The determinants of the success of microlending: a comparison of Iraq and the United States.
Rubach, Michael J. ; Bradley, Don B., III ; Brown, Justin Eric 等
INTRODUCTION
Microfinance institutions (MFIs) have become fixtures of the
international community. For over thirty years, MFIs have successfully
supported entrepreneurship by lending money to needy people all over the
world (Richardson, 2009). The growth of the microfinance and
microlending has spawned considerable research interest in this industry
and its international growth. Much of the prior research has examined
the product and service offerings of MFIs, management best practices,
MFI clientele, and policy issues and their impacts (see Brau &
Woller's (2004) literature review of microfinance). Brau and Woller
(2004) found that scholarly inquiries into microfinance and microlending
have generally lagged behind industry developments.
In Iraq, the United States government through the U.S. Agency for
International Development (USAID) has successfully created programs that
have provided more than 132,000 microloans worth a combined value of
over $300 million. The loans have averaged $1500 at 1518% interest rates
with a repayment rate of over 98%. (US Federal News Service, 2009). The
microfinance loans from MFIs working with USAID have resulted in more
than 130,000 jobs being sustained or created (Iraq Microfinance Industry
(IMFI), 2010). In contrast, microfinance and microlending, while
achieving considerable success internationally, have not generally
succeeded in the United States. Microlending in the US has experienced
high default rates, failures in meeting program goals, and a general
lack of self-sufficiency or sustainability (Richardson, 2009).
Sustainability as used herein refers to survivability, not the social
responsibility focus that sustainability has begun to assume.
This article will examine the factors that contribute to the
success and failure of microlending efforts, and compare the specific
reasons for the success of the USAID programs in Iraq and the general
failure of microlending and microcredit efforts in the US.
DETERMINANTS OF MICROLENDING SUCCESS/FAILURE
Microfinance generally refers to the informal and formal
arrangements that offer financial services to the poor (Brau &
Woller, 2004). While it has existed for centuries, microfinance came on
the international scene during the 1970s as a serious effort to create
and formalize financial services for the poor (Richardson, 2009; Brau
& Woller, 2004). Domestic use of the terms
"microenterprise" and "microfinance" did not appear
for another decade (Burrus, 2005).
A microenterprise is a business with five or fewer employees. Many
of these businesses have no employees other than the owners (Burrus,
2005). The purpose of microfinance is to provide economic opportunities,
including financial capital and services, to the poor in the hope that
the cycles of poverty can be broken through new business development
(Crabb, 2008). Microfinance offers people living in poverty access to
basic financial services, such as loans, savings, money transfer
services, and insurance needed to run their businesses (Consultative
Group to Assist the Poor (CGAP), 2009). At best, commercial banks in
developing countries serve only 20% of the population (Richardson,
2009). MFIs have stepped in to fill this void, lending to individuals
that traditional lenders have ignored due to high transaction costs and
risks (Richardson, 2009). There are now thousands of MFIs servicing
100-200 million of the world's poor (Brau & Woller, 2004). The
individual amount of the microloans in developing countries ranges from
$10 to over $1000 with durations usually of less than two years.
Borrowers are not usually required by microlenders in developing
countries to put up collateral or undergo credit checks (Richardson,
2009).
Since the 1970s, MFIs in developing countries have been very
successful, while those in the United States have seen limited success.
Defining success for MFIs has been problematic. MFIs normally have dual
objectives of financial development and social improvement. Financial
success can be measured by the attainment of two standards:
self-sufficiency and sustainability, i.e., operating without outside
resources and subsidies. Whether an MFI meets the needs of
microentrepreneurs or creates social improvements is more difficult to
ascertain.
Theoretically, capital should flow to the poor and the microfinance
industry should not be necessary (Schmidt, 2009). However, the realities
of investment risk, asymmetric information for both lenders and debtors,
high transaction costs, and the presence or absence of legal
institutions and systems, all work to present challenges for offering
microcredit by commercial financial industries (Schmidt, 2009). These
challenges are compounded by over-emphasis by many financial
institutions on the need for collateral, a tendency to ignore the
debtor's willingness or ability to pay, a poor culture of
repayment, lack of coordination and support between MFIs, business
organizations and the government, and the divergent aims of microfinance
itself (Knight, Hossain, & Rees, 2009).
There may be many causes for the reluctance of conventional
financial institutions to serve the poor (Schmidt, 2009). There may be
socio-psychological reasons, such as social prejudice, stubbornness and
ignorance. More likely it is because poor borrowers are not perceived as
profitable. The risk of lending to them is too high. The costs of the
lending transaction are too great. The borrowers often have no
collateral and no credit history. The costs to enforce the loan
agreement may even exceed the amount of the loan itself (Schmidt, 2009).
Faced with exclusion by conventional banks or exploitation by loan
sharks, the poor can gain access to credit through microfinance
institutions: non-governmental organizations (NGOs), charitable
institutions, self-help institutions, or public banks, organizations
that often pursue objectives other than just making a profit. The common
feature of these institutions is the pursuit of both economic
(profitability) and social (impacting the lives of their clients)
endeavors (Schmidt, 2009).
MFIs in developing countries have been recognized for their
innovative means of delivering credit. Group lending is one way to
ameliorate the problems arising from asymmetric information. Network
theory recognizes that parties cooperate by virtue of the mutual
benefits they will receive and reciprocate. Among networks there is a
high commitment to cooperate among the interdependent parties (Scott,
2003). Under group lending, the borrowers monitor themselves,
eliminating the need for providing risk information to the lender. The
group networking and peer-mentoring associated with group lending add to
its success (Richardson, 2009). In addition to group lending,
innovations in microfinance in developing countries include flexible
repayment schedules, public repayments, and flexible collateral
(Armendariz de Aghion & Morduch, 2005).
Institutional theory highlights how rules enable and/or constrain
organizational decisions. The theory recognizes the importance of
history in shaping the rules, routines and processes that structure an
organization's behavior (March & Olsen, 1989). Rules of
operation are history-dependent and can include both formally codified
standards and informal routines or norms. Rules are embodied in the
policies, procedures, routines, and conventions around which activities
are constructed (Scott, 2003). The rules can cause institutional
inertia, which along with path dependency, can inhibit innovation by
financial institutions and economic expansion in developing economies
(Pei & Xiangping, 2009).
Financial markets have particular characteristics which shape, and
are shaped by, the transaction costs paid by both consumers as buyers
and financial service providers as sellers. Transaction costs are often
hard to measure in practice, and will vary uniquely for each
buyer-seller exchange (Porteous, 2004). They take two main forms: 1) Ex
ante costs, which include the costs of search (for both buyers and
sellers) as well as the costs of contracting; and 2) Ex post costs,
which include monitoring the contract during its term and enforcement of
contractual rights (Porteous, 2004).
Using transaction cost, network, institutional, and competition
theories, we have identified some differences between the microlending
industries in Iraq and the US (see Table 1). These differences and their
effects on the success or failure of MFIs are discussed in the next
sections of the paper.
US-LED MICROLENDING IN IRAQ
Microlending is a relatively new industry in Iraq (USAID-Tijara).
Before 2003, there was no microfinance industry in Iraq. While loans
were made to state-run enterprises and some small businesses during the
Saddam Hussein regime, financial capital was often available only to
those loyal to the regime. Entrepreneurs without political connections
had no sources of capital except loan sharks who charged usurious
interest rates (IMFI, 2010).
Between 2003 and 2006, there were only three MFIs in Iraq and those
were operated by international NGOs. The Cooperative Housing Foundation,
ACDI/VOCA and Relief International were the sole providers of
microfinancing in the country at that time (USAID-Tijara). Currently,
there are ten microfinance institutions (MFIs) operating in Iraq's
18 governorates. The loans to micro and small business enterprises range
from $500 to $25,000 in size with an average duration of 12 months.
Interest rates vary depending on loan size and the business's
location (IMFI, 2009).
The USAID began the Izdihar project in 2005; it was terminated in
March 2008. The Izdihar project began the efforts to create a
sustainable microfinance industry, bank lending for small and medium
size enterprises, business development services and training, investment
promotion, and trade reform (USAID-Tijara). In 2006, the Izdihar
project, in conjunction with the US military, created and funded the
first indigenous Iraqi MFIs: Al Bashaer in Baghdad and Al Aman in
Kirkuk. When the Izdihar project was terminated in 2008, six additional
MFIs had been established (USAID-Tijara).
The Iraqi MFIs are located in different parts of the country (see
Figure 1). They adapt their financial services to local borrowers'
requirements. Some Iraqis have complained about the charging of interest
on loans, a violation of the Koran. In response, the MFIs have offered
murahaba Islamic loans. The major difference between a conventional loan
and an Islamic loan is that a conventional bank charges interest while
an Islamic lender does not. Under the murahaba loan, a service charge is
levied instead of interest, allowing the lender to make a profit. For
example, instead of lending a home builder $10,000 at 12 percent
interest to purchase building materials, the Islamic lender will buy
$10,000 worth of materials for the builder and then sell him those
materials for $11,200. The lender still earns a 12 percent profit on the
transaction. The final result is the same in both the conventional and
murahaba loans. The latter differs only in that it follows the
Koran's prohibition against charging interest (IFMI, 2009).
Since July 2003, when the first MFI working with the USAID began
operation, some 200,000 loans worth more than $370.7 million have been
made (IFMI, 2009). Over 75% of the microloans were made to start or
improve businesses in production, services, agribusiness, and trade. The
remaining loans were for home improvements which supported home-based
and cottage industries. Private residences are often the locales for
many neighborhood businesses, such as barbers, cosmetologists and
seamstresses (USAID-Tijara)
Microloans make differences in peoples' lives. The following
stories are not uncommon, but are more the norm for modern day Iraqi
businesses.
Adla Saleh Azez in the city of Dohuk used three microfinance loans
to create the Havel Academy of Sewing where Adla teaches professional
sewing skills to Iraqi women. "These women come to me to learn how
to make a living sewing," explains Adla. "Most return to their
villages to set up their own businesses." Adla plans to apply for a
fourth loan which she will use to purchase patterns and equipment in
Turkey to make wedding dresses. She adds: "The [MFI] loans ... have
made a real difference in the lives of dozens of women, myself
included." (IFMI, 2009).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Muthana Idan Kabul is an Iraqi citizen who owns and operates a tea
cafe in the Karkh area of Baghdad. During the worst of the sectarian
fighting, insurgents would steal his cafe's furniture and even set
his shop on fire. This did not stop him from operating his business. He
received a $2,500 (US) loan from a USAID-backed MFI to improve his
business. He has since opened a bigger shop and bought new tables and
chairs (Block, 2009).
Hamzi Abid Ali grows grapes in the town of Balad. He has grown
grapes there for many years, starting during the time under Saddam
Hussein. He stated that his income has more than quintupled since
receiving a $2,400 (US) loan from the Al-Baydaa Centre, a US-backed
microcredit institution. He was able to buy a new irrigation system and
well pump that has allowed him to expand his business operations and
help him speed up repayment of the loan
(Fifield, 2009).
In 2008, the Tijara project became the successor to the
USAID's Izdihar project. Tijara means trade in Arabic. The Tijara
project is a three to five year program funded by the USAID to promote
private enterprise growth and employment in Iraq. The project focuses on
Iraqi communities and provides services that will stimulate businesses
and provide greater access to loans and financial services
(USAID-Tijara). The mission of the Tijara project is: "to promote
economic growth and employment in Iraq by increasing private sector
access to finance, in particular for micro, small and medium
enterprises. This objective is fulfilled by stimulating microfinance
institutions and private banks to increase loan volume and diversify
their services and clients; by creating and supporting indigenous
providers of business development services; and by working with the
Government of Iraq to develop an improved enabling environment for
increased trade and investment in the private sector."
(USAID-Tijara).
USAID-Tijara and the Iraqi government have created Small Business
Development Centers (SBDCs). The SBDC services range from offering
microloans to develop new businesses to offering basic business training
courses to help educate the Iraqi citizenry about how to manage a
business. The SBDCs have created a voucher system to provide individuals
with the financial resources to pay for the business education programs.
The SBDCs also offer assistance for creating business plans and help
entrepreneurs develop businesses from the ground up in areas that vary
from taxi drivers to new hospitals (Small Business Development Centers
in Iraq). Further, SBDCs sponsor business conferences, host trade fairs,
and provide business and consulting services. While the SBDCs have not
attained sustainable status, this is a long-term goal. The most critical
service SBDCs perform, however, is linking aspiring and struggling
entrepreneurs with microfinance institutions and banks that have capital
to invest in the local business economy. It is interesting to note that
in the Frequently Asked Questions section of SBDC's website, the
agency was asked if there was an age limit on receiving assistance from
the SBDC. The response was intriguing: "We would expect that a
person who wants to create a business or has an idea should be 15 years
of age or older." (Small Business Development Centers in Iraq).
To reduce risk and ensure repayment, Iraqi MFIs often require
borrowers to provide a guarantor, who usually is a government employee.
This safeguard has caused many of Iraq's poorest citizens to be
excluded because they lack friends within the government. To include
more borrowers and reduce transactions costs, MFIs working with
USAID-Tijara program offer group loans. These loans are structured so
that a borrower can receive a small loan (typically $650) by forming a
group wherein each member serves as a guarantor for the others. During a
four month period of 2009, 8,345 Iraqis (of whom 17% were women)
received group loans collectively totaling $8.9 million (IMFI, 2009). In
order to help the very poor, microfinance institutions in Iraq now are
offering solidarity group loans to eight people or fewer. The
group's collective promise, that every person will repay his or her
loan, serves as the collateral for the loan. Group loans have been made
to women's groups, handicraft associations and people referred from
Iraq's 12 SBDCs that are supported by USAID-Tijara and Provincial
Reconstruction Teams (IMFI, 2009; USAID-Tijara).
The Iraqi government has recognized the need to grow a strong
private sector. The government understands that a modern free market
economy and a favorable legal environment are necessary for Iraq to join
the global economy. There has been substantial progress in the
government's efforts to establish a business climate conducive to
economic growth (USAID-Tijara).
As of February 2010, there are 58,852 outstanding microfinance
loans in Iraq with a total value of $82,855,717 (US) (USAID-Tijara). The
primary goal of the Iraqi microfinance industry is to provide quality
financial services, mostly through loans, that will stimulate economic
growth and create new and higher-paying jobs. The Tijara program assists
in these endeavors by providing business development services and
creating a sustainable microfinance industry (USAID-Tijara). Despite
operating under the challenges of an insecure political environment,
including continued sectarian violence, inadequate sources of human
capital, and an underdeveloped legal and regulatory schema, MFIs in Iraq
have displayed significant portfolio growth and high loan repayment
rates--they are succeeding.
MICROFINANCE IN US
Despite the success that microlending has experienced
internationally, efforts to support entrepreneurship of poor people in
the US have been generally less successful (Burrus, 2005). US MFIs have
been neither efficient (they have failed to become self-sufficient), nor
effective (they have reached less than 1% of US microentrepreneurs)
while suffering higher default rates than their international
counterparts (Richardson, 2009).
US microlending began in the 1980s modeled after the programs
established in the international context. Microfinance is a relatively
young industry with most MFIs being created since 1995. The industry is
very fragmented with many smaller lenders (Burrus, 2005). US MFIs are
typically not-for-profit organizations (NFPs) that make loans usually
for under $25,000 with the average loan about $10,000. The demand for
microlending services in the US far outweighs the suppliers (Burrus,
2005). There are over 13 million microentrepreneurs in the US. Most are
self-employed individuals who have no or few employees (Burrus, 2005).
Many cannot obtain loans from traditional commercial banks due to the
requirements of those institutions for a credit history or collateral.
Unlike their international counterparts, US microfinancers usually do
not make group loans, thus failing to utilize the benefits of networking
(Richardson, 2009).
The US MFI industry is usually broken into two types: either
credit-led--primarily offering credit and financial services, or
training-led--primarily offering training and technical services.
Training-led MFIs are concerned with business plan creation (Burrus,
2005). Training-led organizations often offer courses for feasibility
studies, business plan development, and general individual preparation
for operating a business. Additionally, classes or one-on-one assistance
in tax preparation, marketing, technology utilization, and finances are
available (Burrus, 2005).
While the need for microfinance in the US may never be greater,
traditional financial institutions have not provided loans to
microentrepreneurs. Most commercial banking institutions will not lend
to individuals who lack a credit history or collateral. The US
microfinance industry has been characterized by scale economies; larger
lenders are more efficient and cheaper to run. However, MFI
inefficiency, as measured by the lack of MFI self-sufficiency and
sustainability, also characterizes the industry (Burrus, 2005).
While most not-for-profit microlenders in the US are
unregulated--the only restrictions are general prohibitions within the
Internal Revenue Code, state corporations laws, or consumer protection
acts--US commercial lenders are highly regulated. These regulations
increase transaction costs. The US microlending market suffers from both
high ex-ante and ex-post transaction costs. It is expensive to gather
the necessary information on potential borrowers, as well as to monitor
and enforce loan repayments. The norm for US banks is to require
borrowers to provide collateral, credit histories, and/or business plans
in order to secure loans. These policies and procedures increase
transaction costs. Information asymmetries occur on both sides of
transactions. MFIs lack information about borrowers, an ex-ante cost,
and borrowers have limited knowledge of or experience in financial or
credit markets. US MFIs have failed to adequately address the
information deficiencies of borrowers (Richardson, 2009). The lack of
collateral affects both types of costs. Ex-post transaction costs are
also quite high in the US. The costs to enforce a loan agreement through
the court system in the US can be prohibitive. Further, state usury laws
prevent lenders from charging higher interest rates to offset these
expenses. The limits on interest rates limit lenders' returns and
have adversely affected MFI sustainability (Richardson, 2009).
Further, the regulatory schema is severely restrictive. Under
capital holding requirements, banks are required to hold portions of
their capital against each loan they make. "The more risky the
loan, the greater the amount of capital the bank must hold."
(Richardson, 2009: 932). These requirements make it more difficult for
conventional financial institutions to make microloans.
Previous research (Richardson, 2009; Dyal-Chand, 2005) has
attributed the differences in the success of MFIs between developing
countries and the US to differences in market structures. MFIs in
developing countries have had greater success because the markets in
which they are located are "less formal"--lacking in entry
barriers and market saturation. The informality allows entrepreneurs to
transact business more cheaply, i.e., without extensive transaction
costs. In contrast, US markets are more mature in structure and in
product offerings. US entrepreneurs need more market information and are
required to perform more analyses, especially of the feasibility of
their business models.
Lastly, government support for the US MFI industry has been
previously mixed. There has been a general lack of federal funding for
MFIs due to budget deficits. Plus, the Bush administration was
criticized for its general lack of interest in microlending (Burrus,
2005).
The transaction costs present in US MFI industry together with
regulatory restrictions on financial institutions have hampered the
development of MFIs. While there have been calls for regulatory reform
(Richardson, 2009), due to the structural and operational norms of
financial institutions, MFI success in the US has been spotty.
CONCLUSION
The United Nations declared 2005 as the International Year for
Microcredit to promote and increase the public's understanding of
microfinance and microlending (UN, 2005). Muhammad Yunus and his Grameen
Bank, a microlender in Bangladesh, won the Noble Prize in 2006 (Nobel
Prize, 2006). Microfinance and microlending are now mainstays of
international finance (Richardson, 2009). While microlending has
positively affected the lives of hundreds of millions of people, there
are still many more who have had no access to the services of MFIs
(Crabb, 2008).
There are substantial differences in the operations of MFIs in Iraq
and the US, ranging from how each approaches transaction costs and
innovation to differences in their markets and the presence of
governmental support. In Iraq, MFIs appear to have achieved considerable
success. The experience of MFIs in Iraq supports the theory that a
factor in the success of microlending is the presence of free markets
(Crabb, 2008).
A study by the United Nations found that Iraqi men between the ages
of 15 to 29 faced an unemployment rate near 30%. Microfinance loans made
through the joint efforts of USAID-Tijara and Iraqi MFIs were
instrumental in creating or sustaining 130,000 jobs. The study found
that people with jobs did not join militias. Many of the group loans
were held by former members of the Mahdi army who were able to earn more
money as business owners than they did serving religious extremists
(IMFI, 2010).
Despite the prior lack of government interest and support for
microlending in the US, government support for microlending in Iraq
stands in sharp contrast. Structural differences in markets are not the
only answer. US regulation of financial lending institutions severely
restricts microlending. The need for regulatory reform is great
(Robertson, 2009). The current recession should provide opportunities
for microlenders as the declines in the job market have forced many
laid-off individuals to seek self-employment as a solution. However, the
operational and regulatory structures of the US MFI industry have
impeded its efficiency and effectiveness.
Microlending globally has positively affected many lives (Crabb,
2008). "We make around 220 loans a month that are collectively
worth about $228,000," says Al-Mosaned
Executive Director Wakkas Noori. "Our loans keep widows in
their homes and allow young men to turn their dreams into
businesses." However, Wakkas Noori observed that the biggest
difference between microfinance and banking is one of social
responsibility. For him, "[b]anking is all about money, [but]
[m]icrofinance is about people." (IMFI, 2009). While much has been
done, there are still many more people who have no access to the
services of MFIs. This will continue to be the challenge for both Iraq
and the US on both the operational and policy levels.
REFERENCES
Armendariz de Aghion, B. & J. Morduch (2005). The economics of
microfinance. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Block, D. (2008). Small business comes back to life in Iraq.
Retrieved June 30, 2009, from
http://www.voanews.com/english/archive/2008-08/2008-0808voa13.cfm?
CFID=235951842&CFTOKEN=60647268&jsessionid=8430e86987aa0724c761761 e1570524112c4.
Brau, J. C. & G. M. Woller (2004). Microfinance: A
comprehensive review of the existing literature. Journal of
Entrepreneurial Finance and Business Ventures, 9(1), 1-26.
Burrus, B. (2005). Lessons and trends of microcredit in the United
States. Accion USA. Retrieved August 8, 2009, from
http://www.accion.org/Document.Doc?Id=51.
Consultative Group to Assist the Poor (CGAP) (2009). What is
microfinance? Retrieved March 3, 2009, from
http://www.cgap.org/p/site/c/template.rc/1.26.1302/.
Crabb, P. (2008). Economic freedom and the success of microfinance
institutions. Journal of Developmental Entrepreneurship. 13(2), 205-219.
Dyal-Chand, R. (2005). Reflection in a distant mirror: Why the West
has misperceived the Grameen Bank's vision of microcredit. Stanford
Journal of International Law, 41, 217-306.
Fifield, A. (2009, April 7). Small US loans are catalyst for Iraqi
business. The Financial Times. Retrieved from
http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/c8af6be2-22ff-11de-9c99-00144feabdc0.html
?ftcamp=rss&nclick_check=1, November 19, 2009.
Iraq Microfinance Industry (IMFI) (2010). Microfinance loans help
entrepreneurs start businesses and create new jobs. Retrieved from
http://www.imfi.org/modules.php?name=News& file=article&sid=155,
February 22, 2010.
Iraq Microfinance Industry (IMFI) (2009). Iraq reconstructs thanks
to microfinance industry. Retrieved January 8, 2010, from
http://www.imfi.org/modules.php?name=News&file=rticle&sid=148.
Knight, T., F. Hossain & C. Rees (2009). Microfinance and the
commercial banking system: Perspectives from Barbados. Progress in
Development Studies, 9(2), 115-125.
March, J. G. & J. P. Olsen (1989). Rediscovering institutions:
The organizational basis of politics. New York: Free Press.
Nobel Prize (2006). The Nobel Peace Prize 2006. Retrieved March 3,
2010, from http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/ peace/laureates/2006/.
Pei, Guo & J. Xiangping (2009). The structure and reform of
rural finance in China. China Agricultural Economic Review, 1(2),
212-226.
Porteous, D. (2004). Making financial markets work for the poor.
Retrieved November 20, 2009, from
http://info.worldbank.org/etools/docs/library/128740/Making%20financial
%20market%20work%20for%20the%20poor.pdf.
Richardson, M. (2009). Increasing microlending potential in the
United States through a strategic approach to regulatory reform. Journal
of Corporation Law, 34(3), 923-942.
Schmidt, R. 2009. The political debate about savings banks.
Schmalenbach Business Review: ZFBF, 61(4), 366392.
Scott, W. R. (2003). Organizations: Rational, natural and open
systems (Fifth Edition). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Small Business Development Centers in Iraq. (n.d.). Retrieved
November 19, 2009, from http://sbdc-iraq.com/Cms/.
United Nations (2005). International Year of Microcredit 2005.
Retrieved November 20, 2009, from
http://www.yearofmicrocredit.org/pages/whyayear/
whyayear_learnaboutyear.asp.
United States Agency for International Development (USAID). (n.d).
Tijara Project Retrieved November 20, 2009, from
http://www.tijara-iraq.com/?pname=welcome&t_t=Home
US Federal News Service. 2009. U.S. Agency for International
Development Microfinance Program in Iraq Tops $300 Million in
Micro-Loans. US Fed News Service, including US State News. Washington,
D.C. (2009, July 15).
Michael J. Rubach, University of Central Arkansas
Don B. Bradley III, University of Central Arkansas
Justin Eric Brown, University of Central Arkansas
Table 1
Differences between US and Iraq Microlending Industries
United States Iraq
Formality of Lending Formal Informal
System Highly Regulated for Unregulated
Banks and Commercial
Lenders (CDFIs)
Unregulated for NFPs
Economic Freedom High Low
Transaction Costs High Low
Ex-ante Individual Business Group Loans
Loans
Risk Avoidance Business Plan Peer Recommendations
Collateral
Credit History
Ex-post Enforcement Costly Societal Pressures
Regulatory Regime Usury Laws / Interest Innovative
Rate ceilings
Capital Holding
Requirements for
Commercial Lenders
Conservative
Markets (Dyal- Formal (structurally Informal (structurally
Chand, 2005) developed)--Need for under-developed)
more competitive
analysis
Government Support Mixed Strong