A[[sigma].sup.2.sub.M] (13)
and
[b.sub.i]+[[lambda].sub.i]-r = [[beta].sub.i]([b.sub.M]+
[[lambda].sub.M]-r) (14)
where [[beta].sub.i] = [[sigma].sub.i,M]/[[sigma].sup.2.sub.M] is
the covariance of the return on the i th asset with the return on the
market portfolio.
This is the extended equilibrium market equation and the security
market line of the classical capital asset pricing model of Merton
(1987) in continuous time. In fact, this is the continuous time analog
to Merton's (1987) security market line. The assumption of a
constant investment opportunity set represents a sufficient condition
for investors to behave as if they were single-period maximizers. It is
also sufficient for the equilibrium return relationship specified by
Merton's (1987) simple capital asset pricing model to obtain.
Second case: The general case
Unfortunately, the assumption of a constant investment opportunity
set is not consistent with the facts. In practice, there is at least one
element of the opportunity set which is directly observable. This is the
case for the interest rate. The effect of a changing interest rate is
often considered as a single instrumental variable representing shifts
in the opportunity set.
This is the general case. We assume that there exists an asset (by
convention, the nth one) whose expected return shows the maximum
correlations with the state variable S. We use the same definitions as
those in the previous case.
We also let H = [[summation].sup.k.sub.k=1][H.sup.k], from (8), we
have
[x.sub.i]M = A [n.summation over (j=1)][v.sub.i,j]([b.sub.j] +
[lambda] - r) + H [n.summation over
(j=1)][[sigma].sub.j][sigma]S[[rho].sub.0,j][v.sub.i,j] (15)
Substituting (15) into (8), we get
[x.sup.k.sub.i][W.sup.k] = [A.sup.k]/A [x.sub.i]M + ([H.sup.k] -
[HA.sup.k]/A) [n.summation over
(j=1)][[sigma].sub.j][sigma]S[[rho].sub.0,j][v.sub.i,j], i=1,2, ..., n
(16)
This equation extends equation (A.2) in Breeden (1979) to account
for the effects of information uncertainty. It provides the basis for
the following allocation theorem which results immediately from
individuals' portfolio demands. But, our theorem is a three fund
theorem in the presence of information uncertainty.
Theorem 2. ("Three Funds" theorem): All individuals in
our economy within information uncertainty, regardless of their
preferences, may attain their optimal portfolio positions by investing
in at most 3 funds. These funds may be chosen to be: (i) the
instantaneously riskless asset; (ii) the asset having the highest
correlation with the state variable; and (iii) the market portfolio.
Using equation (15), we can solve for the equilibrium expected
returns on the individual assets. In this context, we obtain the
following equation
[b.sub.i] + [[lambda].sub.i] - r = M/A [n.summation over
(j=1)][x.sub.j][[sigma].sub.i][[sigma].sub.j][[rho].sub.i,j] - H/A
[[sigma].sub.i][sigma]S[[rho].sub.0,i]
We let [[sigma].sub.i,s] = [[sigma].sub.i][sigma]S[[rho].sub.0,1]
as the covariance of the return on the ith stock with the state variable
and [[sigma].sub.M,S] = [n.summation over (i=1)] [x.sub.i]
[[sigma].sub.i,S] as the covariance of the return on the market
portfolio with the state variable. So the equilibrium expected returns
on the individual assets can be written as:
[b.sub.i] + [[lambda].sub.i] - r = M/A [[sigma].sub.i,M] - H/A
[[sigma].sub.i,s], i = 1,2, ..., n 17)
It is possible to show that a generalization of Merton's
(1973) 'multi-beta' asset pricing model obtains in this
economy in the presence of shadow costs of incomplete information. In
fact, the model obtains in this economy when betas are measured with
respect to aggregate wealth and the returns of assets that hedge against
changes in the various state variables, we do the following: aggregate
individuals' portfolio demands and substitute in equilibrium
expected excess returns for the market portfolio [b.sub.M] +
[[lambda].sub.M] - r and for assets perfectly correlated with the state
variable [b.sub.n] + [[lambda].sub.n] - r.
Assuming that these assets exist and multiplying (17) by [x.sub.i]
and summing gives,
[b.sub.M] + [[lambda].sub.M] - r = M/A [[sigma].sup.2.sub.M] - H/A
[[sigma].sub.M,S] (18)
and also, we have
[b.sub.n] + [[lambda].sub.n] - r = M/A [[sigma].sub.n,M] - H/A
[[sigma].sub.n,S] (19)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (20)
This equation reveals that in equilibrium, investors are
compensated in terms of expected returns, for bearing market risk (or
systematic risk). They are compensated also for bearing the risk of
unfavorable shifts in the investment opportunity set. This equation is a
natural generalization of the results in the standard security market
line and the results in Merton's (1987) CAPMI. We also can write
equation (20) as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (21)
This is the corresponding equilibrium market equation and the
continuous time security market line of the intertemporal capital asset
pricing model with incomplete information. The term [[beta].sub.i,MSn].
corresponds to the matrix of "multiple-regression" betas for
all assets on the market and on the assets which are perfectly
correlated with the state variables.
It is important to note that this "fundamental valuation
equation" may be derived for any asset by using Ito's Lemma to
find its expected instantaneous return from the asset price function,
and then, by equating this drift rate to the equilibrium drift rates
implied by the multi-beta model of (21). We can provide some explicit
solutions for the case of CRRA utility functions.
III. EXPLICIT OPTIMAL SOLUTION FOR CRRA UTILITY FUNCTION
In this section, we consider an investor who only invests in one
category of risky assets, (stocks) for which the price [P.sub.1]
satisfies,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (22)
and in one riskless asset, (the bond), whose price satisfies:
d[P.sub.0](t) = r[P.sub.0](t)dt, [P.sub.0](0) = [P.sub.0] (23)
where [b.sub.1] represents the instantaneous expected rate of
return in the stock, [[lambda].sub.1]. is the information cost rate,
[[sigma].sub.1]. is the instantaneous volatility and r is the interest
rate. They are all assumed to be bounded. The term [B.sub.1](t), is
one-dimensional Brownian motion. It represents the external sources of
uncertainty in the market.
At each moment, the investor can invest his money in these two
kinds of assets. We denote by W(t) his wealth and by x the proportion of
his wealth in the stock. The term (1-x) is the proportion in the bond,
c(t) is the consumption rate, so the wealth of the investor satisfies
the following equation:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (24)
We introduce one relevant state variable S, whose dynamic is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (25)
where B(t) is one dimensional Brownian motion which is dependent on
[B.sub.1](t) with correlation coefficients [[rho].sub.0,1].
The investor wants to choose his strategy x and consumption rate
c(t) to maximize the following expected utility function
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (26)
where r and a are constants, r > 0, 0 < a < 1.
We refer to this utility function as the Constant Relative Risk
Aversion (CRRA) case. We want to obtain the explicit optimal proportion
[x.sup.*], consumption rate [c.sup.*](t) and value function for this
case. The admissible strategy ([x.sup.*],[c.sup.*](t)) is called an
optimal strategy which attains the maximum of J([W.sub.0]).
The idea to get the optimal solution comes from the technique to
solve celebrated LQ (linear quadratic) problems in optimal control
theory. This method is developed in Wu and Xu (1996).
From (24) and (25), we first have
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (27)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (28)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (29)
We let Q(t) be a nonnegative deterministic smooth function
satisfying Q(T)=1 whose dynamics will be given latter. Applying
Ito's formula to [e.sup.-rt]/1-a [w.sup.1-a](t)[S.sup.1-a] from 0
to T and taking expectation on both sides, we have
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
So we can write
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Now we let Q(t) be the solution of the following ordinary
differential equation of Bernoulli type:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (30)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (31)
Let [??](t) = [e.sup.-M(T-t)]Q(t), then
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
So
[??](t)=[[1 + [[integral].sup.T.sub.t][e.sup.-1/aM(T-s)]ds].sup.a]
and we obtain: [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(32)
Then we can look back I and II. If we take
[c.sup.*](t)=[(1-a).sup.-1/a][Q.sup.-1/a](t)W(t), t[member of][0,T]
(33)
where Q(T) is given by (32) and is positive. One can check that I
attains its maximum at point [c.sup.*](t) and I=0. This is also the feed
back form of wealth. Then we take:
[x.sup.*] = [[rho].sub.0.1](1-a)[sigma][[sigma].sub.1] + [b.sub.1]
+ [[lambda].sub.1] - r/a[[sigma].sup.2.sub.1] (34)
where the denominator is positive. One can check that L'
([x.sup.*] = 0 and L" ([x.sup.*]) < 0. Thus the function L(x)
attains its maximum at point [x.sup.*] and L([x.sup.*])=0, II=0.
So for CRRA case, we can have the explicit optimal proportion
[x.sup.*] from (34), the optimal consumption rate [c.sup.*](t) from (33)
and the optimal value function:
J([W.sub.0]) = 1/1-a [W.sup.1-a.sub.0][S.sup.1-a.sub.0]Q(0) (35)
where Q(0) is given by (32).
IV. SUMMARY
Information costs, which are different from transaction costs, are
justified by the huge amounts of money spent by individual and
institutional investors in analysis, valuing, and treating information.
Information is fundamental for asset pricing since investor's
information set is incomplete because it does not contain information
regarding the expected return and its variability. These information
costs are assimilated by Merton and here as additional discount rates
for future cash flows. When information costs are ignored, our model
reduces to the standard model.
An intertemporal model of the capital market has been developed
which is consistent with both the expected utility maximization and the
limited liability of assets. The analysis in Merton (1973) shows that
the equilibrium relationships among expected returns specified by the
classical capital asset pricing model will obtain only under some
special additional assumptions. Merton's model is robust in the
sense that it can be extended in an obvious way to include some other
effects.
In this context, we derive an intertemporal capital asset pricing
model in an economic context permitting both stochastic
consumption-goods prices and stochastic portfolio opportunities. The
model is a generalization of Merton's (1973) continuous-time model,
deriving equivalent pricing equations that are simpler in form. Breeden
(1979) concludes his paper by stressing the fact that areas that need
additional theoretical development include the role of firms and their
optimal investment and capital structure decisions, the impact of
information costs and transaction costs.
We provide two theorems. Theorem 1 shows that in the presence of a
riskless asset and information costs regarding the n risky assets in the
economy, (i) there exists a unique pair of efficient portfolio known as
mutual funds: the first one contains only the riskless asset and the
second comprises only risky assets. All investors will be indifferent
between choosing portfolios from among the original (n+1) assets or from
these two funds in the presence of incomplete information; and (ii) the
return distribution on the risky fund is log-normal.
Theorem 2 is a "Three Funds" theorem. It shows that all
individuals in our economy within information uncertainty, regardless of
their preferences, may attain their optimal portfolio positions by
investing in at most 3 funds. These funds may be chosen to be: (i) the
instantaneously riskless asset; (ii) the asset having the highest
correlation with the state variable; and (iii) the market portfolio.
Our model is a generalization of Merton (1973) and Breeden (1976)
by accounting for the effects of information costs.
REFERENCES
Adler, M., and B. Dumas, 1983, "International Portfolio Choice
and Corporation Finance: A Synthesis", Journal of Finance.
Bellalah, M., and M. Bellalah, 2003, "International Portfolio
Choice and the Effect of Information Costs", International Journal
of Finance.
Black, F., 1974, "International Capital Market Equilibrium
with Investment Barriers", Journal of Financial Economics, pp.
337-352.
Breeden, D..1979. "An Intertemporal Asset Model with
Stochastic Consumption and Investment Opportunities", Journal of
Financial Economics 7, pp. 265-296
Merton, R., 1971. "Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in
A Continuous Time Model", Journal of Economic Theory, pp. 373-413.
Merton, R., 1973. "An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing
Model", Econometrica, p. 867-887.
Merton, R., 1987, "A Simple Model of Capital Market
Equilibrium with Incomplete Information", Journal of Finance, pp.
483-511.
Solnik, B., 1974a, "An Equilibrium Model of International
Capital Market", Journal of Economic Theory, pp. 500-524.
Wu, Z., and W. Xu, 1996, "A Direct Method in Optimal Portfolio
and Consumption Choice", Applied Mathematics, 11B, pp. 349-354.
ENDNOTES
1. Merton's model may be stated as follows: [[bar.R].sub.p]-r
= [[beta].sub.p][[bar.R]m-r] + [[lambda].sub.p]-
[[beta].sub.p][[lambda].sub.m], where
[[bar.R].sub.p] : the equilibrium expected return on security P;
[[bar.R].sub.m]: the equilibrium expected return on the market
portfolio; r: the riskless rate of interest; [[beta].sub.p] =
cov([[??].sub.p]/[[??].sub.m])/var([[??].sub.m]: the beta of security P,
that is the covariance of the return on that security with the return on
the market portfolio, divided by the variance of market return;
[[lambda].sub.p] : the equilibrium aggregate " shadow cost"
for the security P. It is of the same dimension as the expected rate of
return on this security P; [[lambda].sub.m]. : the weighted average
shadow cost of incomplete information over all securities.
Mondher Bellalah (a) and Zhen Wu (b) *
* This work is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation
(10671112), the National Basic Research Program of China (973 Program,
No. 2007CB814904), the Natural Science Foundation of Shandong Province
(Z2006A01), and Doctoral fund of Education Ministry of China.
(a) Professor of Finance, Universite de Cergy-Pontoise 33 boulevard
du port, 95000 Cergy, France Mondher.Bellalah@u-cergy.fr
(b) Professor, School of Mathematics Shandong University, Jinan
250100, P. R. China wuzhen@sdu.edu.cn