Growth and persistence of large business groups in India.
Rajakumar, J. Dennis ; Henley, John S.
The international business literature is belatedly recognizing the
significance of large family-controlled business groups in emerging
markets. Most research has focused on analyzing the impact of
concentrations of private wealth on economic development in home
countries using panel data. This paper examines the growth and
persistence of business groups since 1951 in one country--India. Since
Independence, the government has attempted to operate an economic policy
framework that had, amongst its prime objectives, the curbing of the
tendency of business groups to concentrate economic power: As their
growth was seen as synonymous with concentration of wealth, business
groups became obvious candidates for regulation. Various policy
instruments were introduced, such as the Industries (Development and
Regulation) (IDR) Act 1951 and the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade
Practices (MRTP) Act 1969, with the aim of erecting barriers to their
growth. In 1991, economic reform ushered in the removal of the
legislative barriers to business group growth. The analysis in this
paper concludes that large business groups expanded their share of
wealth between 1951 and 1969, but this growth was arrested between 1970
and 1990, and since 1991, it has dwindled. The pre-eminent position of
Tata and Birla, as the two largest business groups, remained
unchallenged from 1951 until the emergence of the Reliance Group in the
late 1990s. However; there has been frequent change in the relative
positions of other groups in and out of the Top-20. After economic
liberalisation accelerated from 1991, their was significant change in
the ranks of business groups in the Top-20. Existing smaller groups or
newly emerging groups, particularly in the IT and telecommunications
sectors, have replaced many of the previously dominant older groups.
This is interpreted as indicating the central role of entrepreneurship
in combination with technological innovation, and the opening up of the
Indian economy to international competition, in disturbing established
business hierarchies in India. More generally, policy intervention
appears to have been less effective in breaking up concentrations of
economic power in India than economic liberalization and increased
competition.
Introduction
The presence of large business groups in emerging markets has
stimulate considerable interest in whether their performance has a
positive or negative effect on the host countries' general economic
performance. Fogel (2006), for example, finds that greater oligarchic family control over large corporations is associated with worse economic
outcomes, interventionist governments and underdeveloped market
institutions in a group of 41 countries including India. Khanna and
Palepu (2000) and Khanna and Rivkin (2001) suggest, by contrast, that
oligarchic family groups operate efficiently by creating their own
internal capital and managerial talent markets, functioning largely
independently of the institutional environment characterised by
bureaucracy, 'red tapeism' and market failure. This, of
course, neatly sidesteps the issue of the direction of causality and the
extent to which large business groups through the process of
internalising capital and labour markets undermine the weak and
inefficient institutional structures of the wider society. It seems
implausible that large family-controlled business groups will not at
times use their economic power to protect or enhance their positions.
Even if this is not true, Morck and Yeung (2004) argue that large firms
have significant scale advantages in dealing with government. Certainly
reducing or eliminating this size advantage is one of the key drivers
behind the World Bank's campaign to improve investment climates in
all countries and for all sizes of firms (World Bank, 2006 & 2007).
From the beginning, the founders of modern India were concerned to
ensure that the economic system did not concentrate wealth. These
concerns are enshrined in the Constitution of India which places an
obligation on the government of the day to control the concentration of
wealth and, by implication, the growth of large business groups. (1)
In newly independent India, in the early 1950s, it was feared that
the accelerated growth being predicted by economic planners would
further concentrate economic power. Curbing any such tendency became an
integral part of formal economic policy. All firms in India were
required to operate in a tightly controlled and regulated policy
environment, exemplified by a complex licensing regime, or 'license
raj', the disparaging name it was popularly known by. This obliged
firms to seek prior permission to issue capital, to raise money from
financial institutions and to obtain foreign exchange. A high tariff
regime was imposed on imported capital goods and raw materials.
The effectiveness of government controls as a means for checking
the accumulation of wealth attracted a wide debate, even among policy
makers (GOI, 1965, pp. 3-10). The Schumpetarian (1934) argument that
economic growth requires constant rejuvenation through the destruction
of the old and the creation of new firms with new technologies was not
part of the dominant orthodoxy of the day. Nor was the idea that the
removal of controls would facilitate the emergence of new entrepreneurs
and lead to a diminution of concentration accepted in official circles.
Only in the early 1990s and after a severe financial crisis, did
decontrolling economic activity become central to economic policies.
Since then, the Government has initiated wide-scale removal of controls
and taken steps to reduce the regulatory burden on business. Competition
has been increased in the domestic market by progressively removing
equity caps on foreign direct investment (FDI) and reducing tariffs on
imported goods.
This paper examines the growth and persistence of large business
groups in India under different policy regimes. (2) The growth of
business groups is analyzed in terms of the increase or decrease in
their share of four macroeconomic variables. These variables are chosen
to represent different ways of measuring concentration.
The paper is divided into two parts. Part One identifies the
various phases through which the policy regime to control the growth of
business groups has evolved between 1951 and 2001. The growth of
business groups is then mapped across changes in the policy regime. In
Part Two, the persistence of large business groups is examined. The
paper ends with some concluding remarks.
Part One
Growth of Business Groups, 1951 to 2001:
For four decades from 1950, the growth of business groups was
regulated by two principal legislative instruments: the Industries
(Development & Regulation) (IDR), Act, 1951 and the Monopolies and
Restrictive Trade Practices (MRTP) Act, 1969. The IDR Act sought to
prevent the concentration of wealth through a comprehensive system of
licensing. The MRTP Act was designed to regulate the growth of assets
and market power of business groups. Periodic amendments were made to
the IDR Act and the MRTP Act was revised in 1982 and 1984.
As part of the economic reforms introduced after 1991, industries
were de-licensed and the threshold limit on assets was repealed. These
changes, together with relaxation of controls over capital and credit
markets, and easing of sector-related policies, have removed all major
policy barriers specifically targeted at large business houses. In
effect, the government switched to relying on the forces of competition
to satisfy their obligations under the Constitution to limit
concentrations of wealth.
From 1951, three distinct policy regimes regulating business groups
can be distinguished:
* Phase 1: From 1951 to 1969: Regulation through licensing under
the IDR Act
* Phase 2: From 1970 to 1991: Regulation through a combination of
licensing and the MRTP Act
* Phase 3: After 1991: Enhancement of market efficiency through
de-regulation and progressive tariff reductions.
Growth of Business Groups Phase 1:1951-1969
This phase covers India's first three Five-year plans and
three successive Annual plans. Development strategy during this period
was designed to achieve higher economic growth, complimented by
legislation to prevent concentration of wealth. The IDR Act, 1951,
empowered the central government to reserve industries of national
importance for the public sector. In other industries, where private
firms could participate, the Act required firms to obtain a license to
establish any new undertaking and seek prior permission to produce any
new line or undertake any substantial expansion programme (Shaw, 1971).
Two other important pieces of legislation that sought to reduce
concentration of economic power were the Capital Issues (Control) Act,
1947, which was intended to ensure wide dispersal of share ownership,
and the Indian Companies Act, 1956, which restricted inter-corporate
investment and directorships.
In order to evaluate whether such policies were effective in
curtailing the concentration of wealth, the Government constituted four
important committees in the 1960s. (3) Unfortunately, the committees
defined business groups in different ways and used different parameters
to measure concentration levels so making comparisons between the
committees' findings is difficult.
The Monopolies Inquiry Commission (MIC) classified a company as
being part of a business group, if the group had a controlling equity
stake of 50 per cent or more (GOI, 1965, p.33). The MIC, using an assets
threshold of Rs. 5 crore (4) or more, identified 75 groups (controlling
a total of 1536 companies) in 1964 which it defined as 'large
business groups'.
In contrast, Hazari (1967, pp. 5-7) argued that a business group
could be represented by 'a series of concentric circles' and
so allocated group companies between in inner and outer circles. Units
assigned to the inner circle had decision-making powers. Those in the
outer circle were companies where the group had 'fifty-fifty or
minority equity participation'. Hazari identified 20 business
groups which he referred to as complexes, but did not classify any group
as large.
The Dutt Committee used the criterion of one-third or more of
effective equity, defined as, 'total equity capital minus holdings
by the State-sponsored financial institutions, Governments, and
Non-Resident Indians' to identify large business group-controlled
companies (GOI, 1969, pp. 4-15). The Committee then set a threshold of
assets worth over Rs. 35 crore to identify 73 large business groups
operating in 1966.
Hazari (1967) estimated the relative share of Indian business
groups by total paid-up capital, net fixed assets, net fixed capital
stock and gross capital stock, while the MIC (1965) used paid-up capital
and total assets to classify large business groups. The findings of
these studies are summarised in Table 1.
As can be seen from Table 1, the share of the top 20 business
groups in private corporate assets increased during the 1950s. While the
share of assets reported for the 1960s is not strictly comparable with
that of the 1950s due to differences in definitions and variables used,
there is again a discernible increase in the relative share of business
groups. (5) This was widely attributed to ineffective policy
implementation. For example, the MIC observed that controls actually
helped existing large firms by restricting the entry of new firms.
Smaller and newer firms, because they had fewer assets of their
own, were normally exposed to the full rigour of the licensing regime if
they wished to undertake a new venture. Large business groups, by
contrast, usually had the required financial reserves or in-house
capacity to raise finance for new activities. They received preferential
treatment from the licensing authorities and foreign collaborators were
typically eager to participate with them in joint ventures. The Dutt
Committee concluded, "Not only was no attempt made to use licensing
to prevent the further growth of the Larger Industrial Houses, but the
process actually worked in their favour" (GOI, 1969, p. 183). The
analysis behind this conclusion was influential in framing the MRPT Act
1969.
Growth of Business Groups Phase 2:1970-1991
This second phase of the analysis covers the period from the fourth
to the seventh Five-year plan. During this period, the scope of
legislation designed to curb the increasing concentration of private
assets in large business houses was extended significantly by the
passage of the Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Act 1969. (6)
The license raj was also continued through the IDR Act.
The MRTP Act legislation used both asset and control criteria to
classify large business groups. It covered undertakings whose assets
individually or together with the assets of its interconnected
undertakings, amounted to Rs. 20 crore or more. This limit was raised
from Rs. 20 crore to Rs. 100 crore in 1985. (7)
The analysis below is based on information reported by the
Monopolies Research Unit (MRU) in Company News and Notes. The MRU
reported the assets of business houses, the paid-up capital, turnover
and profit before tax (PBT) on a regular basis from 1971 until it was
discontinued in 2003 with the abolition of the Department of Company
Affairs. The MRTP Act's definition of a Large Business House (LBH)
is followed in the analysis.
In order to work out the share of different groupings of business
houses in the three variables reported by the MRU, their respective
population estimates were derived using the Reserve Bank of India's
(RBI) studies of the finances of both public and private limited
companies. The RBI statistics are based on a sample of companies and so
the sample results have to be extrapolated to arrive at aggregate
values. Population figures for paid-up capital alone are available and
so the ratio of 'total paid-up capital of non-Government
companies' to the 'paid-up capital of sample companies'
is used for extrapolation. A linear relationship is assumed to exist
between the paid-up capital and the extrapolated variables. (8) Table 2
presents the relative share of large business groups in total assets,
turnover, and profit before tax (PBT) of the corporate sector.
As noted above, the asset floor defining a large business house was
raised from Rs. 20 crore to Rs. 100 crore in 1985. This led to the
de-registering of many undertakings that belonged to business houses.
Sinha et al. (1990, Table 1, p. 2) estimate that as many as 309
undertakings were de-registered in 1985, following the raising of asset
limits. It also resulted in a sharp fall in the number of large business
groups covered by the MRU, from 157 to 61 between 1984 and 1985.
From Table 2 and Figure 1, two broad features can be observed.
First, between 1972 and 1984, the share of the Top-20 large business
houses in corporate India's total assets declined, while that of
other large business groups increased, particularly in the second half
of the 1970s. Second, between 1985 and 1989, the share of large business
group assets in total assets of the whole corporate sector declined.
This suggests that policy measures succeeded in slowing the growth of
large business groups between 1972 and 1989.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The share of the Top-4 business groups in turnover was
approximately the same as that of their share in assets, while the next
16 and other large business groups had a proportionately higher share in
turnover relative to their assets. This suggests that new entrants into
the ranks of large business groups were either entering into new areas
of economic activity with associated higher turnover per rupee of assets
or reflects more efficient use of assets. However, an examination of
trends in share of profits before tax (PBT) indicates that the Top-4
were able to increase the share of their operations in the PBT of
corporate India. By contrast, large business houses outside the Top-20
suffered a significant reduction in their share in PBT, even though the
number of large business houses above the Rs. 100 crore asset threshold,
had increased from 47 to 58 between 1985 and 1989.
In summary, the evidence suggests that, while policy instruments
may have facilitated the emergence of new large business houses, their
operations had a limited impact on the profitability of the Top-20.
Indeed, the Top-4 appear to have increased their share of the total
profits of corporate India between 1985 and 1989, although they lost out
significantly between 1976 and 1981 to new comers.
Growth of Business Groups Phase 3: After 1990
The year 1991 was a watershed in the history of the corporate
sector in India. There was a decisive break in the underlying political
philosophy behind the macroeconomic management of India and the
associated microeconomic policy instruments, from state intervention
towards economic liberalization. Reform measures, introduced from 1991,
removed a large number of regulatory hurdles in order to increase
competition in the domestic economy. As part of these policy changes,
the MRTP Act was amended in 1991, abolishing the asset limits on its
scope. Regulation of market dominance and abuse of market power was
extended to the operations of all firms.
This section of the paper relies on data extracted from the PROWESS
database developed by the Centre for Monitoring the Indian Economy
(CMIE). PROWESS contains comprehensive information on firms, including
coverage of all known affiliates of business groups. (9) The CMIE
follows a rigorous procedure in identifying an operating unit associated
with a particular business group, relying either on publicly available
information or accounts of management structures as described in company
annual reports. In this study, after careful scrutiny of the companies
identified as belonging to each business group in PROWESS, steps were
taken to cross-reference firm membership with each major business group,
to make sure the data-set used in the analysis contained all major units
of each business group. The CMIE's data-set was found to be
reliable in terms of completeness over the time period from 1991-92 to
2000-01. (10)
Though a wide range of company information is available in PROWESS,
three variables were selected for the analysis gross value added, net
fixed capital stock and market capitalization--for which aggregate
estimates are available from official publications. Gross value added
(11) was chosen as a measure of income and is comparable with that of
gross domestic product (GDP) as reported in the National Accounts
Statistics (NAS).
Net fixed assets were re-valued at company level. To arrive at the
total value for a business group, the assets of group companies were
added together. On examination of the year of incorporation,
unsurprisingly, it was noted that group companies were of differing
vintages and so net fixed capital stock had to be estimated at the
operating unit level. First capital stock was estimated for a chosen
base year, 1999-2000 (12) and then, using the perpetual inventory method. Such an exercise requires a revaluation factor (Rf) for each
base year. To calculate this factor, the methodology of Srivastava
(1996) was followed. It is given by
Rf = {[[(1 + g).sup.t+1] - 1][(1 + [pi]).sup.+t][(1 + g)( 1 +
[pi])] - 1]}/ {g([[(1 + g)(1 + [pi])].sup.t+1] - 1)}
where 9 = growth rate of capital formation
[pi] = growth rate of the price of capital
Net fixed capital formation was considered as a measure of capital
formation and the implicit deflator as the price of capital (Base Year
1993/4 = 100). Following the Raj Committee (GOI, 1982: Table VII-1, p.
114), 20 years was considered as the average age of net fixed assets.
The population net fixed capital stock was that of joint stock companies
as reported in the NAS.
Market capitalization was worked out by multiplying 'closing
price of shares' by 'number of shares in issue' as on the
last trading day of the financial year, which is March 31 of every year.
Aggregate market capitalization was the total capitalization of all
companies listed on the Bombay Stock Exchange (BSE).
From Table 3, it can be seen that the relative share of gross value
added of the Top-50 business groups in GDP has increased by about a
third of a percentage point. While there was a rise in the share of
gross value added to a peak in 1995-6 of 4.10 per cent of GDP at factor
cost, this share has declined steadily since then. Over the decade, the
overall rise in share has been accounted for by the Top-4 business
groups, whereas that of the remaining 46 groups has shown a decline,
particularly since 1996-97.
Against a background of the Indian economy expanding at nearly 6
per cent per annum, the Top-50 business groups' share of net fixed
capital stock has declined over the years from 73.7 per cent in 1992 to
41.6 per cent in 2001. Although the Top-4 business groups' share
has declined sharply from 39.5 per cent in 1992 to 23.1 per cent in
2001, they have actually managed to slightly increase their share of the
diminished share of the Top-50 business groups. This is because there
has been a dramatic near halving of the shares of the next 16 and the
next 30 business groups in the net fixed capital stock of all joint
stock companies.
As far as the Top-50 large business houses' share in market
capitalization is concerned, there is a clearly discernible rise from 32
per cent in 1997 to nearly 40 per cent in 2001. Closer examination of
trends shows that most of the rise in market capitalization can be
attributed to the performance of the Top-4, which together account for
nearly a quarter of total market capitalization in 2001 up from 17 per
cent in 1997.
The analysis presented above demonstrates that economic
liberalization the removal of controls and other entry barriers and
increasing domestic competition has been more effective in dispersing
economic concentration than microeconomic policy interventions, as
embodied in the IDR Act, 1951 and MRTP Act, 1969, however
well-intentioned they may have been. The ensuing expansion of the Indian
economy, in the 1990s and subsequently, has facilitated the entry and
growth of many new enterprises, not belonging to already existing large
business houses. There is also evidence that the momentum of the
de-concentration process slackened after 1997. The growth in the share
of market capitalization of the Top-4 large business houses does give
rise to concern, although 1997 to 2001 was a period of considerable
turbulence on the Bombay Stock Exchange and so may simply represent a
short-term flight to quality in a time of uncertainty.
The second part of this paper examines in more detail the movement
of large business groups in and out of the Top-50.
Part 2
The Persistence of Large Business Groups:
This part of the paper is divided into two sections. The first part
covers the period 1951 to 1990, when the government of India was
actively engaged in the microeconomic management of the growth of large
business houses. The second part covers the period from 1991, when the
government abandoned direct controls in favour of liberalization and
progressive opening of the Indian economy to international investment
and competition.
Trends in Business Group Rankings between 1951 and 1990;
The ranking of the Top-20 business groups in selected years from
1951 to 1990 is presented in Table 4. The procedure used to obtain these
rankings was first, the Top-20 groups in 1990 were ranked in ascending
order. Then, their rank in earlier years was benchmarked backwards until
1951. This exercise was restricted to those business groups that
appeared at least once in the Top-20 in any year from 1951 to 1989. All
rankings are based on total net assets, except for 1951 and 1958 when
gross capital stock was used.
Despite the government's policy interventions to restrict
concentration of economic power, it is clear from Table 4 that this did
not have the desired impact on the growth of very large business groups.
For example, the Tata and Birla Groups maintained their position in the
Top-2 all through the period of regulatory intervention. Moreover, J K
Singhania, Thapar, and Mafatlal retained their positions in the Top- 10
for eighteen years from 1972 to 1990. The only major breakthrough into
the top rank of Indian business houses was that of the Reliance Group,
ranked 67th in 1976, but ranked third after 1986.
A less stringent test of the impact of the regulatory framework on
the growth of business groups is to examine movements in and out of the
Top-20. Here there is more evidence of changes in the ranking of
business houses. For example, of the Top-20 in 1951, only eleven groups
figure in the Top-20 ranking for 1972 and only nine survive into the
Top-20 list of 1990. Furthermore, some of the groups in the Top-20 of
1990, were late entrants, such as MA Chidambaram that entered in 1985,
Bajaj in 1979 and Modi in 1976. And, finally, most of the new groups,
which entered after 1971, had moved up into the third quartile by 1989,
while well-established groups, such as Bangur, Walchand, ACC and Shri
Ram were pushed back from the top to the bottom half of the Top-20.
Several groups belonging to the Top-20 in the 1950s and 1960s had
disappeared from the Top-50 after 1970. Apart from European-controlled
groups that were nationalised in the 1970s, notable losers were Indra
Singh, Seshasayee, and Shapoorji.
Table 5 summarises the overall movement of business groups in and
out of the Top-20 by comparing movements over a one year time period for
various years from 1972 to 1989.
The data confirms that the proportion of business groups in the
Top-20 retaining their rank from one year to the next increases between
1972 and 1989. Conversely more business groups drop out of the Top-20 in
the earlier years. This implies that the large business groups were
beginning to accumulate sufficient market power and assets to protect
their positions of dominance in the Indian economy by the latter half of
the 1980s.
Trends in Business Group Rankings after 1990:
Since the mid-1980s, India's Top-3 business houses have
remained Reliance, (13) Tata (14) and Birla (15) (Table 6). However, a
major change has been the displacement of the Tata Group from the top
position by the Reliance Group (Ambani). Lower down the rankings, six
business groups have moved out of the Top-20 between 1991-92 and
2000-01. On a year-on-year basis, there is noticeably greater churn in
business groups moving in and out of the Top-20 by comparison with the
period 1972 to 1990 (Table 7). (16)
Closer examination of the companies moving into the Top-20 reveals
the increasing prominence of groups heavily involved in the new economy,
especially software-related businesses and telecommunications. A few of
the older groups have moved up the rankings by exploiting new market
opportunities. For example, Bajaj, Hero and TVS have all contributed to
and benefited from the phenomenal growth in the demand for two wheelers
from an increasingly affluent urban population in the 1990s.
Many of the business opportunities realised by rising large
business groups are in part a product of the easing of controls over
sector-related policies, such as, controls on the importation of
computer hardware and telecommunications equipment. This relaxation of
controls has enabled business groups such as WIPRO and HCL to exploit
information technology and to operate in the global market place where
demand for software services originates. Other groups, such as Hero and
TVS, rely more on domestic demand, while the easing of policies has
allowed them to obtain the necessary technology through collaboration
agreements with foreign partners, mostly from Japan.
Similarly, the de-reservation of certain strategic sectors like oil
exploration and refining, petrochemicals, steel and telecommunications,
which used to be the exclusive monopoly of the public sector until 1991,
has also helped a few already large business houses to move away from
their earlier core businesses and grow even larger. Thus the rapid
growth of the Reliance Group, in the 1990s, owes more to its
diversification into petroleum refining and petrochemical production
than its original core business as a textile house and its bedrock in
the 1970s and 1980s.
Economic growth stimulated by the reforms introduced after 1991 has
also created new business opportunities. As domestic demand has grown,
liberalization has encouraged market-seeking foreign investors to form
alliances with business groups, thereby changing the profile of
associated business groups in India. Though the very large business
houses of the 'old regime' continue to become stronger,
including through investing heavily in the new economy, economic reform
has certainly facilitated the growth of new business groups. It has also
reduced the relative performance of some of the older groups.
The survival, and indeed reconfiguration and expansion, of some of
the old business groups testify to the persistence of entrepreneurship
in India even in a highly restrictive business climate. Had Indian
business groups grown only by deriving benefits from a restrictive and
protective policy regime, they would not have survived or flourished in
the competitive post-1991 business climate, nor would they be as
prominent as they are today. The reform process has opened up new
opportunities for growth, which were recognized and exploited by
business groups. Entrepreneurship may have been seriously distorted by
the license raj regime but it survived. The decline of some previously
dominant business groups and the emergence of new ones lend credence to
Schumpeter's remarks on the rise and fall of the entrepreneurial
class:
"... the entrepreneurial function is not only the vehicle of
continual reorganization of the economic system but also the vehicle of
continued changes in the elements which comprise the upper strata of
society. The successful entrepreneur rises socially, and with him his
family, who acquire from the fruits of his success a position not
immediately dependent upon personal conduct. This represents the most
important factor of rise in the social scale in the capitalist world.
Because it proceeds by competitively destroying old businesses and hence
the existence of people dependent upon them, there always corresponds to
it a process of decline, or loss of caste, or elimination. ... This is
not only because all individual profits dry up, the competitive
mechanism tolerating no permanent surplus values, but rather
annihilating them by means of just this stimulus of the striving for
profit which is the mechanism's driving force; but also because in
the normal case things so happen that entrepreneurial success embodies
itself in the ownership of a business." (Schumpeter, 1934: pp.
155-156)
Conclusions
This paper has examined the growth of Indian business groups in
terms of the increase or decrease in the relative shares of business
groups in some important macroeconomic indicators. Paradoxically, it was
found that the Top-20 business groups grew between 1951 and 1969, even
though the licensing regime was arguably at its most restrictive.
However, this growth was arrested during the following period, from 1970
to 1991, when both licensing and controls over assets under the MRTP Act
were in force. Since 1991 and the repeal of restrictive legislation,
there has been a decline in the growth of some business groups together
with consolidation of the position of the Top-3 large business
houses--Reliance, Tata and Birla.
The paper then evaluated the persistence of business groups by
analyzing changes in the ranking of individual groups. After 1991, it
was observed that, except for the top three groups, there was
considerable churning in the ranking of the remaining Top-20 business
groups. A few of the highly ranked groups from before 1991 have survived
in the Top-20 in 2000-01 but they do not retain their earlier and higher
ranked positions.
The growth and decline of large business houses in India appears to
be an evolutionary process. Many well-known groups of the 1950s could
not survive in the 1960s, and hitherto unranked groups have surged ahead
in the 1970s and 1980s. During the 1990s, while the Top-3 very large
business groups have increased their market capitalization, new or
already existing smaller groups have generally replaced erstwhile
dominant groups. An important feature of this evolution is that large
business groups together still define the landscape of wealth
accumulation in India.
Inevitably, this leads to the question of whether such groups
contribute towards the concentration of wealth in the economy, as was
widely believed at the time of drafting the Indian Constitution. It
remains an important question but cannot be answered without systematic
analysis of the decision making and governance structures of large
business groups which is beyond the scope of this paper.
References
Ahuja, P K. (1986). Corporate sector under the purview of the MRTP
Act, 1969. Company News & Notes, Vol. XXIV (2), 1-6.
Baskar, M V. (1992). Concentration in Indian Manufacturing
Industry, 1970-1990, Unpublished M. Phil Dissertation submitted to
Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi, Thiruvanthapuram: Centre for
Development Studies.
Chandra, N K, (1981). Monopoly capital, private corporate sector
and the Indian economy: a study in relative growth, 1931-1976. In AK
Bagchi and N Banerjee (eds.), Change and Choice in Indian Industry.
Calcutta: KP Bagchi & Co., 299-381.
Datta, B. (1970a). The monopolies legislation: A measure to prevent
concentration of economic power, Company News & Notes, Vol. VIII
(l&2), January 1 & 16, pp. 17, 27-31.
Datta, B. (1970b). Growth of industrial houses: a survey for the
period 1963-64 to 1967-68, Company News & Notes, Vol. VIII
(9&10), May 1 & 16, pp. 1-12.
Fogel, K. (2006). Oligarchic family control, social economic
outcomes, and the quality of government, Journal of International
Business Studies Vol. 37 (5): 603 -622.
Government of India. (1965). Report of the Monopolies Inquiry
Commission 1965, New Delhi: Ministry of Finance (Chairman: Shri. KC Das
Gupta). Volume I and II: 3-10, 33.
Government of India. (1966). Industrial Planning and Licensing
Policy Interim Report to Planning Commission, New Delhi: Planning
Commission.
Government of India. (1969). Report of the Industrial Licensing
Policy Inquiry Committee (Main Report) New Delhi: Ministry of Industrial
Development (Chairman: Shri. Subimal Dutt), pp. 4-15.
Government of India. (1978). Report of the High Powered Expert
Committee on Companies Act and MRTP Act, New Delhi: Ministry of Law,
Justice, and Company Affairs (DCA).
Government of India. (1979). Report of the Committee on Industrial
Licensing, New Delhi: Ministry of Industry.
Government of India. (1982). Capital Formation and Saving in India
1950/51 to 1979/80, Report of The Working Group on Savings. Department
of Statistics, Ministry of Planning, New Delhi: Reserve Bank of India.
Government of India. (1985). Report of The Committee to Examine
Principles of a Possible Shift from Physical to Financial Controls, New
Delhi: Ministry of Finance, Department of Economic Affairs.
Government of India. (1999). New Series on National Accounts
Statistics (Base Year 1993-94), New Delhi: Central Statistical
Organisation, Ministry of Planning and Programme Implementation.
Government of India. (2001). National Accounts Statistics Back
Series 1950-51 - 1992-93, New Delhi: Central Statistical Organisation,
Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation.
Government of India. (2004). National Accounts Statistics, New
Delhi: Central Statistical Organisation, Ministry of Statistics and
Programme Implementation.
Goyal, S. K. (1970). The concept and measurement of concentration
of economic power, Company News & Notes, Vol. VIII (3&4),
February 1 & 16, pp. 1-6.
Hazari, R. K. (1967). The Structure of the Corporate Private
Sector: A Study of Concentration, Ownership and Control, London: Asia
Publishing House.
Khanna, T., and Palepu, K.G. (2004). The Evolution of Concentrated
Ownership in India Broad Patterns and a History of the Indian Software
Industry, NBER Working Paper 10613, Cambridge: NBER.
Khanna, T. and Palepu, K. (2000). Is group affiliation profitable
in emerging markets? An analysis of diversified Indian business groups,
Journal of Finance, 55 (2):867-891.
Khanna, T. and Rivkin, J. (2001). Estimating the performance
effects of business groups in emerging markets, Strategic Management
Journal, 22 (1):45-74.
Morck, R. and Yeung, B. (2004). Family control and the rent-seeking
society, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 29 (4): 391-409
Piramal, G. (1996). Business Maharajas, New Delhi: Penguin Books.
Rajakumar, J. D. (2003). How real are estimates of corporate
investment? Economic and Political Weekly, XXXVIII (2):2155-2158.
Reserve Bank of India. Reserve Bank of India Bulletin, Bombay:
Reserve Bank of India, various issues.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The Theory of Economic Development,
Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Securities and Exchange Board of India. (2004). Handbook of
Statistics on the Indian Securities Market, Mumbai: SEBI
Shanta, N. and Rajakumar, J..D. (1999). Corporate statistics: The
missing numbers. Journal of Indian School of Political Economy,
11(4):655-668.
Shaw, G.A. (1971). Prevention of concentration of economic power
and monopolies and restrictive trade practices through corporate laws.
Company News & Notes, Special Number, Vol. 9 (l&2), January, pp.
41-48.
Sinha KAD, Behari, R., and Jhangiani, A. (1990). A review of
undertaking registered under the MRTP Act, 1969 (As on 30th June, 1990),
Company News & Notes, Vol. XXVIII (2), August, pp. 17.
Srivastava, V. (1996). Liberalization, Productivity and
Competition: A Panel Study of Indian Manufacturing, New Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
World Bank. (2007). Doing Business in South Asia 2007, Washington
DC: World Bank, February.
World Bank. (2006). Doing Business in 2007--How to Reform.
Washington DC: World Bank, September.
by
J. Dennis Rajakumar
ICFAI Business School, India
John S. Henley
The University of Edinburgh, UK
Endnotes
* We would like to thank the Charles Wallace India Trust for
providing the CWIT Visiting Fellowship that enabled Dr Rajakumar to
visit the University of Edinburgh and complete this paper. We wish to
thank Dr. M. Vijayabaskar for the useful comments received on an earlier
version of the paper.
(1) Article 39 (b) and (c) of the Constitution reads as follows:
".. the State shall, in particular direct its policy towards
securing -(1) that the ownership and control of the material resources
of the community are so distributed as best to sub-serve the common
goal; and (2) that the operation of the economic system does not result
in concentration of wealth and the means of production to the common
detriment" (Cited in Datta, 1970a, p. 27).
(2) In this paper, the terms large business group and large
business house (LBH) are used interchangeably.
(3) These included Mahalanobis Committee in 1960, the Monopoly
Inquiry Commission (GOI, 1965), Hazari Committee (GOI, 1966), and Dutt
Committee (GOI, 1969).
(4) Rs. 1 Crore equals Rs. 10 million
(5) Also see Goyal (1970) and Chandra (1981).
(6) The preamble to the MRTP Act slates that its objectives are:
"(a) that the operation of the economic system does not result in
the concentration of economic power, to the common detriment, (b)
control of monopolies and (c) prohibition of monopolistic and
restrictive trade practices" (Cited in Ahuja, 1986, p. 1). The Act
sought to control both assets and market dominance. However, Sinha,
Behari, and Jhangiani, (1990) show that the regulation of undertakings
was more due to the size of their assets than any assessment of their
market dominance. The MRTP Act's definition of a Large Business
House (LBH) is followed in the analysis of the growth of business groups
from 1970-1991 reported in this paper.
(7) The asset limit of Rs. 20 crore remained unchanged until 1985,
despite significant inflation in the country. This became a contentious
issue for industrialists. Though industry representatives submitted a
memorandum to raise the limit to Rs. 50 crore, the Sachar Committee did
not find it necessary to raise the limit (GOI, 1978, p. 303).The Nanda
Study Group, the following year, proposed that the asset limit was
anyway irrelevant in an inflationary environment and instead, suggested
using market dominance as the criterion for coverage of the MRTP Act
(GOI, 1979, p. 32). While reinstating the use of the asset criterion,
the Narasimbam Committee suggested raising the limit to Rs. 75 crore,
despite industry representatives suggesting a floor of Rs. 100 crore
(GOI, 1985, p. 7).
(8) This methodology is widely used for bud ng up population
estimates such as for private corporate investment and savings, and net
fixed capital stock of joint stock companies (GOI, 1999). Rajakumar
(2003) has argued that population estimates are very sensitive to the
extrapolation factors used.
(9) Shanta and Rajakumar (1999) discuss the unique features of
PROWESS compared with other major sources of data on the corporate
sector in India.
(10) The CMIE updates PROWESS as and when new information about a
company is available. The present analysis uses data available up to
August, 2005. We do not rule out the possibility of the exclusion of a
few companies from the business groups identified by PROWESS.
(11) It is the sum of; (a) salaries, wages and bonuses, (b)
provident fund, (c) employee welfare expenses, (d) managerial
remuneration, (e) rent paid net of rent received, (f) interest paid net
of interest received, (g) tax provisions, (h) dividends paid net of
dividends received, (i) retained profit net of non-operating
surplus/deficit, and (j) depreciation.
(12) The year 1999-2000 was chosen as the base year because every
company had reported net fixed assets for that year.
(13) Reliance owes its growth to the unparalleled entrepreneurship
of its founder the late Dhirubhai Ambani. (Piramal, 1996, pp. 164-174).
The group has been split between the two sons of Dhirubhai Ambani, since
his death. The elder son, Mukesh Ambani, has retained control of the
former flagship company of the group, known as Reliance Industries
Limited, which is the largest company operating in the petroleum
refining and petrochemicals sectors in India, along with other
companies. The younger son, Anil Ambani, has retained Reliance Energy,
which is significant in the power sector, Reliance Infocomm, which is a
major mobile phone and telecommunications company and Reliance Capital.
(14) Tara Group is managed by Tata Sons, which is a private holding
company of the many group companies and is partly owned by those
companies as well. The Tata Group is the only top business group that
has a presence in almost every area of economic activity: Tara Steel
(formerly TISCO), Tara Motors (formerly TELCO), Taj Hotels which has a
presence in all major Indian cities, Tata Teleservices, a large
telecommunications company owning mobile phone franchises under the
brand Tata Indicom. Tata Power, "rata Tea and Tata Consultancy
Service (TCS), the largest software company in India.
(15) Birla Group was split up among family members with the Aditya
Birla Group becoming the largest business group. Kumaramangalam Birla,
the only son of the founder Aditya Birla, now manages the Aditya Birla
Group.
(16) Hindustan Lever, ITC and ICI are not included in the data set
because PROWESS does not report these companies as Large Business
Houses.
Table 1: Share of business groups in
private corporate assets in India, 1951-1968
Years Top 4 Next 16 Top 20 Others All
1951 * 20.44 16.61 37.05 n.a. n.a.
1958 * 25.66 19.19 44.85 n.a. n.a.
1963-64 ** 16.89 15.17 32.06 14.88 (55) 46.94 (75)
1967-68 *** 19.62 17.08 36.69 17.08 (53) 53.77 (73)
Note:
* Ratio of total gross capital stock of business groups to total
gross capital stock of non-Government public companies (Hazari,
1967, pp. 36-37).
** Ratio of total assets of the business groups to total assets of
all non-Government and non-banking compa- nies (GOI, 1965, pp.
119-122).
*** Ratio of total assets of business groups to assets of all
non-Government and non-banking companies fol- lowing the Dart
Committee's (1969) definition (Datta, 19706, pp. 3-4).
n.a.: not available
Figures in brackets indicate numbers of large business groups
Table 2: Share of business groups in assets, turnover and profits
before tax of the private corporate sector in India, 1972-1989
Years Top 4 Next 16 Top 20 Others All
Total Assets
1972 12.53 12.69 25.22 14.74 (54) 39.96 (74)
1976 11.50 11.73 23.23 14.61 (61) 37.84 (81)
1981 12.29 11.78 24.07 16.54 (81) 40.61 (101)
1984 11.99 11.25 23.24 18.02 (137) 41.26 (157)
1984 * 11.99 11.25 23.24 10.69 (41) 33.93 (61)
1985 11.53 11.84 23.37 10.81 (47) 34.18 (67)
1989 11.50 9.39 20.89 9.45 (58) 30.34 (78)
Turnover
1972 11.86 13.68 25.54 17.11 42.65
1976 11.31 12.65 23.96 17.83 41.79
1981 12.66 13.14 25.80 19.99 45.79
1985 11.16 12.24 23.40 11.11 34.51
1989 10.62 12.60 23.22 11.05 34.27
Profit before Tax
1972 13.97 13.61 27.58 16.43 44.01
1976 14.76 12.91 27.67 15.63 43.30
1981 11.39 11.58 22.97 17.70 40.67
1985 12.34 12.68 25.02 10.73 35.75
1989 15.95 10.99 26.94 7.91 34.85
Note:
Figures in brackets are the number of large
business houses identified under the MRTP Act.
* Based on Annexure II of Ahuja (1986, pp. 4-5)
Source: Company News and Notes, various issues
Table 3: Percentage share of business groups in
macroeconomic indicators, 1991-92 to 2000-01
Years Top 4 Next 16 Top 20 Next 30 Top 50
GDP at Factor Cost *
1991-92 1.49 1.01 2.50 0.60 3.10
1992-93 1.48 0.98 2.46 0.63 3.09
1993-94 1.46 1.06 2.51 0.64 3.15
1994-95 1.75 1.13 2.88 0.82 3.70
1995-96 2.02 1.19 3.21 0.89 4.10
1996-97 1.74 1.16 2.90 0.84 3.74
1997-98 1.71 1.12 2.83 0.76 0.30
1998-99 1.64 0.99 2.63 0.69 3.32
1999-2000 1.67 0.99 2.66 0.68 3.34
2000-01 1.92 0.88 2.84 0.57 3.41
Net Fixed Capital Stock **
(at end of March)
1992 39.5 22.0 61.5 12.2 73.7
1993 36.1 19.2 55.3 11.2 66.4
1994 35.6 17.4 53.0 10.6 63.6
1995 32.3 16.8 49.1 9.9 59.0
1996 27.9 14.7 42.6 8.7 51.3
1997 24.6 13.5 38.1 8.1 46.2
1998 23.4 13.0 36.4 7.8 44.2
1999 23.6 12.7 36.3 7.3 43.7
2000 24.0 12.8 36.8 7.2 44.0
2001 23.1 11.8 34.9 6.7 41.6
BSE Market Capitalization ***
(at end of March)
1997 17.0 6.1 23.1 8.9 32.0
1998 13.8 6.0 19.8 8.2 28.0
1999 13.4 9.2 22.6 11.4 34.0
2000 26.5 7.6 34.1 9.2 43.3
2001 23.7 7.2 30.9 8.9 39.8
Note:
* Ratio of 'gross value added of a group' to GDP at factor cost at
current price (with 1993-94 as base year).
** Ratio of 'net fixed capital stock of a group' to 'net fixed
capital stock of joint stock companies' at current price (with
1993-94 as base year).
*** Ratio of 'market capitalization of the listed group companies'
to 'market capitalization of all companies listed' on the Bombay
Stock Exchange.
Sources: For GDP and net fixed capital stock of joint stock
companies. GOI (2001 and 2004) For market capitalization of the
Bombay Stock Exchange, SEBI (2004)
Table 4: The Top-20 large business groups, 1951 to 1990
Name of Business Group 1990 1986 1981 1976 1972
Birla 1 1 2 2 2
Tata 2 2 1 1 1
Reliance 3 3 11 67
JK Singhania 4 4 4 4 8
Thapar 5 5 5 6 4
Mafatlal 6 6 3 3 3
Bajaj 7 10 20
Modi 8 7 15 18
Larsen & Toubro 9 8 19 14 15
MA Chidambarain 10 9 66
TVS Iyengar 11 15 17
Hindustan Lever 12 18 14 17 17
ACC 13 11 6 12 6
Shri Rain 14 14 12 10 9
ITC 15 16 19
United Breweries 16
ICI 17 20 7 7 5
Bangor 18 12 9 8 7
Kirloskar 19 17 10 13 13
Walchand 20 13 15 12
Other groups that made
into the Top-20 at least once
Mahindra & Mahindra 21 19 18 16 14
Sarabhai 29 8 19
Ashok Leyland 28 13 10
Seindia 78 16 9 11
Oil India 22 5
Chowgule 36
Bhiwandiwala 33 11 16
Kasturbhai Lalbhai 25 18
Khatau 38
Macneil & Magor 32 20 20
Parry 69
Martin Burn
Sahu Jain 50
Bird Heilgers
Surajmull Nagarmull
Esso
Goenka 22
Andrew Yule
Killicks
Kilachand
Ramakrishna 48
Indra Singh
Seshayee
Shapoorji
Name of Business Group 1968 1966 1964 1958 1951
Birla 2 2 2 2 2
Tata 1 1 1 1 1
Reliance
JK Singhania 12 12 9 10 10
Thapar 9 5 6 9 12
Mafatlal 4 7 15 12 8
Bajaj 30
Modi 55
Larsen & Toubro
MA Chidambarain
TVS Iyengar 27
Hindustan Lever
ACC 8 8 5
Shri Rain 6 10 12 8 7
ITC
United Breweries
ICI 20 19
Bangor 5 4 4 6 13
Kirloskar 19 36 19 18
Walchand 10 9 11 13 11
Other groups that made
into the Top-20 at least once
Mahindra & Mahindra 14 16 16 16 19
Sarabhai
Ashok Leyland 15 17 13
Seindia
Oil India
Chowgule
Bhiwandiwala 20 18
Kasturbhai Lalbhai 11 9
Khatau 17 15 20 14
Macneil & Magor
Parry 3 3 3
Martin Burn 11 14 7 3 3
Sahu Jain 13 11 8 4 4
Bird Heilgers 7 6 10 5 5
Surajmull Nagarmull
Esso 16 13 14
Goenka 17
Andrew Yule 18 19 18 7 6
Killicks 20
Kilachand
Ramakrishna 14 17
Indra Singh 15 15
Seshayee 17 16
Shapoorji 18 20
Notes:
Groups reported for 1951 and 1958 follow definitions by Hazari
(1967), for 1964 as defined by MIC (GOI, 1965), and for 1966 and
1968 as defined by the Dutt Committee (GOT, 1969).
Groups such as Bird Heilgers and Andrew Yule were
European-controlled and Martin Burn was partly European Controlled
(Hazari, 1967, p. 21). The government nationalised the Andrew Yule
and Martin Burn groups in the early seventies and management of
many companies belonging to the Bird Heilgers group also came under
government control as a result of financial difficulties (Chandra,
1981, p. 332). Macneil & Magor, another European-controlled group,
had most of its assets taken over by RP Goenka.
Sources: For 1951 and 1958, Hazari (1967, p. 17).
For 1964, GOT (1965, pp. 119-122).
For 1966 and 1968. Datta (1970b, pp. 7-8).
For other years, Company News & Notes, various issues.
Table 5: Changes in the ranking of business groups, 1972-1989
Top-20 Large Business Groups
Years Retained rank Moving up Moving down Dropped out
1989 (a) 11 5 4 0
1986 (a) 9 5 5 1
1981 (a) 9 3 6 2
1976 (a) 5 3 9 3
1972 (a) 5 7 2 6
Note: Movements are calculated by comparison
with the immediately preceding year
Source: a Company News & Notes, various issues.
Table 6: The Top-20 Large Business Groups, 1991-02 to 2000-01
(Based on relative shares in GDP)
Name of the Group 2000-01 1995-96 1991-92
Reliance Group [Ambani] 1 3 3
Tata Group 2 1 1
Birla Group 3 2 2
Larsen & Toubro Group 4 5 6
T.V. S. Iyengar Group 5 8 10
RPG Enterprises Group 6 4 8
WIPRO Group 7 46 45
Mahindra & Mahindra Group 8 10 15
Bajaj Group 9 6 7
Om Prakash Jindal Group 10 23 39
Essar (Ruia) Group 11 11 19
J.K. Singhania Group 12 9 5
Videocon Group 13 35 33
HCL Group 14 36 31
Hero (Munjals) Group 15 43 40
Chidambaram M.A. Group 16 13 13
Muru gappa Chettiar Group 17 20 14
DCM Group 18 16 21
Thapar Group 19 7 4
Bangur Group 20 22 17
Other Groups that made
the Top-20 at least once
ACC Group 21 14 9
Escorts Group 22 15 20
Nagarjuna Group 23 17 47
Godrej Group 24 28 23
Wadia (Bombay Dyeing) Group 26 19 16
Williamson Magor Group 28 27 18
Modi Umesh Kumar 30 21 12
Kirloskar Group 31 18 27
Lalbhai Group 45 18 22
Arvind Mafatlal Group 46 12 11
Source: PROWESS
Table 7: Changes in the ranking of business groups, 1991-92 to 2000-01
Top-20 Large Business Groups
Years Retained rank Moving up Moving down Moved out
2000-01 3 8 9 --
1999-2000 5 10 4 1
1998-99 7 4 5 4
1997-98 6 4 6 4
1996-97 4 5 5 6
1995-96 5 5 4 6
1994-95 6 5 3 6
1993-94 5 4 6 5
1992-93 5 5 5 5
Note: The comparison for each year is with the immediately preceding
year.
Source: PROWESS