Effect of price limits on volatility and stock returns in emerging markets: evidence from the Johannesburg stock exchange.
Ngassam, Christopher
Christopher Ngassam *
This study provides additional empirical evidence on effects of
price limits on stock price volatility in emerging markets using data
from the Johannesburg, South Africa (JSE), stock exchange. It is found
that price limit rates of stocks on the ISE vary cross-sectionally
according to stock price levels and that it is possible to control for
other factors besides price limits in examining effects of price limits
on stock price volatility. When return volatilities between high price
limit portfolios (HPLP) and low price limit portfolios (LPLP)
constructed on the basis of ranked price limit rates are compared, the
results show that price limits serve to reduce stock price volatility on
the JSE. Although the findings reported here hold useful policy
implications for policy makers and regulators, several avenues for
future research on some unanswered questions are identified.
INTRODUCTION
Capital markets are essential to preventing underutilization and
waste of resources in an economy faced with declining real value of its
currency. In most emerging markets today, capital markets afford the
opportunity to millions of savers to invest their savings in various
productive assets that act as a hedge against erosion of purchasing
power. The ability to buy a claim on a fraction of a real asset and the
concomitant diversification possibilities for an investor with limited
resources is valuable to individuals as well as the society as a whole.
Stock price volatility in developed and emerging markets around the
world has received much attention in the popular press over the last few
years, especially since the stock market crash on October 19, 1987.
Stock price volatility unrelated to variation in fundamental values or
'noise' is considered socially wasteful. It obscures the
information in prices about resource allocation. It can increase the
expected returns that investors require to hold stock, which means
higher cost of capital for firms and less capital investment. Therefore,
academicians and policy-makers have been much concerned with the
micro-structure of the stock market to protect it from great fluctuation
caused by speculative and noise tradings. Circuit breakers have been
recommended as mechanisms for reducing or controlling stock price
volatility. The most common and perhaps the most primitive type of
circuit breakers is maximum price change limits.
Theoretically, however, it is not clear whether the imposition of
price limits will bring about the desired effect of reducing stock
market volatility. A commonly cited benefit ascribed to price
fluctuations limits is that such measures provide a cooling--off period
allowing investors to re-evaluate markey information so that investment
strategies can be formulated. It also allows order imbalances to be
publicized to attract value traders that could bring back equilibrium.
Opponents against price fluctuation limits argue that they serve no
purpose other than to slow down or delay the price change. They say that
even though it can stop the rice of a share from free falling on the
trading day when a shock hits, the price will continue to move in the
direction towards equilibrium as new trading limits are established in
subsequent trading days. According to this point of view, price limits
only prolong the number of trading days for the market to adopt a
disturbance.
Given the above contrasting views, the effect of price limits on
stock price volatility is therefore an empirical issue to be tested.
However, there is relative paucity of empirical literature on the
effects of price limits in emerging stock markets. The purpose of this
study is to provide additional empirical evidence on the effects of
price limits on stock price volatility in emerging markets using data
from the Johannesburg, South Africa (JSE), stock exchange. The remainder
of this paper is organizes as follows. The next section reviews the
literature on the effect of price limits on stock price volatility.
Research design and data are described in the third section. The fourth
section presents empirical results while section five concludes the
paper with recommendations for further research.
LITERATURE ON PRICE LIMITS AND VOLATILITY
The study by Ma, Rao, and Sears (1989) focused on the effect of
price limits on future prices. They found that price limits may provide
a cooling-off period for the market and be accompanied by substantial
reduction in volatility. Chiang, Wei, Wu (1990), Chung (1991), and Chen
(1992), however, did not uncover significant evidence that price limits
reduce the volatility of the stock market in Taiwan and Korea.
In examining the effect of price limits on stock price volatility
empirically, it is very important to control for other variables besides
price limits that may affect stock price volatility. For instance, if
the effect of price limits on stock market volatility is investigated
simply through comparing the volatilities as measured by the standard
deviation of returns for some trading days before and after price limit
moves or changes in price limit rate, it could lead to a spurious conclusion because of the time-varying property of stock market
volatility. To solve such a problem, Chen (1992) tried to control for
the determinants of stock market volatility by constructing a regression
model with a few explanatory variables (for example, macro economic and
financial volatility) to explain the sources of stock market volatility.
However, since the volatilities of a variety of macro economic variables
explain a relatively small part of the movements in stock market
volatility, as Schwert (1989) suggests, such an approach may lead to
only a partial solution to the problem.
Until recently, the minimum price change increment in the United
States equity markets was 1/8th of a dollar. On June 2, 1997 and June
24, 1997, the minimum price increment was lowered from 1/8th to 1/16th
of a dollar for most stocks on Nasdaq and the NYSE, respectively. To
date, debate continues about the impact of further
"decimalization", to 1/100th of a dollar or smaller, on order
flow and transaction costs. At first blush, it seems evident that
minimum price increments induce artificially wide spreads, and that
bid-ask spreads of many firms (especially low-priced firms) are
artificially wide. However, the empirical evidence suggests that
decimalization may not improve the welfare of all market participants.
Before the change in Nasdaq rules, several studies examined the effects
of minimum price variations. For example, although Harris (1994) does
not analyze actual reductions in market tick size, he estimates the
impact of changes in minimum price variations by characterizing the
relation between price l evels, spreads, depth and trading volume. His
evidence suggests that a smaller tick size (relative minimum price
variation) may yield narrower spreads but would also result in less
depth. This follows from the argument that if the price of liquidity
(the spread) is lowered all else being constant, the quantity supplied
(the depth) will fall. The analysis by Harris (1994) is well supported
by subsequent empirical evidence. Harris (1996, 1997a) examines the
Paris Bourse and Toronto Stock Exchange and finds that smaller tick
sizes discourage order exposure (the placement of limit orders) by
raising the expected profits of front-running (placing an order one-tick
ahead of limit orders). Bacidore (1997) and Porter and Weaver (1998)
find that quoted and effective spreads generally decline after the
Toronto Stock Exchange lowered the tick size on April 15, 1996.
Goldstein and Kavajecz (1999) report a decrease in depth across the
entire limit order book after the NYSE adopted the 1/16th minimum price
increment. Final ly, Jones and Lipson (1999) analyze a sample of
institutional trades and find that the move to sixteenths increased
trading costs as a direct result of its adverse effect on depth. The
evidence, therefore, does not unambiguously support the decimalization
of prices. As always, there are tradeoffs. Although the lower price
obtainable through decimalization can lower the cost of trading,
particularly for small orders, the cost of executing large orders may
increase, due to the adverse effect of decimalization on depth. Harris
(1997b,c) provides extensive reviews of research on this topic.
A segment of previous studies on the effects of price limits on
volatility examines the pros and cons of using price limits to control
stock market volatility. The Brady report (1987) for example, suggested
that the introduction of a circuit breaker system, including price
limits, has three benefits. First, it limits credit risks and loss of
financial confidence by providing a 'time-out' amid frenetic trading to settle up and ensure that everyone is solvent. Second, it
facilitates price discovery by providing a 'time-out' to
pause, evaluate, inhibit panic, and publicize order imbalances to
attract value traders to cushion violent movements in the market.
Finally, circuit breaker mechanisms counter the illusion of liquidity by
formalizing the economic fact of life, so apparent in the 1987 October
crash, that markets have a limited capacity to absorb massive one-sided
volume. Making circuit breakers part of the contractual landscape makes
it far more difficult for some market participants (pension portfolio
ins urers, and aggressive mutual funds) to mislead themselves into
believing that it is possible to sell huge amounts in a short period of
time.
The findings by Ma, Rao and Sears (1989) is consistent with this
viewpoint. Using minute-by-minute data, they compared the return
volatilities between pre-limit and post-limit periods and found that
price limit moves are followed by reduced volatility. However, Roll
(1987) argued that the fact that price limits reduce volatility does not
constitute unambiguous evidence that reduced volatility after a limit
move is equally consistent with a reduction in the amount of news
received relative to the pre-limit move period and the limit move
period. We really need information about whether the imposition of price
limits reduces overall volatility in all periods.
Fama (1987) opposed the introduction of the circuit breaker as a
market rule to reduce noise or unnecessary volatility in price and
doubted its usefulness. He argued that this system results in the
reduction of the supply and liquidity when the demand increases. Rather,
it could increase the price volatility by inciting trading in
anticipation of halts. He insisted that this system can only delay the
adjustment of price to changes in fundamental values. Fama's
argument is consistent with the study of Roll (1987), which showed
empirically that the market decline of each country during the crash of
October 1987 is similar irrespective of the price limits. The result of
Roll's study indicates that price limits can influence price
adjustment speed, but do not have any effect on the size of the price
adjustment.
A theory of price limits in futures markets developed by Brennan
(1986) focus on their effectiveness in preventing futures traders from
reneging on contracts. Brennan's theory predicts that price limits
will disappear in futures markets that have closely correlated cash
markets, a prediction more or less satisfied by the existing markets in
the United States. This suggestive evidence against the proposition that
price limits should be used to reduce volatility. Sholler (1981) argued
that the observed volatility in stock return is excessive in the sense
that it cannot be explained solely by the uncertainty of future real
dividend. French and Roll (1986) formalized this argument and suggested
that volatility may be related to trading motivated by public or private
information, or by traders' overreaction ('noise').
Schwert (1989) showed that the estimates of standard deviation of
monthly stock returns vary from two to twenty percent per month during
the 1957-1987 period in the US stock market. Furthermore, test s for
whether these large differences could be attributable to estimation
error strongly reject the hypothesis of constant variance.
DATA AND METHODOLOGY
Do price limits reduce the volatility of the stock market? To
provide a more reliable empirical answer to this question, it is very
important to control for ocher factors besides price limits which may
affect the volatility of the stock market. As mentioned before, the
empirical results obtained simply by comparing the volatilities of the
stock market for some trading days before and after changes in the price
limit rate, may be contaminated by the effects of factors other that the
price limit system.
To protect stock investors from abrupt fluctuations of stock price,
the JSE has adopted price limits. Since the rates of price limit vary
according to price levels as seen in Table 1, the price limit system of
the JSE provides a rare opportunity for examining the relationship
between price limits and stock price volatility.
In a cross-sectional analysis, it is not necessary to control for
all other determinants of volatility that could also have changed over
time. To be reliable, of course, the result of cross-sectional analysis
must be adjusted to cross-sectional variations in firm specific
characteristics such as beta, price level and firm size. First we
construct three portfolios on the basis of the ranked price limit rates
of each day to adjust cross-sectional differences besides price limits.
Then we test the difference in return volatilities between high and low
price limit portfolios using the modified Levene test statistic that is
robust under non-normality.
Price limit rates for listed stocks vary according to the price
level of each stock. The JSE price limit system allows the price of
every listed stock to fluctuate in any given trading day within a
pre-specified level above or below its previous day's closing
price. It is possible, therefore, to examine the relationship between
price limits and stock price volatility cross-sectionally. Of course, an
empirical result of cross-sectional analysis is more reliable after it
has been adjusted to cross-sectional variations in firm specific
characteristics such as beta, price level and firm size. In this study,
separately constructed portfolios are used to isolate the impact of
price limits from other determinants of volatility. The specifics of the
portfolio construction methods are as follows:
Step 1: For each trading day, calculate the price limit rate of
each stock using the previous day's closing price and pre-specified
price limit range, and then sort the price limit rates of listed stocks
in descending order.
Step 2: For each trading day, construct three portfolios, composed
of equal number of stocks, on the basis of ranked price limit rates and
calculate the daily returns of equally weighted portfolios: high price
limit portfolio (HPLP), medium price limit portfolio, and low price
limit portfolio (LPLP). Since the price limit rate of stock alters
according to the change of stock price the stock composition of each
portfolio changes over time. This property also allows any volatility
difference between three portfolios which may be caused by the cross
sectional variations of variables other than price limits, to be
eliminated.
Step 3: Test the equality of return volatilities between HPLP and
LPLP. Even though price limits serve no purpose other than slowing down
or delaying the price change, measured volatility using returns over a
short enough interval (for example, one day) is bound to be affected.
For example, the measured volatility is much higher when a market goes
down 20 percent in one day than when a market hits a 5 percent down
limit four days in a row. Hence, to remove the difference in
volatilities caused only by delay effect, we test the equality of
volatilities between HPLP and LPLP using the returns of several non
overlapping holding intervals (1 day, 2 day, 3 day, and 5 day).
Furthermore, to see whether the results of the above experiment are
reliable, it is necessary to examine whether the portfolio approach is
effective in controlling for other factors besides price limits.
Therefore, portfolios are constructed using residuals from the following
cross-sectional regression model for each trading day. The equality of
volatilities between HPLP and LPLP is tested as follows:
R (I,t) = a + b PLR (i,t) + e (i,t),
where R (I,t) and PLR (I,t) are the daily return and the price
limit rate of stock I at day t, respectively. If the portfolio approach
is effective in controlling for other factors besides price limits, the
difference of volatilities between HPLP and LPLP, if any, would be
caused only by the difference of price limits between HPLP and LPLP.
Therefore, the volatility of HPLP will not be significantly different
from that of LPLP when residuals from the above regression model are
used to construct portfolios.
The data used in this study are described in Table 2.
The entire sample period (1990.1-1999.12) is divided into five
2-year sub periods. Each subperiod is also analyzed separately to gauge
the variation of price limit effects by sample periods. To construct
five portfolios on the basis of ranked price limit rates, both daily
returns and closing prices are necessary. The daily return of each stock
is defined as:
R (i,t) = IN [P(i,t)/P(i,t-1)],
where P (I,t) is the closing price of stock I at day t. For a small
time interval such as a day, this definition is similar to the
arithmetic rate of return.
EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Table 3 shows descriptive statistics on a daily return series for
HPLP and LPLP.
The skewness of a distribution refers to its degree of symmetry;
whereas the kurtosis of a distribution refers to its degree of symmetry;
whereas the kurtosis of a distribution is influenced by the peakness and
thickness of its tails. In Table 3, the skewness coefficients are
positive and the kurtosis coefficients normalized to zero are higher
than zero, indicating greater peaks and fatter tails than under
normality. The Kolmogorov statistics for daily returns of two portfolios
also reject the hypothesis that the distribution of daily returns is
normal at the one percent significance level. These results imply that
some traditional test results concerning stock returns, which assume the
normality of stock returns, may be misleading. For the hypothesis
testing of equal variance, Brown and Forsythe (1974) showed that if the
data have fatter tails than in the case of normal distribution, the
F-statistic rejects the null hypothesis too frequently. However, the
modified Levene statistic proposed by Brown and Forsy the (1994) is not
sensitive to departure from normality. Hence we use the modified led
Levene statistic to test the equality of return volatilities between
HPLP and LPLP. To test the null hypothesis of equal variance between
HPLP and LPLP, the modified Levene statistic is computed as:
L = n [[([Z.sub.H] - Z).sup.2] + [(Z.sub.L] - Z).sup.2]]/[summation over (n/t = 1)] ([Z.sub.h,t] - [Z.sub.H] + [summation over (n/t = 1)]
([Z.sub.L,t] - [Z.sub.L])]/(2n - 2)
where [Z.sub.H,t]=\[[blank].sup.r][H.sub.,t] - [[blank].sup.r]H\,
t=1, ..., n
[Z.sub.L,t] = \[[blank].sup.r][L.sup.,t] - [[blank].sup.r]L\, t=1,
..., n
[Z.sub.H] = [summation over (n/t=1)] [Z.sub.H,t]/n, [Z.sub.L] =
[summation over(n/t=1)] [Z.sub.L,t]/n,
Z = [[summation over (n/t =1)] [Z.sub.H,t] + [summation over (n/t =
1)] [Z.sub.L,t]]/2n,
[r.sub.H] and [r.sub.L] are the daily returns of HPLP and LPLP,
respectively, and [r.sub.H] and [r.sub.L] are 10% trimmed means of HPLP
and LPLP, respectively. Under the null hypothesis, the modified Levene
statistic is asymptotically distributed as F (1 ,2n).
Table 4 shows the comparison of return volatilities between LPLP
and HPLP.
For the full sample period, the modified Levene statistics show
that the volatilities of HPLP are significantly higher than those of
LPLP regardless of the length of holding interval. Even when the 5-day
holding returns are used, the difference in volatilities between LPLP
and HPLP is still significant at the five percent level. These results
indicate that price limit do not only slow down price changes but also
have a positive effect on reducing stock price volatility. However, as
shown in Table 4, the effect of price limits on stock price volatility
appears to be different across the sample periods. Generally, over
subperiods 1, 2, and 3, the volatility of HPLP is not significantly
different from that of LPLP for most of the holding intervals, whereas
the difference is significant over subperiods 4 and 5 regardless of
holding intervals. Why does the effect of price limits on stock price
volatility appear to be different according to the sample periods?
Tables 5 and 6 may provide an answer to this question.
Price limits do not always reduce stock price volatility. Price
limits become binding constraints to reduce stock price volatility when
stock prices go up or down beyond the price limits.
Table 5 shows the average number of trading days per listed stock
effect by price limits for each subperiod, and table 6 represents the
average price limit rates of both HPLP and LPLP for each subperiod. For
subperiods 1, 2, and 3, the numbers of average trading days per stock
affected by price limits are much smaller than those for subperiods 4
and 5. This is because the average price limit rates for subperiods 1, 2
and 3 are higher than those for subperiods 4 and 5. This may help
explain why differences in volatilities between HPLP and LPLP are not
significant for subperiods 1, 2, and 3.
Next we examine whether previous results are caused only by price
limits or by factors other than price limits. As mentioned above, if
differences in volatilities between HPLP and LPLP are eliminated when
residuals from the regression model are used to construct HPLP and LPLP,
it would indicate that the above results are influenced by the effect of
price limits. Surprisingly, Table 7 shows that the difference in return
volatilities between LPLP and HPLP are mostly insignificant regardless
of the holding intervals and sample periods.
We can therefore conclude that the difference in volatilities
between LPLP and HPLP is caused by price limits.
CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS
Since price limit rates of stocks vary cross-sectionally according
to stock price levels, it is possible to control for other factors
besides price limits in examining the effect of price limits on stock
price volatility. We compare the return volatilities between high price
limit portfolio (HPLP) and low price limit portfolio (LPLP) constructed
on the basis of ranked price limit rates. The results show that price
limits serve to reduce stock price volatility.
Some very basic questions remain unanswered that future research
needs to address. For example, 1) Do price limits change the character
of prices around limits? 2) If price limits change price behavior, do
they do so in a way detrimental to the integrity of the market? If so,
is it because price limits are too tight or too loose? 3) Do price
limits affect liquidity? What happens to bid/ask spread immediately
before and after a limit? What happens to volume? Are there big orders
on one side that are broken up into smaller orders to be executed? 4) Do
local traders get out of the market and let customers trade with other
customers? Do hedgers lose because they cannot establish positions, and
do speculators win? In particular, who is rationed out of the market,
and do they subsequently lose money because of this rationing? No one
has yet examined who is affected by limits. This is an important issue
for establishing policy. 5) Assuming price limits can be useful, what is
the optimal strategy for setting them so as to obtain the most effective
outcome? 6) When should exchanges change limits? How can they be
proactive and anticipate an optimal time to do so? 7) Do price limits
lower default risk? How many defaults have occurred in markets without
limits versus those with limits, when other factors are controlled?
APPENDIX
The Johannesburg Stock Exchange, South Africa: Brief Background.
The Johannesburg Stock Exchange (JSE) in South Africa was
established in November 1887. It is the largest and most developed tock
exchange in the African continent. During 1997 and 1998, 154 firms went
public. With $13.2 billion in market capitalization, the JSE is the
tenth largest market in the world, ahead of, for example, Italy and
Australia. There are 759 listed companies issuing a variety of
securities from common stocks to preferred stocks. Debentures, mutual
funds, government and municipal securities, financial futures,
commodities futures, options as well as money market instruments are
traded on the JSE. Of the companies quoted on the JSE, over 150 have
dual listings on foreign stock exchanges, including the New York Stock
Exchange.
Trading is done using an electronic on-line real time trading
system that combines order-and quote-driven systems. The system is known
as the JSE Equities Trading (JET) System. The capacity of the JSE system
is 500,000 trades per day. Trading time runs from 9:00 a.m. to 4:00 p.m.
All settlements are executed through a clearinghouse. The exchange
conducts surveillance on price limits and position monitoring through
the Johannesburg Stock Exchange Committee, a regulatory body that
comprises fifteen stockbrokers elected annually and the Registrar of
Financial Institutions as a government-appointed member. Full financial
disclosure is required of all listed companies.
Margins are levied at 28% for delivery trades and 35% for other
transactions. Counter-party risk management is facilitated by a trade
guarantee fund. In 1998, the JSE introduced an internet-based support
system to match suppliers and demanders of capital in conjunction with a
stock exchange news service (SENS) to disseminate listed companies news.
The average number of daily deals for the past five years (1995-1999) is
264,387.
Table 1
Price Limit on Different Sock Price Levels in the JSE
(As of December 1999)
Stock Price (Rand) (a) Price Limit Price Limit Rate
%
- 30 10 -3.33
30 - 50 20 6.67-4.00
50 - 70 30 6.00-4.29
70 - 100 40 5.71-4.00
100 - 150 60 6.00-4.00
150 - 200 80 5.33-4.00
200 - 300 100 5.00-3.33
300 - 400 130 4.33-3.25
400 - 500 160 4.00-3.20
500 - 700 200 4.00-2.86
700 - 1000 250 3.57-2.50
1000 - 1500 300 3.00-2.00
1500 - 400 2.67-
Note: (a) The Rand is the South African currency unit: Rand 1 = US$ 0.65
in December 1999.
Table 2
Data Description
Source: JSE Equity Trading (JET) Systema
Daily returns file and daily
closing price file
Sample period: 1990.1-1999.12 inclusive.
The entire period is divided into
5 equal subperiods.
Subperiod 1 (1990-1991)
Subperiod 2 (1932-1993)
Subperiod 3 (1994-1995)
Subperiod 4 (1996-1997)
Subperiod 5 (1998-1999)
Selection criteria: All listed equity securities
Basic data unit: Return adjusted for all capital
changes and including dividends
Note: (a) The JET System was created by the Johannesburg Stock Exchange
Committee, a Regulatory body that comprises fifteen stock brokers
elected annually and the Registrar of Financial Institutions as a
government- appointed member.
Table 3
Descriptive Statistics on Portfolio Daily Return Series
Original Return Series Residual Return
Series
Statistics LPLP HPLP LPLP
No. of Obs. 2921 2921 2921
Mean (%) 0.096 0.147 0.039
Variance (%) 0.781 0.946 0.555
Skewness 0.320 0.907 0.531
Kurtosis 2.304 5.008 4.262
Min. (%) -3.289 -4.426 -3.289
Max. (%) 4.648 7.734 2.298
Kolmogorov Stat. 0.067 (**) 0.087 (**) 0.136 (**)
Residual
Return
Series
Statistics HPLP
No. of Obs. 2921
Mean (%) 0.025
Variance (%) 0.546
Skewness 0.568
Kurtosis 4.707
Min. (%) 3.529
Max. (%) 2.294
Kolmogorov Stat. 1.423 (**)
Note: a(**) = significant at the 1% level
Table 4
Comparison of Volatilities between LPLP and HPLP
(based on original returns data)
Sample Holding Number Standard Deviation (%)
Period Period of
(Days) Obs. LPLP HPLP
Full period 1 2921 0.781 0.946
(1990-1999) 2 1460 1.244 1.478
3 973 1.606 1.885
5 486 2.443 2.872
Subperiod 1 1 582 0.921 0.839
(1990-1991) 2 291 1.432 1.380
3 194 1.891 1.867
5 97 2.834 2.979
Subperiod 2 1 591 0.677 0.742
(1992-1993) 2 295 1.046 1.097
3 197 1.373 1.479
5 98 1.912 1.996
Subperiod 3 1 587 0.551 0.665
(1994-1995) 2 293 0.920 0.975
3 195 1.167 1.244
5 97 1.877 1.798
Subperiod 4 1 584 0.891 1.249
(1996-1997) 2 292 1.461 1.981
3 194 1.875 1.875
5 97 2.843 3.782
Subperiod 5 1 582 0.792 1.086
(1998-1999) 2 291 1.247 1.429
3 194 1.695 2.212
5 97 2.400 2.400
Sample Modified
Period Levene
Statistic
Full period 37.04 (**)
(1990-1999) 16.93 (**)
7.24 (**)
3.30 (**)
Subperiod 1 6.66 (**)
(1990-1991) 0.74
0.39
0.06
Subperiod 2 0.59
(1992-1993) 0.00
0.30
0.13
Subperiod 3 8.76 (**)
(1994-1995) 0.90
0.08
0.77
Subperiod 4 39.25 (**)
(1996-1997) 16.80 (**)
5.45 (**)
4.15 (**)
Subperiod 5 33.89 (**)
(1998-1999) 19.18 (**)
8.05 (**)
7.30 (**)
Notes:
a(**) = significant at the 1% level.
b(*) = significant at the 5% level.
Table 5
Average Price Limit Rate for LPLP and HPLP
Same Average Price Limit Rate (%)
Period LPLP HPLP
Full period 5.443 7.776
Subperiod 1 6.504 9.360
Subperiod 2 6.390 9.164
Subperiod 3 5.843 8.920
Subperiod 4 4.620 6.628
Subperiod 5 3.861 4.811
Table 6
Total Trading Days of Stocks affected by Price Limits
Sample Average Number Total Trading Days Average Trading Days
Period of Listed Firms of Stocks Affected of Stocks Affected
by Price by Price Limits
Subperiod 1 307 5,358 17.45
Subperiod 2 307 2,427 7.91
Subperiod 3 322 3,582 11.12
Subperiod 4 340 16,717 49.17
Subperiod 5 487 39,810 81.75
Table 7
Comparison of Volatilities between LPLP and HPLP
(based on original returns data)
Sample Holding Number Standard Deviation (%) Modified
Period Period of Levene
(Days) Obs. LPLP HPLP Statistic
Full period 1 2921 0.555 0.546 1.02
(1990-1999) 2 1460 0.857 0.836 0.77
3 973 1.085 1.048 1.49
5 486 1.628 1.568 1.56
Subperiod 1 1 582 0.687 0.622 3.70
(1990-1991) 2 291 1.101 0.988 2.41
3 194 1.359 1.212 1.78
5 97 1.966 1.743 0.88
Subperiod 2 1 591 0.523 0.489 0.95
(1992-1993) 2 295 0.777 0.698 1.32
3 197 0.976 0.872 0.64
5 98 1.380 1.287 0.44
Subperiod 3 1 587 0.359 0.349 0.76
(1994-1995) 2 293 0.545 0.515 1.73
3 195 0.679 0.656 0.81
5 97 0.961 0.771 6.64
Subperiod 4 1 584 0.617 0.660 0.74
(1996-1997) 2 292 0.942 1.031 1.68
3 194 1.261 1.362 0.61
5 97 1.902 2.085 0.32
Subperiod 5 1 582 0.524 0.548 0.17
(1998-1999) 2 291 0.789 0.817 0.28
3 194 1.068 1.086 0.14
5 97 1.533 1.576 0.90
Notes:
(a)(**) = significant at the 1% level.
(b)(*) = significant at the 5% level.
REFERENCES
African Stock Exchange Performance (1998). Standard Bank London
Limited, December 14, 2001.
Bacidore, J., (1997). The impact of decimalization on market
quality: An empirical investigation of the Toronto Stock Exchange,
Journal of Financial Intermediation, 92-120.
Brennan, M. (1986). A theory of price limits in future markets.
Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 16, 213-233.
Brown, M.B. and A.B. Forsythe (1974). Robust tests for the equality
of variances. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 364-367.
Chen, Y.-M. (1992). Price Limits and Stock Market Volatility in
Taiwan. Working Paper (San Francisco State University.)
Chiang, R., K.C.J. Wei, and S. Wu (1990). Price limits in Taiwan
and risk-returning estimation. Pacific-Basin Capital Markets Research,
1, 173-180.
Chung, J.-R. (1991). Price limit system and volatility of Korean
Stock Market. Pacific-Basin Capital Markets Research, 2, 283-294.
Fama, E.F. (1989). Perspectives on October 1987, or, what did we
learn from the crash? In Black Monday and the Future of Financial
Markets, Kamphuis, Kormendi and Watson (eds.) Mid America Institute for
Public Policy Research, Inc., Chicago Illinois, pp. 71-82.
French, K. and R. Roll (1986). Stock return variances: The arrival
of information and the reaction of traders. Journal of Financial
Economics, 17, 5-16.
Goldstein, M. and K. Kavajecz (1999). Eighths, sixteenths, and
market depth: Changes in tick size and liquidity provision on the NYSE,
Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming.
Harris, L.E. (1994). Minimum price variations, discrete bid-ask
spreads, and quotations sizes, Review of Financial Studies, 7, 149-178.
Harris, L.E. (1996). Does a large minimum price variation encourage
order exposure? Working Paper, University of Southern California.
Harris, L.E. (1997a). Order exposure and parasitic traders. Working
Paper. University of Southern California.
Harris, L.E., (1997b). Decimalization: A review of the arguments
and evidence. Working Paper. University of Southern California.
Harris, L.E. (1997c). Testimony on H.R. 1053: The Common Cents
Stock
Johanesburg Stock Exchange (2001). About the JSE and Regulations,
December 2.
Jones, C.M. and M.L. Lipson (1999). Sixteenths: Direct evidence on
institutional trading costs. Working Paper, Columbia University.
Ma, C.K., R. Rao and R.S. Sears (1989). Limit moves and price
resolution: The case of Treasury Bond Futures. Journal of Futures
Markets, Vol. 9, pp. 321-335.
Porter, D.C. and D.G. Weaver (1998). Post-trade transparency on
Nasdaq's national market system, Journal of Financial Economics 50,
231-252.
Roll, R. (1988). The international crash of October 1987. Financial
Analysts Journal, 44, 19-35.
Schwert, G.W. (1989), 'Why does stock market volatility change
over time? Journal Of Finance, 44, 1115-1151.
Sheimo, Michael (1999). International Encyclopedia of the Stock
Market. Fitzroy Dearborn Publishers: Chicago. Vol. 2.
Shiller, R.J. (1981). Do stock prices move too much to be justified
by subsequent changes in dividends? American Economics Review, 71,
421-436.
United States Presidential Task Force on Market Mechanisms (1988).
The Brady Report (Washington DC).
World's Major Stock Exchanges: Listing Requirements. Price
Warehouse Information Guide. 1984.
ENDNOTE
* Please address all comments to Christopher Ngassam, Ph.D.,
Associate Professor of Finance, Department of Entrepreneurial Studies.
School of Business, Norfolk State University. Norfolk, Virginia,
23504-8060, USA: phone (757) 823-9534; e-mail: cngassam@nsu.edu. I would
like to thank Professor Basu Sharma, the editor of this journal and two
anonymous referees for helpful comments on an earlier draft. I also wish
to thank participants of the 2002 Financial Management Association
International Annual Meetings (Session on Emerging Stock Market
Volatility and Diversification) in San Antonio, Texas for valuable
suggestions that were later incorporated in the final revision of the
paper. All remaining errors are of course mine.