Memory in world stock prices.
Arshanapalli, Bala G. ; Belcher, Larry ; Ma, Christopher K. 等
ABSTRACT
The random walk hypothesis is rejected for foreign stock market
prices. Variance ratio tests are performed on weekly stock prices of
nine major foreign stock market indices. While longer-term returns
follow random walks, short-horizon, bi-weekly returns exhibit
significant positive serial correlation.
JEL: C0, C4, D4, F3
Keywords: Random walks; Memory; International stockprices; Variance
ratio; Mean reverting
I. INTRODUCTION
In recent years, much controversy has been raised regarding the
time series properties of the stock returns. It has been shown that the
long-horizon stock returns using monthly and annual data exhibit
negative serial correlations (Fama and French, 1988; Lehmann, 1989;
Paterba and Summers, 1988; Cecchetti, Lam and Mark, 1989). The common
evidence suggests that there are information components in past prices
that can be used to predict future prices; price movements in stock
markets violate the random walk hypothesis. While such a conclusion may
contradict the findings in earlier studies (Working, 1934; Kendall,
1953; Roberts, 1959; Alexander, 1961), further complications surface
when nonuniform evidence is found in returns of different time horizons.
For example, both French and Roll (1986) and Lo and MacKinlay (1988)
show that daily and weekly individual security returns are negatively
autocorrelated, but Conrad and Kaul (1988), Lo and MacKinlay (1988) find
that weekly portfolio returns demonstrate positive serial correlation.
In an effort to explain return dependence, Conrad, Kaul and
Nimalendran (1989) decompose the daily stock return series into
positively autocorrelated expected return component, a negatively
autocorrelated bid-asking spread component, and an independent random
component. Ma (1990) presents similar findings in the daily GNMA bond
prices, but concludes that the unexpected information component is
positively autocorrelated. These studies provide the empirical
justification for the need to distinguish the relationship between
individual components in the price series.
To test the robustness of the results and avoid the "data
snooping" problem often found in the U.S. time series, this study
investigates the random walk hypothesis in nine major foreign stock
market indices. Three components are identified in the price series: a
systematic component reflecting the expected information, a negatively
autocorrelated component which is attributed to the bid-asking spread of
the marketmaker's behavior, and a noise term which represents the
pricing on the unexpected information. The evidence suggests that the
short-horizon (ie. 2-week holding period) realized return exhibits
persistence. The sources of the time dependence cannot be explained by
the bid-asking spread, the underlying nonnormality of the return
distribution, or the systematic movement of the underlying structure.
Therefore the implication is that the foreign stock prices did not react
to unexpected information in a rational fashion, and the adjustment
process is not instantaneous. However, once the holding period is
extended to a month, the null hypothesis of random walk cannot be
rejected.
II. THE MODEL
Before we investigate the nature of random walks, it is important
to make the distinction between anticipatory and random elements in a
price series (see Working, (1934)). Furthermore Houthakker (1934)
pointed out that randomness of a process could be defined only in the
absence of any systematic pattern. Conrad, Kaul and Nimalendran (1991)
have shown that the stock return series exhibit different time-series
properties and therefore the distinction between the anticipatory and
the random components are very important. Furthermore, Conrad and et al
(1991) have shown that short-horizon realized returns exhibit negative
dependence. However, they showed that negative dependence is most due to
the bid-asking spread rather than due to the randomness. Thus, some have
argued that the systematic structure of the time series, if expected,
should be deterministic.
Consequently, the testing of the random walk hypothesis should be
only relevant with respect to the random component of the price series.
To properly show the impact on the variance from various components in
the return series; the price formation process should be described as
follows. At time t =1, the ith investor forms expectations of price at
time t based on the information available at t-1, [X.sub.t-1], and can
be written as
E([P.sub.t] / [[phi].sub.t-1]) = [alpha] + [beta][X.sub.t-1] (1)
where [alpha] & [beta] are parameters and [X.sub.t-1], is the
information available in time [period.sub.t-1]. Further, it is also
assumed that investors enter at time t-1 with probability beliefs prob
(.) defined over the information set [[phi].sub.t]. The information
available in time period t-1 ([X.sub.t-1]) is a subset of [[phi].sub.t].
The actual formation process can be described as
[P.sub.t] = [E.sub.t-1](Pt/[[phi].sub.t-1]) + [e.sub.t] +
b([X.sub.t] - [X.sub.t-1]) (2)
where [e.sub.t] is assumed to be identically and independently
distributed (iid), [X.sub.t] is the information available at time t. The
difference ([X.sub.t] - [X.sub.t-1]) is the incremental information set
available from t-1. Thus, the actual price is a fraction of expected
price component at t-1, systematic component ([X.sub.t] - [X.sub.t-1])
which may be attributed to risk premium or bid-ask spread or trend
specific to certain specific periods, and a random component. The
testing of random walk hypothesis involves the testing of the
time-series properties of the noise terms, [e.sub.t]. Since stock prices
are non-stationary, returns are used in our empirical model.
To separate the random component from the systematic component
reflecting the changes of an underlying economic model, we employ the
variance ratio test first developed by Tintner (1940) and the
corresponding tests statistics by Lo and MacKinlay (1988). Specifically,
let [P.sub.t] represent the asset price at time t and [L.sub.t] be the
natural logarithm of prices. The continuously compound return, [R.sub.t]
which is the difference in successive log-prices, should contain three
components: a systematic component, [[phi].sub.t], which is
differentiable with respect to time and determined by the underlying
fundamentals of the asset; bid-ask spread component, [[delta].sub.t] S,
reflecting the impact of dealer's marketmaking behavior; and a
random innovation, [[epsilon].sub.t] generated by unexpected random
causes. Therefore,
Log([P.sub.t]/[P.sub.t-1]) = [[phi].sub.t] + ([[delta].sub.t] -
[[delta]sub.t-1])S + [[epsilon].sub.t], (3)
where cov([[phi].sub.t], [[epsilon].sub.t]) = 0,
cov([[delta].sub.t], [[epsilon].sub.t]) = 0, cov ([[phi].sub.t],
[[delta].sub.t]) = 0, E([[epsilon].sub.t]) = E([[delta].sub.t]) = 0, and
cov ([[delta].sub.t], [[delta].sub.t-1]) = [[rho].sub.t1 < 0.
In equation (3), S is the level of a time-invariant bid-ask spread,
and [[delta].sub.t] is the stochastic variable for the transaction type
of the price, Pt: [[delta].sub.t] =1 if the transaction price is an ask
price and [[delta].sub.t] = -1 for a bid price.
In addition, bid-ask spread is introduced in equation (3) to
account for non-trading effects. The studies that use monthly or annual
data (see for example, Fama and French, 1988 or Paterba and Summers
1999) are less likely to be affected by non-trading at those
frequencies. However, in daily or weekly studies, it has been shown that
returns show positive correlation due to infrequent trading, (see
Conrad, Kaul and Numalendran, 1991). For example, if some of the
securities in the market index trade infrequently, these securities will
have higher bid-ask spread to reflect the illiquidity of these
securities. Furthermore, we are using index data of 9 countries, the
inclusion of bid-ask spread in equation 3 became even more important to
account for non-trading effects. It makes even more sense to include
bid-ask spread especially to account for different market
microstructures of these countries.
As market makers stand ready to offer a (higher) price to sell and
ask a (lower) price to buy, the differences between the two prices, in
the form of positive bid-ask spreads, is the reward for market makers
for providing the liquidity services. Roll (1984) argues that if buy and
sell orders arrive randomly in a non- trending market, market prices
will tend to vary between the bid and ask prices in such a way that the
observed prices changes act as if they are negatively autocorrelated.
Thus, the correlation between the successive transaction types,
[[rho].sub.1], is assumed to be negative. A mean of zero for
[[delta].sub.t] reflects the assumption that there is no concentration
on the type of the transaction for the entire sample period. By
definition, [[phi].sub.t], [[delta].sub.t], and [[epsilon].sub.t] are
independent. The components of the spread variables in equation (1)
reflect the effect of the transaction type of the quoted prices on the
computed returns. When two successive prices are the same type of
transaction, i.e., [[delta].sub.t] = [[delta].sub.t-1], there is no
measurement bias of bid-ask spreads in the returns or the variances.
Conversely, if the bid and ask prices reverse perfectly from price to
price; there is a significant bias in the return variances.
In order to test empirically equation (3), it is important to
neutralize the impact of systematic component. It should be noted,
however, that the systematic component can be serially correlated due to
the nature of the economic determinants which may be time- path
dependent. That is, cov ([[phi].sub.t], [[phi].sub.t-1]) is not
necessarily equal to zero. Based on the specification in equation (1),
[[epsilon].sub.t], are said to follow a Gaussian random walk, if and
only if, the noise component is independent of time and normally
distributed with an expected value of zero and variance equal to
[[sigma].sup.2]. It is necessary, therefore, to isolate the noise
component from the entire series, which can be accomplished by taking
finite differences of the price series. When a lag, q, is used to finite
differences the series, any systematic pattern of [[phi].sub.t] that
exists between [P.sub.t] and, [P.sub.t-q] should be irrelevant in
determining the variance ratios. Thus, the finite differencing of a
series will eliminate or at least reduce to any desired degree on the
importance of the systematic component without changing the random
component (Powers, 1971). On the other hand, the random component cannot
be reduced by finite differencing since it is not ordered in time.
The above tests is often considered superior to traditional
white-noise tests or autocorrelation tests for random walks, since it
does not require that the underlying ex ante economic model be
specified. The traditional autocorrelation method assumes either that
there is no systematic component in the underlying process (martingale)
or that the economic model be specific ad hoc in order to distinguish
the random component et for testing. In either case, the hypothesis is
always a joint test for both the validity of the model and the
independence of the [[epsilon].sub.t]. Therefore, there should exist a
non- negative integer, q, which will eliminate the impact of the
systematic structure, and equation (3) can be written as:
Log ([P.sub.t]/[P.sub.t-q]) = [q.summation over (k=0)]
[[epsilon].sub.t] - k + ([[delta].sub.t] - [[delta].sub.t] - q)S
and the variance of the q- period return is:
V([R.sub.q]) = [q.summation over (k=0)] V([[epsilon].sub.t] - k) +
2[S.sup.2] V([[delta].sub.t]) + [q.summation over (i=0)] [q.summation
over (j=0)] Cov([[epsilon].sub.t-i], [[epsilon].sub.t-j]) - 2[S.sup.2]
Cov([[delta].sub.t], [[delta].sub.t-q]), where i [not equal to] j.
The random walk hypothesis would require that [[epsilon].sub.t] be
independent and identically distributed (i. i.d.). Therefore, let
[[sigma].sub.[delta].sup.2] = V([[delta].sub.t]), and [[rho].sub.q] =
COV([[delta].sub.t], [[delta].sub.t-q]),
V([R.sub.q]) = gV([[epsilon].sub.t]) + 2
[S.sup.2]([[sigma].sub.[delta].sup.2], [[rho].sub.q]) (4)
Assume that bid-ask spread does not exists, equation (4) is reduced
to V([R.sub.q]) = gV([[epsilon].sub.t])=q[[sigma].sup.2]. Thus, the
familiar unit- root variance ratio and the following necessary condition
for random walks must hold:
[lambda](q) = V(q)/[V(1)q] = 1, (5)
where [lambda](q) represents the variance ratio of the finite
difference log-price series. The variance ratio test compares the
variance of a q-period return to that of the product of q and the
variance of a one-period return. To test the null hypothesis that the
time-variance relationship in equation (5) holds, finding [lambda](q)
significantly different from unity is sufficient to reject the random
walk hypothesis. Consider the observed log-prices series [L.sub.0],
[L.sub.1], ... [L.sub.n], where the total number of observations equals
n + 1. Define the unbiased estimations of [mu], V(1) and V(q),
respectively. Then:
[mu] = 1/(n) [n.summation over (k=1)] (Lk - Lk - 1) V(1) = 1/(n-1)
[n.summation over (k=1)] [(Lk - Lk - 1] - [mu]).sup.2]
V(q) = 1/[q(n-q+1)(1-q/n)] [n.summation over (k=1)] [(Lk - Lk - q -
q[mu]).sup.2]
As shown by Lo and MacKinlay (1988), the test statistic, z(q),
which is insensitive to non-normality of the underlying return
distribution and overlapping data problem, is asymptotically normal with
a mean of zero and variance of unity with the following specifications:
z(q) - [[[lambda].sup.*](q)/t[(q).sup.1/2]] (6)
where
[[lambda].sup.*](q) - v(q)/[V(1)q] (7)
t(q) = [q-1.summation over (j=1)] [[(2(q - j) / q].sup.2] d(j),and
d(j) = [n.summation over (k=j+1)][(Lk - Lk - 1] - [mu]).sup.2]
[([L.sub.k-j] - [L.sub.k-1] - [mu]).sup.2] / [[[n.summation over
(k=j+1)] [(Lk - Lk - 1 - [mu]).sup.2]].sup.2]
The estimations on the variance ratios of different lags,
[lambda](q), and their associated test statistics, z(q), will allow us
to assess if the variance ratios are significantly different from unity.
The random walk hypothesis will be rejected if [[lambda].sup.*](q) is
significantly different from unity. Furthermore, an estimate of
[lambda](q) greater (less) than 1 for q=2 would suggest significantly
positive (negative) serial correlation between prices. Furthermore, the
test is rather insensitive to heteroscedasticity, a phenomenon in which
the variance changes over time, i.e., [sigma] may itself be a random
variable, possibly following a random walk or varying systematically
with time. The estimations on the variance ratios of different lags,
[lambda](q), and their associated tests statistics z(q) will allow us to
determine whether the variance ratios are significantly different from
unity.
To determine whether the systematic component in the original price
series is not contributing to the price dependence measured by the
variance ratios, the length of the different interval, q, must be
significantly larger. However, the variance ratio would start from one
(q=1) and exhibit deviations from one as q becomes larger, and
eventually resolute back to one when q equals [q.sup.*], where [q.sup.*]
is the number of differences needed to randomize the original series. As
[q.sup.*] is unknown if the underlying model is not first estimated, the
evidence of deviations from unity for a given q only indicates the
rejection of random walks relative to the holding period being
investigated.
A. The Impact of the Bid-Ask Spreads
It should be noted, however, the existence of a nontrivial bid-ask
spread, while not observable, complicates the measurement of the true
variance ratio on the random element. This can be demonstrated by
deriving the variance ratio from the specification of the variance
function in equation (3) based on the observed prices:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8)
Let
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (9)
where [theta] measures the bias from the bid-ask spread in the
observed variance ratio. The observed variance in equation (4) is always
upward biased for [partial derivative]V(Rq)/[partial derivative]S >
0. However, the variance ratio computed over the observed prices is
biased downward since [theta] >0, for q [greater than or equal to] 2.
This implies that [lambda](q) [less than or equal to] [lambda] (q) =1
for any positive q greater or equal to 2, where [lambda] (q) is the true
variance ratio associated with random walks independent of the bid-ask
spread. Apparently, it is less interesting that the significant
deviation of the variance ratio from unity is a result of simple
measurement errors from bid-ask spreads. Since [partial
derivative][theta]/[partial derivative]q > 0 , the magnitude of the
downward bias on the variance ratios increases as the number of lags
increases. However, as [partial derivative][V.sup.2](Rq)/[partial
derivative]g[partial derivative]S < 0 , the relative importance of
the bias on the variance level also decreases when the number of lags
increases. This would motivate the need of testing the hypothesis by
computing the variance ratios of larger lags.
The bias from bid-ask spread components also varies with the length
of the holding period for returns. From equation (3), the finite
differenced log-prices over a longer horizon may be given as follows:
Log([P.sub.t]/[P.sub.t-hq]) = [hq.summation over (k=0)] [epsilon]t
- k + ([delta]t - [delta]t - hq)S
where h is the number of periods in one holding horizon during
which the return is measured and q is the number of lags taken on the
longer horizon (h-period) returns. The variance ratio function specified
by equation (8) can be modified as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and the bid-ask spread bias on the variance ratio over long-horizon
returns as in equation (9) is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Since [partial derivative]0 / [partial deivative]h < 0 , the
downward bias on the variance ratio for longer-horizon returns less.
This is mainly due to the non time-additive nature of the bid-ask
spreads. The implication is that the impact of trading practice such as
bid-ask spreads often dominates for the short-term holding period (Roll,
1984; Lehmann, 1989). Hence, the extent of a "manufactured"
negative serial correlation from bid-ask spreads is expected to diminish
significantly if the length of the holding period is extended. In short,
to measure the time-series properties beyond the nontrivial impact of
bid-ask spreads as well as the underlying systematic component, both the
length of the holding period for the return and the lag for differencing
should be significantly longer.
III. DATA
For the reasons discussed above, the weekly stock index levels of
nine major foreign industrialized stock markets were gathered for the
period 1981 to 2001. There are 1095 weekly Wednesday observations for
each foreign stock market. The selection of the same weekday is based on
the consideration that the confounding impact of the well-known
day-of-the-week effect in major stock market indices can be minimized.
These are Morgan Stanley Composite stock Indices obtained from
Datastream. The nine stock markets are Belgium, Canada, France, Germany,
Italy, Japan, Netherlands, Switzerland, and UK. These indices are all
denominated in US dollars. Using stock indices, instead of individual
stock prices, can also reduce the problem of the negative serial
correlation in the individual stock price quotes.
IV. EMPIRICAL FINDINGS AND CONCLUSIONS
Based on the procedure described in the previous section, the
variance ratios and their test statistics for lags 2 through 10 (q=2 to
10) are computed for each of the nine major foreign stock market
indices. For the sake of brevity, we only report the variance ratios of
one-week, two-week, and four-week returns for lag 2, 5 and 10 in Table 1
in Appendix. As the variance ratio for lag 2 can be approximated by
1-[theta], where [theta] is the first-order autocorrelation, a variance
ratio of 1.12 for Canada, for example, implies a 12 percent positive
serial correlation between successive weekly price changes (returns).
The results for weekly return reveal that none of the variance ratios
are significantly different from one except for Canada.
While the weekly price changes may still be affected by the bid-ask
spreads, the evidence on the bi-weekly returns shows a stronger pattern.
Six out of the nine foreign stock indices (except for Netherlands, Italy
and UK) exhibit significant positive serial correlations. These results
are similar to the results obtained by Poterba and Summers (1988).
However, they found negative autocorrelation over longer horizons. These
results are not necessarily different from our results, since they also
could not reject random-walk price behavior statistically. The inclusion
of bid-ask spread may partially explain why we did not find negative
autocorrelation over longer horizon. The robustness of the evidence can
be further confirmed by the significant ratio when the lag is
lengthened. Since the level of the downward bias from bid-ask spread
would be greater when the lag is larger, the generally higher level of
the variance ratios for the longer lags suggests that the variance ratio
is least "contaminated" by the bid-ask spread problem, if it
exists, in the data series. Therefore, this implies that the positive
price dependence is very strong considering the impact of negative
serial correlation due to the bid-ask spread. The persistence in the
movements of stock indices is also consistent with the previous findings
that portfolio returns exhibit positive serial correlation.
However, once the holding period extends to a month, the null
hypothesis of random walks cannot be rejected. That is, almost all
except one variance ratio are not different from one over shorter
horizon but the hypothesis of random walk cannot be rejected over longer
horizon.
To check the robustness of the results we divided the sample into
pre and post 1987 crash. The estimated results of these two sub samples
are presented in Tables 2 and 3. In the pre-crash period only 4 out of
nine markets exhibit significant positive autocorrelation. However, in
the post crash period seven out of nine markets show significant
positive autocorrelation in bi-weekly holding period periods. In
summary, similar to the recent findings in the U.S. stock market, we
document significant evidence of deviations from random walks in the
foreign stock markets.
APPENDIX
Table 1
Variance ratio test for short-horizon foreign stock returns
sample period: January 1981 - December 2001
Country Weekly Returns
q=2 q=5 q=10
Belgium 1.05 1.12 1.24
0.74 1.27 1.68 *
Canada 1.12 1.23 1.32
1.72 * 2.18 * 2.09 *
France 1.09 1.15 1.19
1.34 1.53 1.36
Germany 1.05 1.07 1.07
0.73 0.75 0.54
Italy 1.05 1.14 1.12
0.83 1.40 0.94
Japan 1.03 1.11 1.18
0.47 1.16 1.33
Netherlands 0.98 0.90 0.88
-0.40 -1.37 -1.19
Switzerland 1.05 1.07 1.09
0.85 0.79 0.69
UK 0.95 0.91 0.81
-0.80 -1.12 1.96 *
Country Bi-Weekly Returns
q=2 q=5 q=10
Belgium 1.26 1.50 1.79
2.39 * 2.74 * 2.69 *
Canada 1.18 1.25 1.30
1.75 * 1.64 1.40
France 1.20 1.30 1.36
1.98 * 1.90 * 1.61
Germany 1.19 1.28 1.33
1.86 * 1.82 * 1.52
Italy 1.08 1.25 1.34
0.85 1.67 * 1.53
Japan 1.17 1.28 1.34
1.72 * 1.82 * 1.54
Netherlands 1.05 1.01 1.02
0.61 0.10 0.12
Switzerland 1.18 1.25 1.31
1.82 * 1.68 * 1.46
UK 1.01 0.98 0.89
0.13 -0.17 -0.78
Country Monthly Returns
q=2 q=5 q=10
Belgium 1.06 1.20 1.38
0.43 0.94 1.14
Canada 1.05 1.04 1.03
0.41 0.23 0.13
France 1.10 1.23 1.24
0.73 1.06 0.81
Germany 1.00 0.99 0.88
-0.03 -0.04 -0.56
Italy 0.99 1.07 1.04
-0.12 0.36 0.17
Japan 1.02 1.08 0.94
0.13 0.42 -0.28
Netherlands 0.98 0.97 0.83
-0.19 -0.16 -0.83
Switzerland 1.06 1.17 1.14
0.41 0.81 0.51
UK 1.05 1.12 0.99
0.36 0.60 -0.03
The tests are performed from lag 2 (q=2) through 10. Only three
representative lags are reported.
The variance ratio is computed by equation (7).
The Z-statistic reported below the variance ratio is computed
using equation (6).
* Significant at the 5 percent level.
Table 2
Variance ratio test for short-horizon foreign stock returns
sample period: January 1981 - September 1987
Country Weekly
q=2 q=5 q=10
Belgium 1.19 1.41 1.68
1.49 1.92 * 1.98 *
Canada 1.20 1.38 1.60
1.57 1.83 * 1.83 *
France 1.23 1.40 1.62
0.69 1.91 * 4.75 *
Germany 1.07 1.14 1.18
0.59 0.81 0.75
Italy 1.06 1.29 1.47
0.56 1.50 1.57
Japan 1.24 1.39 1.49
1.82 1.87 * 1.61
Netherlands 0.98 0.93 0.93
-0.21 -0.47 -0.38
Switzerland 1.11 1.18 1.35
0.95 1.00 1.27
UK 0.89 0.87 0.84
-1.11 -1.02 -0.92
Country Bi-Weekly Returns
q=2 q=5 q=10
Belgium 1.26 1.48 1.67
1.38 1.53 1.39
Canada 1.07 1.07 1.10
0.41 0.30 0.31
France 1.15 1.28 1.26
0.84 1.02 0.72
Germany 1.01 0.97 0.79
0.06 -0.13 -0.91
Italy 0.99 1.11 1.11
-0.08 0.47 0.35
Japan 1.05 1.05 0.85
0.29 0.24 -0.62
Netherlands 0.99 1.00 0.85
-0.04 0.01 -0.61
Switzerland 1.08 1.14 0.96
0.49 0.58 -0.16
UK 1.08 1.13 1.02
0.50 0.54 0.06
Country Monthly Returns
q=2 q=5 q=10
Belgium 0.99 1.02 1.07
-0.03 0.06 0.14
Canada 1.04 0.99 0.86
0.19 -0.03 -0.38
France 0.99 1.04 1.05
-0.05 0.11 0.10
Germany 0.89 0.93 0.88
-0.54 -0.23 -0.33
Italy 1.02 0.99 0.96
0.09 -0.04 -0.10
Japan 0.85 0.78 0.71
-0.81 -0.89 -0.95
Netherlands 0.94 0.79 0.63
-0.30 -0.83 -1.35
Switzerland 0.86 1.02 1.28
-0.66 0.05 0.51
UK 0.96 0.94 0.87
-0.18 -0.19 -0.36
The tests are performed from lag 2 (q=2) through 10. Only three
representative lags are reported.
The variance ratio is computed by equation (7).
The Z- statistic reported below the variance ratio is computed
using equation (6).
* Significant at the 5 percent level.
Table 3
Variance ratio test for short-horizon foreign stock returns
sample period: November 1987 - December 2001
Country Weekly
q=2 q=5 q=10
Belgium 0.94 0.92 0.93
-0.93 -0.87 -0.54
Canada 1.03 1.11 1.17
0.42 0.98 1.01
France 0.95 0.90 0.81
-0.73 -1.11 -1.62
Germany 0.98 0.95 0.90
-0.22 -0.53 -0.78
Italy 1.03 1.04 0.91
0.42 0.37 -0.67
Japan 0.95 0.99 1.02
-0.78 -0.09 0.11
Netherlands 0.93 0.79 0.72
-1.09 -2.51 * -2.75 *
Switzerland 1.00 0.99 0.93
-0.06 -0.13 -0.52
UK 0.95 0.91 0.78
-0.68 -0.98 -1.95 *
Country Bi-Week Returns
q=2 q=5 q=10
Belgium 1.21 1.38 1.60
1.66 * 1.88 * 1.87 *
Canada 1.27 1.42 1.50
2.07 * 2.00 * 1.67 *
France 1.26 1.34 1.47
2.00 * 1.71 * 1.61
Germany 1.26 1.40 1.51
2.00 * 1.93 * 1.70 *
Italy 1.15 1.39 1.58
1.27 1.90 * 1.84 *
Japan 1.20 1.33 1.46
1.63 1.69* 1.57
Netherlands 1.09 1.00 1.06
0.76 -0.01 0.28
Switzerland 1.25 1.32 1.50
1.95 * 1.66 * 1.67 *
UK 0.99 0.92 0.86
-0.09 -0.63 -0.82
Country Monthly Returns
q=2 q=5 q=10
Belgium 1.05 1.20 1.28
0.33 0.76 0.74
Canada 1.07 1.08 1.10
0.40 0.33 0.31
France 1.13 1.27 1.24
0.74 0.99 0.65
Germany 0.99 0.92 0.61
-0.09 -0.38 -1.38
Italy 0.94 1.01 0.99
-0.40 0.05 -0.03
Japan 1.09 1.19 0.90
0.52 0.72 -0.36
Netherlands 0.98 1.00 0.85
-0.12 0.01 -0.62
Switzerland 1.08 1.15 0.97
0.48 0.61 -0.12
UK 1.08 1.20 1.06
0.50 0.77 0.18
The tests are performed from lag 2 (q=2) through 10. Only three
representative lags are reported.
The variance ratio is computed by equation (7).
The Z- statistic reported below the variance ratio is computed
using equation (6).
* Significant at the 5 percent level.
REFERENCES
Alexander, S, 1961, "Price Movements in Speculative Markets:
Trends or Random Walks," Industrial Management Review 2, 7-26.
Cecchetti, S., P. Lam and N. Mark, 1989, "Mean Reversion in
Equilibrium Asset Prices." Working paper, Ohio State University.
Conrad, J. and G. Kaul, 1988, "Time-Variation in Expected
Returns," Journal of Business, 61, 147-163.
Conrad, J., G. Kaul and M. Nimalendran, 1991, "Components of
Short-Horizon Individual Security Returns," Journal of Financial
Economics, 29, 365-385.
Fama, E., 1970, "Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory
and Empirical Work," Journal ofFinance, 25, 383-417.
K. French, 1988, "Permanent and Temporary Components of Stock
Prices," Journal of Political Economy, 96, 246-272.
French, K. and R. Roll, 1986, "Stock Return Variances: The
arrival of Information and the Reaction of Traders," Journal of
Financial Economics, 17, 5-26.
Houthakker, H., 1934, "Systematic and Random Elements in
Short-Term Price Movements," Journal of the American Statistical
Association, 29, 164-172.
Kendall, M., 1953, "The Analysis of Economic Time-Series, Part
1: Prices," Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 96, 11-25.
Lehmann, B., 1990, "Fads, Martingales, and Market
Efficiency," Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Lo, W. and C. Mackinlay, 1988, "Stock Market Prices Do Not
Follow Random Walks: Evidence from a Simple Specification Test,"
Review of Financial Studies, 1, 41-66.
Ma, C., 1990, "Meant Reversions in GNMA Returns," AREUEA,
18, 207-226.
MacKinlay, C. and K. Ramaswamy, 1988, "Index-Futures Arbitrage and the Behavior of Stock Index Futures Prices," Review of
Financial Studies, 1, 137-158.
Paterba, J.M. and L. H. Summers, 1988, "Mean Reversions in
Stock Prices: Evidence and Implications," Journal of Financial
Economics, 22, 27-59.
Powers, M., 1971, "Does Futures Trading Reduce Price
Fluctuations in the Cash Markets?" American Economics Review, 61,
460-464.
Roberts, H., 1959, "Stock Market 'Pattern' and
Financial Analysis: Methodological Suggestions," Journal ofFinance,
14, 1-10.
Roll, R., 1984, "A Simple Measure of the Effective Bid-Ask
Spread in an Efficient Market," Journal of Finance, 39, 1127-39.
Tintner, G., 1940, The Variance Difference Method, Bloomington.
Working, H., 1934, "A Random Difference Series for Use in the
Analysis of Time Series," Journal of the American Statistical
Association, 29, 11-24.
Bala G. Arshanapalli (a)
Larry Belcher (b)
Christopher K. Ma (c)
James E. Mallett (d)
(a) Indiana University Northwest, bala@iunbusl.iun.edu
(b) Department of Finance, Stetson University, lbelcher@stetson.edu
(c) Department of Finance, Stetson University, kcma95@aol.com
(d) Department of Finance, Stetson University, jmallett@stetson.edu