Human capital and the national accounts.
Jorgenson, Dale W.
KATHARINE Abraham's paper, "Accounting for Investments in
Formal Education" (2010), provides an excellent and comprehensive
survey of the main issues regarding the measurement of education and
provides important links to the substantial literature in labor
economics. Estimates of expenditures on education provide the starting
point for the measurement of investment in human capital. This approach
can be extended to expenditures on training, as in the recent work of
Carol Corrado, Charles Hulten, and Daniel Sichel (2009). While
expenditures on education and training are inputs into the process of
investment, the central question is: what is the output?
Barbara Fraumeni and I (1989) have proposed a measure of the output
of education and training, namely, the increment to lifetime labor
incomes. This accrues as current income to individuals who receive the
education and training. Our approach has the important advantage of
providing separate measures of output and input. The value of input into
investment in education is equal to expenditures on education and the
incomes of students in school. The value of output is equal to additions
to lifetime labor incomes.
The lifetime incomes approach to measuring investment in human
capital has attracted considerable attention from national accountants.
Michael Christian (2010) has developed new estimates for the United
States. Australia, Canada, France, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, and
Spain have developed measures of investment in formal education based on
our approach. In September, the OECD launched a project to apply this
approach to more than 20 countries, including the major OECD countries.
A research project on these measures was completed for China last
October. (1)
There has been a steady growth of interest in applying national
accounting ideas to economic activity that occurs outside markets. While
the boundary between market and nonmarket activities has always been
ambiguous, the traditional approach to national accounting has leaned
toward a narrow definition of the boundaries. Systems of
"satellite" accounts apply a broader definition but are
consistent with national accounting principles. Formal education is an
obvious candidate for such a satellite system because of its economic
importance.
National accounting principles stress the use of accounting
concepts such as double-entry bookkeeping and the separation of quantity
changes from value changes through the use of prices. The National
Academies report by Abraham and Christopher Mackie Beyond the Market
(2005) presents these ideas and applies them to a wide range of issues,
including investment in human capital. The report is summarized in their
chapter in A New Architecture for the U.S. National Accounts, a book
edited by Steven Landefeld, William Nordhaus and me (2006). Nordhaus has
contributed a chapter to this book outlining the basic principles of
nonmarket accounting.
A second reason for the emergence of interest in our approach is
the increasing currency of the basic concepts of capital theory in the
national accounts. The work of the Canberra II group, part of the United
Nations 2008 System of National Accounts, has been instrumental in
developing a workable approach to the application of capital theory to
national accounting issues. The results are summarized in Paul
Schreyer's OECD Manual: Measuring Capital (2009). These ideas are
applied to the U.S. national accounts in my paper with Landefeld. (2)
From the point of view of these recent developments in national
accounting, Barbara Fraumeni and I have applied the same principles to
human capital as to other forms of capital. We have established the
conceptual basis for including investment in formal education in the
output of the economy. We have also developed measures of the
contribution of net saving in the form of human capital to the income
and expenditure account and the contribution of the stock of human
capital to the national wealth.
The key to measuring investment in formal education is the
definition of human wealth as lifetime labor income. The value of human
wealth for society as a whole is the sum of lifetime labor incomes over
the whole population. Since the value of this investment includes
nonmarket incomes of individuals who participate in formal education, it
is important to include both market and nonmarket components of lifetime
labor incomes. By measuring the increments to lifetime labor incomes
with increases in educational attainment, we can quantify investments in
formal education.
The key inputs into a satellite system for formal education are
first, an estimate of the population, classified by age, sex, and
education. Data on market labor incomes for the employed population are
available from the Census of Population and the Current Population
Survey. We have controlled estimates of hours worked to totals from the
national accounts. We make similar estimates for nonmarket labor time up
to 14 hours per day. These estimates could be improved by the
incorporation of data from the American Time Use Survey as Abraham
suggests.
We estimate the value of nonmarket time to be the after-tax market
wage multiplied by the nonmarket time available. This is consistent with
evidence from microeconomic studies, like those cited by Abraham. Our
key assumption is to anchor expectations about future wages with current
data for wages of people with the same gender and educational attainment
but different ages. We also allow for an increase in wages, relative to
current wages, at a constant rate, which we interpret as the rate of
labor-augmenting technical change.
We view investment in formal education as a production process with
outputs given by increments to lifetime incomes and inputs of
educational institutions--most importantly, teachers' labor
compensation--as well as the services of school facilities and the costs
of school materials and other expenses. However, the inputs also include
the value of the time of students, and this is precisely equal to the
increments in their lifetime incomes since they "own" all the
benefits of a better education. In a system of national accounts this
must be counted as their current income from schooling.
The same principles can be applied to training, provided that
expenditures on training can be identified and individuals can be
classified not only by educational attainment but also by the training
they have received. To separate investment in formal education from
investment in training, it would be necessary to cross-classify
individuals by educational attainment and training. Similarly, this
principle could also be applied to other investments in human capital,
such as medical care, provided that the population can be classified by
health status.
Fraumeni and I have also applied this accounting approach to child
rearing by the family. The change in lifetime incomes from maturing or
"growing up" is a form of investment in human capital. This is
an output of the family but accrues to the child as income. Finally, we
have applied these principles to the value of new individuals added to
the population, whether through birth or immigration. Individuals are
subtracted from the population through death or emigration. Investment
is the difference between the additions and the subtractions. Both
demographic accounting and time use accounting can be incorporated into
a satellite accounting system for human capital.
My main conclusion is that accounting for human capital should be
viewed as an important addition to national accounting for nonmarket
activities, perhaps the most important addition. Investment in human
capital is the ultimate intangible form of investment. This includes,
but is not limited to, investment in formal education. Abraham has
provided an up-to-date survey of this topic that can serve as a guide to
the Bureau of Economic Analysis and other statistical agencies
interested in exploring this important new frontier for research on
national accounting.
References
Abraham, Katharine G. 2010. "Accounting for Investments in
Formal Education." Unpublished paper. College Park: University of
Maryland.
Abraham, Katharine G., and Christopher Mackie, eds. 2005. Beyond
the Market: Designing Nonmarket Accounts for the United States.
Washington, DC: National Academies Press.
Abraham, Katharine G., and Christopher Mackie, eds. 2006. "A
Framework for Nonmarket Accounting." In A New Architecture for the
U.S. National Accounts, eds. Dale W. Jorgenson, J. Steven Landefeld and
William D. Nordhaus, 13-112. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Christian, Michael S. 2010. "Human Capital Accounting in the
United States, 1994-2006." Unpublished working paper. Madison, WI:
University of Wisconsin Center for Education Research.
Corrado, Carol A., Charles R. Hulten, and Daniel E. Sichel. 2009.
"Intangible Capital and U.S. Economic Growth." Review of
Income and Wealth 55, no. 3 (September): 661-685.
Jorgenson, Dale W., and Barbara M. Fraumeni. 1989. "The
Accumulation of Human and Nonhuman Capital." In The Measurement of
Saving, Investment, and Wealth, eds. Robert E. Lipsey and Helen Stone
Tice, 227-281. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Jorgenson, Dale W., and J. Steven Landefeld. 2006., "Blueprint
for an Expanded and Integrated U.S. National Accounts: Review,
Assessment, and Next Steps." In A New Architecture for the U.S.
National Accounts, eds. Dale W. Jorgenson, J. Steven Landefeld and
William D. Nordhaus, 13-112. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Jorgenson, Dale W., J. Steven Landefeld, and William D. Nordhaus,
eds. A New Architecture for the U.S. National Accounts. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Liu, Gang. 2010. "The OECD Human Capital Project: Progress
Report." Paris: Organisation for Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD) Statistics Directorate, Committee on Statistics, May
20.
Schreyer, Paul. 2009. OECD Manual: Measuring Capital. Paris:
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development.
(1.) See Gang Liu (2010).
(2.) Jorgenson and Landefeld (2006).
Dale W. Jorgenson is the Samuel W. Morris University Professor at
Harvard University and Chairman of the Bureau of Economic Analysis
Advisory Committee. More information about the author is available at
www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/jorgenson.