Preview of the 2003 comprehensive revision of the national income and product accounts: changes in definitions and classifications.
Moulton, Brent R. ; Seskin, Eugene P.
IN December, the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) will release the
initial results of a comprehensive, or benchmark, revision of the
national income and product accounts (NIPA's). This revision is the
12th of its kind; the last such revision was released in October 1999.
Comprehensive revisions differ from annual NIPA revisions because
of the scope of the changes and because of the number of years subject
to revision. Comprehensive revisions incorporate three major types of
improvements: (1) Changes in definitions and classifications that update
the accounts to more accurately portray the evolving U.S. economy, (1)
(2) statistical changes that update the accounts to reflect the
introduction of new and improved methodologies and the incorporation of
newly available and revised source data, and (3) presentational changes
that update the NIPA tables to reflect the definitional and statistical
changes and to make the tables more informative.
This article is the second in a series of SURVEY OF CURRENT
BUSINESS articles about the comprehensive revision. An article in the
January 2003 issue described the effects of incorporating the 1997
benchmark input-output (I-O) accounts and identified some of the
proposals being considered for this comprehensive revision. (2) An
article in the August issue will describe the new and redesigned tables.
(3) An article in the September issue will describe the statistical
changes. An article in the January 2004 issue will describe other
aspects of the revision, including estimates of the effects of the
definitional and statistical changes.
Comprehensive revisions, and to a lesser extent annual revisions,
provide the opportunity to introduce major changes that are outlined in
BEA's strategic plan for maintaining and improving its economic
accounts. (4) In discussing the national accounts, BEA's strategic
plan outlines several major objectives, including addressing data gaps
and other shortcomings, improving consistency and integration with other
accounts, and improving consistency with international guidelines. The
definitional, presentational, and statistical improvements planned for
this year's comprehensive revision constitute important steps
toward meeting each of these objectives.
For example, the measurement of financial and insurance services
has long been considered a shortcoming in the NIPA's. The
definitional changes that will be made to the measures of property and
casualty insurance and of commercial banking that are described in this
article are the result of considerable research by BEA staff and reflect
a better understanding of the output of these industries. A number of
other changes that address data gaps and other shortcomings will be
presented in the September article on statistical changes.
Several changes to sector definitions will improve the consistency
and integration of the NIPA's with other accounts, such as
BEA's I-O accounts, the Federal Reserve Board's flow of funds accounts, and the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) productivity
statistics. These changes will enable data users to move more easily
from one set of accounts to another, thereby expanding the set of
information that can be brought to bear in studying economic changes in
a sector or an industry. For example, balance sheets that are integrated
with the NIPA's would be useful in examining the association
between the rise in wealth in the late 1990s and the decline in personal
saving.
Increased integration of the world's monetary, fiscal, and
trade policies has led to a growing need for international harmonization of economic statistics. Many of the definitional changes presented in
this year's revision will improve consistency with the principal
international guidelines for national accounts, System of National
Accounts 1993. (5) BEA actively participated in preparing SNA 1993, and
after it was approved by the United Nations Statistical Commission, BEA
announced that it would move its accounts toward SNA 1993. (6) Since
then, BEA has adopted most of the major SNA 1993 changes that affect
gross domestic product (GDP), investment, and saving. In the 1996
comprehensive revision, chain-type indexes were adopted for measuring
changes in real GDP and prices, and government fixed investment was
recognized. In the 1999 comprehensive revision, investment in software
was recognized, the treatment of government employee retirement plans
was changed, and capital transfers were identified separately from
current transfers. For this year's comprehensive revision, the
changes will help bring the NIPA classifications of various transactions
into conformity with the classifications used by SNA 1993. While these
changes, together with the presentational changes that will be described
in the August article, will modify the appearance of the NIPA's, in
most cases they do not affect the major aggregates, such as GDP, gross
national product (GNP), personal income, profits, saving, and
investment. (However, national income will be redefined as described in
the section "Consistency With International Guidelines.")
BEA supports the goal of international harmonization of its
national accounts, and the NIPA's will continue to adopt SNA 1993
to the extent feasible. Nevertheless, because BEA has decided to retain
several important NIPA aggregates, such as personal income and corporate
profits, that do not appear in SNA 1993, some differences will persist.
In most cases, the classification systems used by the NIPA's for
sectors, industries, and type of product differ from those recommended
by SNA 1993. In efforts to harmonize these systems, BEA must consider
the needs of the U.S. user community along with the goal of improved
international harmonization. Improving consistency with SNA 1993 remains
an element of BEA's mission of producing accurate, relevant, and
timely statistics, of responding to customers, and of meeting the
challenges of a changing economy.
The major changes in definitions and classifications that will be
introduced in this comprehensive revision are as follows.
* Recognize the implicit services provided by property and casualty
insurance and provide a more appropriate treatment of insured losses,
thereby reducing large swings in measured services
* Allocate a portion of the implicit services of commercial banks
to borrowers, thereby recognizing that both borrowers and depositors
receive these services from banks
* Recognize explicitly the services produced by general government
and treat government purchases of goods and services as intermediate
inputs
* Broaden the definition of national income to include all net
incomes (net of consumption of fixed capital) earned in production
In addition to these major changes, a number of other changes in
definitions and classifications will be introduced, including the
following.
* Reclassify Indian tribal governments, farm housing services,
owner-occupied housing services, and rental value of fixed assets used
by nonprofit institutions serving households in order to improve
conformity with other BEA accounts and with accounts of other agencies
and to make the NIPA's more usable
* Reclassify certain NIPA components--including miscellaneous
compensation, nonresident taxes, business and personal nontax payments,
and government current receipts and expenditures--in order to improve
consistency with international guidelines
* Split the NIPA foreign transactions account into two
accounts--the foreign transactions current account and the foreign
transactions capital account--in order to separately identify capital
transfers
* Introduce several new aggregates that will provide alternative
measures of income, saving, and investment
* Redefine change in private farm inventories to include farm
materials and supplies, thereby improving the measures of GDP and gross
farm product
* Reclassify military grants-in-kind to improve consistency between
the NIPA's and BEA's international transactions accounts
(ITA's)
* Redefine compensation-in-kind of Federal Government employees to
include mass transit benefits
In the following sections of the article, each change is described,
the reason for the change is given, and the effect on the accounts is
provided. In addition, whenever available, preliminary estimates of the
impact of the change are provided.
For each change, table 1 shows the aggregates and components of the
current NIPA five-account system (see table 2) that will be affected and
the initial year of the revision.
Addressing Data Gaps and Other Shortcomings
This comprehensive revision will introduce definitional changes
that will refine the concepts used to measure property and casualty
insurance services, implicit services of banks, farm inventories, and
compensation of Federal Government employees. These changes, together
with the changes in source data and methods that will be described in
the September article on statistical changes, will address many of the
data gaps and other shortcomings in the NIPA's.
Insurance services
The definition of property and casualty insurance services (other
than health insurance) will be changed to recognize the implicit
services that are funded by investment income; to provide a more
appropriate treatment of insured losses, thereby reducing the large
swings in measured services that result from catastrophes such as the
terrorist attacks of September 11, 2001; and to change the treatment of
reinsurance. (7) This change, which will be carried back to 1929,
represents another step in BEA's effort to improve its measures of
the production of services. (8)
Insurance companies provide financial protection to policyholders
through the pooling of risk, and they provide financial intermediation
services through the investment of reserves that are held to help cover
extraordinary losses. The provision of these services of financial
protection and financial intermediation represent the output of the
insurance industry. Depending on whether the policyholder is a person,
general government, the rest of the world, or a domestic enterprise,
these services appear in personal consumption expenditures (PCE),
government consumption expenditures, exports of services, or
intermediate inputs of owner-occupied housing and of business. In most
periods, the insurance premiums received and the investment income
earned provide the funds needed for a "normal," or expected,
level of insurance claims and insurance services and for additions to
reserves. However, in some periods, funds must be withdrawn from
reserves to cover extraordinary losses. Alternatively, the insurance
company may purchase reinsurance as a protection against extraordinary
losses. Therefore, after accounting for investment income, insurance
companies set premiums in order to cover the expected costs of providing
the services, of settling claims, of maintaining reserves against future
claims, and of purchasing reinsurance.
Implicit services. In the NIPA's, the value of insurance
services (except for life insurance) is currently measured as the
premiums receivable by insurance carriers less the actual insured losses
incurred and the dividends payable by mutual insurance companies to
their policyholders. As part of the new treatment, the value of the
expected investment income on the funds on which policyholders have
claim will be added to the value of the premiums earned--that is, the
portion of the premiums accrued during the period. This expected
investment income is not output in and of itself, but it will be used to
impute the value of the implicit component of the intermediation
services provided to policyholders. This change recognizes that in
setting their premiums, insurance companies take into account the
expected income that may be earned from the investment of reserves. This
implicit component of insurance services will be referred to as a
premium supplement. (9)
Normal losses. Another major aspect of the redefinition involves
the substitution of normal losses for actual losses incurred in a period
in the calculation of the value of insurance services. This change
recognizes that in setting their premiums, insurance companies do not
yet know the actual losses in the period. Normal losses represent an
approximation of the losses expected to be incurred by the insurance
company--that is, the benefits they expect to pay to policy holders.
This change will reduce the large swings in measured insurance services
that result from catastrophes such as Hurricane Andrew in 1992 and the
terrorist attacks on September 11, 2001.
Formulas. For each type of insurance, normal losses will be
calculated as a geometric-weighted moving average of past loss ratios
(that is, the ratio of actual losses to premiums earned) multiplied by
the premiums earned during the current period. That is, the normal loss
in period t, N[L.sub.t], is
N[L.sub.t] = NL[R.sub.t] x [P.sub.t]
where
NL[R.sub.t] = [alpha]L[R.sub.t] + [alpha](1 - [alpha])L[R.sub.t-1]
+ [alpha][(1 - [alpha]).sup.2] L[R.sub.t-2] ...,
[P.sub.t] is the premiums earned, L[R.sub.t] is the loss
ratio--that is, [L.sub.t]/[P.sub.t]--in period t, and [alpha] is a
parameter. Premiums earned and loss ratios are based on trade source
data. The formula is based on the adaptive-expectations model developed
by Cagan. (10) The "free" parameter [alpha] is the weight
applied to the prior period's value in the weighted average; this
parameter will be assigned a value of 0.3 based on evidence that it
provides the best prediction of future values. (11) Thus, for every
deviation in the loss ratio from its previously expected value, the
normal, or expected, value for the subsequent period is adjusted by 30
percent.
For each type of insurance, premium supplements will be calculated
as a geometric-weighted moving average of past investment gain/loss
ratios (that is, "net investment gain/loss on funds attributable to
insurance transactions" divided by premiums earned) multiplied by
the premiums earned during the current period. (12) That is, the premium
supplement in period t, P[S.sub.t], is
P[S.sub.t] = NI[R.sub.t] x [P.sub.t]
where
NI[R.sub.t] = [beta]I[R.sub.t] + [beta](1 - [beta])I[R.sub.t-1] +
[beta][(1 - [beta]).sup.2]I[R.sub.t-2] ...,
I[R.sub.t] is the investment gain/loss ratio--that is,
[I.sub.t]/[P.sub.t]--in period t, and [beta] is a parameter, which will
be assigned a value of 0.3. Net investment gains/losses on funds
attributable to insurance transactions are available from trade source
data and represent the industry rate of return on investment multiplied
by the reserves that are directly attributable to policyholders because
of prepayment of premiums or accrual of benefits.
Reinsurance. Insurance services will be calculated from source data
on direct premiums and direct losses--that is, without any adjustment
for reinsurance. Transactions related to reinsurance will be treated in
the same way as those related to direct insurance, and the services of
reinsurance will be treated as an intermediate input to the insurance
carriers industry or as exports of services. Currently, insurance
services are calculated from premiums and losses after netting the value
of reinsurance that is assumed or ceded.
New flows. As a result of the above changes, several new insurance
flows will be recognized in the NIPA's. An insurance company
receives premiums and investment income that must fund the ongoing
production of services as well as covering a normal level of losses;
extraordinary losses are paid from reserves or from reinsurance. One can
think of these transactions as being decomposed into four pieces. (1)
The policyholders pay the insurance company total premiums (including
the imputed portion) equal to the premiums earned plus premium
supplements less dividends payable to policyholders. A portion of this
total premium is considered a payment for insurance services consumed and is valued as total premiums less normal losses. (2) The remaining
portion of the total premium, which is equal to normal losses, is a
transfer-like flow from the policyholders to the insurance company that
is used to pay for actual losses, additions to reserves, and
reinsurance. (3) Because premium supplements are funded by investment
income from the portion of reserves that are, in principle, the property
of the policyholders, the accounts must show an equal flow of imputed
income paid to the policyholders, which will be classified as imputed
interest. (4) Actual insured losses (or claims payable) are a
transfer-like flow from the insurance company to the policyholder. (13)
The net value of (4) minus (2), which equals actual losses less normal
losses, will be referred to as "net insurance settlements."
Effects on the accounts. As a result of the new treatment, PCE,
government consumption expenditures, and exports will each change by the
value of premium supplements on policies held by the corresponding
sector plus the difference between actual losses and normal losses on
insurance held by the sector. Imports will change by the value of
premium supplements on policies of foreign insurance carriers held by
domestic residents plus the difference between actual losses and normal
losses on those policies. GDP will change by the sum of the value of the
changes in PCE, in government consumption expenditures, and in exports
less the value of the change in imports. Premium supplements on policies
purchased by business and on policies purchased by homeowners for
owner-occupied housing will be treated as intermediate inputs and will
not affect the value of GDP.
Offsetting flows will appear on the income side of the NIPA's.
Net interest will increase to reflect the implicit income, which is
equal to the premium supplements that are allocated to persons and to
government. Income receipts from the rest of the world will increase by
an amount equal to the premium supplements that are allocated to
domestic policies issued by foreign insurance carriers, and income
payments to the rest of the world will increase by an amount equal to
the premium supplements allocated to foreign policyholders. Business
transfer payments will change by the value of net insurance settlements
(actual losses less normal losses) paid to persons, to government, and
to the rest of the world, less net insurance settlements received by
domestic business from foreign insurance carriers. The change to gross
domestic income (GDI) will equal the change to GDP, so the statistical
discrepancy will not be affected. Because the flows of premium
supplements to and from the rest of the world are offset by the flows of
implicit income, the addition of premium supplements to exports and to
imports will not affect GNP; consequently, the change to GNP will equal
the value of net insurance settlements that will be included in business
transfer payments plus the value of premium supplements added to PCE and
to government consumption expenditures.
In the personal income and outlay account (account 2), personal
interest income will increase by the value of imputed interest
attributable to persons as policyholders, and business transfer payments
to persons will change to reflect net insurance settlements received by
persons. Within personal outlays, PCE will change as described above.
The changes to the income components will equal the changes to personal
outlays, so personal saving will not be affected.
In the government receipts and expenditures account (account 3),
net insurance settlements received by government will be shown as
"business transfer payments to government" (a new NIPA
category within current receipts that will be further discussed in the
section "Indirect business tax and nontax liabilities"). Net
interest paid will be reduced by the imputed interest attributable to
government as policyholders (also see the section "Government
current receipts and expenditures," which explains that interest
received will be reclassified as part of government receipts).
Government consumption expenditures will change as described above. The
changes to the current receipts components will equal the changes to the
current expenditures components, so the government current surplus or
deficit will not be affected.
Within the foreign transactions account (account 4), exports,
imports, and income receipts and payments will change as described
above. Transfer payments to the rest of the world (net) will change by
the value of net insurance settlements paid to the rest of the world
less net insurance settlements received from the rest of the world. Net
foreign investment will not be affected.
The gross saving and investment account (account 5) will not be
affected by this definitional change.
Implicit services of banks
In the NIPA's, an imputation is made for the services that
banks and other depository institutions provide without an explicit
charge. These services include processing checks, disbursing or
transferring funds when and where needed, bookkeeping, protecting
deposited funds, and investment services. Charges for these services may
be explicit, or they may be implicit--that is, banks may pay depositors
lower interest rates rather than charging for each service provided.
(14)
BEA has imputed the value of these implicit services as the
monetary interest that banks receive from loans and securities less the
interest that they pay on deposits and other liabilities, and it has
treated depositors as the consumers of these services. The imputed
expenditures for the implicit services appear on the product side of the
NIPA's in PCE, in exports of services, and in government
consumption expenditures; they are treated as intermediate inputs for
business.
One of the most important services provided by banks is financial
intermediation--collecting funds from depositors or lenders and
repackaging them in ways that meet the needs of borrowers, thereby
reducing transactions costs for both depositors and borrowers. SNA 1993
recommends that the value of these implicit services be allocated partly
to depositors and partly to borrowers, recognizing that both depositors
and borrowers receive these implicit services from banks and other
depository institutions. (15) Therefore, as part of the upcoming
comprehensive revision, BEA will allocate the implicit services of
commercial banks to borrowers as well as to depositors. (16) This
change, which will be carried back to 1929, will reduce GDP and the
total gross output of banks. A significant source of the reduction in
GDP will be the reallocation of implicit services from final
expenditures to intermediate consumption because a larger share of
borrowed funds than deposited funds is attributable to business. GDI
will be reduced by the same amount as GDP, so the statistical
discrepancy will not be affected.
Use of a reference rate. SNA 1993 proposes that the implicit
financial services, which it terms "financial intermediation
services indirectly measured" (FISIM), be allocated using a
"reference rate" of interest that represents the opportunity
cost of borrowing or lending funds. (17) Under the reference-rate
approach, the difference between the interest received by depositors and
the interest they would have received had they been paid the reference
rate is the value of the implicit services to depositors. Similarly, the
difference between the interest paid by borrowers and the interest they
would have paid had they borrowed at the reference rate is the value of
the implicit services to borrowers.
The reference rate of interest in SNA 1993 represents the
"pure cost of borrowing funds"--a rate that does not include a
risk premium or any intermediation services. (18) BEA investigated two
approaches to estimating the reference rate, one based on current market
interest rates and one based on "book-value" interest rates.
Empirical tests indicated that the use of current market interest rates
would cause excessive volatility in the estimates of implicit services
to depositors and to borrowers, while the use of book-value rates would
not. (19)
Book-value interest rates are computed by dividing the annualized interest receipt or payment for a financial product by the stock of that
financial product on the balance sheet. To estimate a reference rate,
BEA divided the interest received from Treasury and Federal agency
securities for each period by the average book values of these
securities held by banks during that period. These types of securities
are highly liquid and free of credit risk, so their interest rates are
presumed to exclude the costs of risk-bearing or illiquidity in addition
to excluding routine services to loan customers, such as bookkeeping.
Use of this reference rate implies that the Federal Government receives
no implicit services from financial intermediaries holding securities.
Allocation among sectors. As discussed above, the allocation to
sectors of the implicit services provided by banks and certain other
financial intermediaries is currently based on deposits. Once the
implicit services provided to borrowers is recognized, this allocation
will change because households tend to hold a larger share of deposits,
whereas businesses--including owner-occupied housing (which is treated
like a business)--tend to receive a larger share of loans. (20) Thus,
the share of implicit services allocated to final demand (by households,
government, and the rest of the world) will decrease, and the share of
implicit services allocated to intermediate consumption (by business)
will increase.
Banking output. The recognition of borrower services will also
result in changes to the measure of the unpriced, or imputed, portion of
the gross output of commercial banks. Currently, the imputed gross
output of banks and similar depository institutions is calculated as the
interest received from borrowers net of the interest paid to depositors
and to other providers of funds. A rationale for this calculation is
that if banks were to charge explicit fees for all of their services,
the interest paid to depositors would be equal to the interest earned on
the investment of their deposits. (21)
An assumption implicit in this calculation is that deposits are the
only source of funds available to banks for making loans and for
purchasing securities. However, a bank's "own funds"
(that is, funds that come from stockholders' equity rather than
from deposits or other liabilities) are also a source of funds for
lending, so the value of loans and other interest-bearing assets
generally exceeds the value of deposits and other interest-bearing
liabilities. When a bank loans its own funds, it avoids the cost of
paying interest on deposits. Therefore, implicit services should not be
attributed to depositors for the interest earned by the bank on the
portion of its assets that is in excess of its liabilities, because
depositors are not the source of these funds. Similarly, implicit
services should not be attributed to stockholders, because no such
services are provided on stockholders' equity.
Because the new method separately values the opportunity cost to
the bank of using own funds, this amount can be deducted from the
imputation of expenditures for borrower and depositor services. To
prevent an incorrect imputation of depositor services on
stockholders' equity, the measure of imputed output must be reduced
by an amount equal to the reference rate multiplied by the difference
between the bank's assets and liabilities. Consequently, adoption
of the reference-rate approach will reduce imputed gross output.
The effects of this change can be shown diagrammatically.
Currently, imputed gross output of banks is calculated as the rate of
return on assets (rA) multiplied by the value of assets (vA) less the
rate paid on liabilities (rL) multiplied by the value of liabilities
(vL) (figure 1). Thus, the imputed gross output of banks is represented
by the sum of the areas A + B + C. With the allocation of a portion of
banks' imputed output to borrowers, gross imputed output of banks
will be calculated as the difference between the rate of return on
assets and the reference rate (rr) multiplied by the value of assets
plus the difference between the reference rate and the rate paid on
liabilities multiplied by the value of liabilities, or ((rA-rr) x vA) +
((rr-rL) x vL). Thus, the imputed gross output of banks is represented
by the sum of the areas A + B. The net effect of the definitional change
is to reduce gross output by the reference rate multiplied by "own
funds" (the difference between the value of assets and the value of
liabilities), or rr x (vA - vL), which is represented by area C.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
As is evident from figure 1, the new measure of imputed gross
output will be sensitive to how the relevant types of assets and
liabilities are defined. Assets included in the calculation of imputed
output consist primarily of loans, securities, and balances due from
other banks. (22) Liabilities included consist primarily of deposits
plus some nondeposit, interest-bearing liabilities, such as subordinated
debt and repurchase agreements. In short, assets are limited to earning
assets, and liabilities, to sources of funds.
Domestic and foreign output. To calculate U.S. domestic banking
output, adjustments are made to remove the output of foreign offices of
U.S.-owned banks and to add the output of foreign-owned bank offices in
the United States. These adjustments are necessary because the primary
source data used to estimate the output of the banking industry, the
Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council Call Reports
published by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, include foreign
offices of U.S. banks and exclude the U.S. offices of foreign banks.
Foreign offices of U.S.-owned banks. The output of foreign offices
of U.S. banks is currently measured as the difference between their
interest receipts from borrowers and their interest payments to
depositors. In recent years, the value of deposits in foreign offices
has substantially exceeded the value of loans made, but interest rates
on deposits are generally lower than interest rates on loans. As a
result, depositors have received about the same amount of interest as
borrowers have paid, so essentially no output has been attributed to the
foreign offices.
Adoption of the reference-rate approach will result in more output
being attributed to the foreign offices of U.S.-owned banks.
Specifically, the output of foreign offices will increase by an amount
equal to the reference rate multiplied by the difference between the
deposits and the loans of the foreign offices. Currently, the imputed
gross output of these foreign offices is calculated as the rate of
return paid on assets multiplied by the value of assets minus the rate
of return paid on liabilities multiplied by the value of liabilities, or
(rA x vA) - (rL x vL) (figure 2). This imputation is represented by the
areas A + B + C - (C + F), or A + B - F. With the allocation of a
portion of banks' imputed output to borrowers, area F is no longer
subtracted from the gross output of the foreign offices, and area E is
added to their gross output.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Because the output of foreign offices of U.S.-owned banks is
deducted from the worldwide gross output of U.S. banks to arrive at
domestic output, increases in the output of foreign offices will result
in decreases in the domestic output. These decreases reflect a more
accurate allocation of the implicit services provided by domestic banks
to their foreign and domestic customers.
Foreign-owned bank offices in the United States. The revisions to
the estimated output of foreign-owned banks in the United States will
reflect improved source data and are not primarily a result of the
adoption of the reference-rate approach. Output of foreign banks is
currently measured by applying ratios of balance-sheet items for all
banks in the United States to the corresponding items for U.S.-owned
banks. (23) BEA will continue to use this general approach for measuring
the output of these foreign-owned offices. However, the ratios will be
revised using improved source data, and they will be applied at a more
detailed level to account more accurately for differences in rates
earned on different types of assets or paid on different types of
liabilities. The revisions to the ratios will lower the estimates of the
imputed output of the foreign-owned offices for recent years, because of
both lower estimates of their interest income from assets and higher
estimates of their interest expense for liabilities.
Effects on components of GDP and GDI. The allocation of a portion
of implicit financial services to borrowers will not alter the
"identity" between imputed gross output of financial
intermediaries and the corresponding net interest flows; therefore, the
statistical discrepancy will not be affected. GDP will record the final
demand for implicit financial services by household borrowers (other
than for owner-occupied housing) and household depositors in PCE, by
government borrowers and depositors in government consumption
expenditures, and by rest-of-the-world borrowers and depositors in
exports of services.
As discussed above, banks are considered to pay depositors imputed
interest that is equal to the imputed expenditures for implicit services
provided to depositors. The treatment of depositor services will be the
same as the present treatment, though the values of these services will
be smaller.
For borrowers, however, the treatment of imputed interest will
change. A portion of the interest the borrower pays to the bank will be
considered an expenditure for implicit services; therefore, the interest
paid by the borrower, and received by the bank, will be reduced by the
amount of the imputed expenditure for borrower services. (24) This
reduction of borrower interest will be accomplished by recording
negative imputed interest paid by the borrower and received by the bank.
For example, if a borrower in the personal sector pays a bank $100
interest, of which $20 is an imputed expenditure for implicit services,
then the accounts will show the borrower paying $80 interest--consisting
of $100 in monetary interest and -$20 in imputed interest--and $20 in
PCE. The effect on net interest is the same as if the bank had paid
imputed interest, because net interest equals interest paid by business
and by the rest of the world, less interest received by business and by
the rest of the world. (25) The effect on net interest of negative
imputed interest received by the bank is therefore the same as the
effect of positive imputed interest paid by the bank. This treatment of
borrower services recognizes that these services are not actually
unpriced; rather, the price for borrower services is embedded in the
interest paid by the borrower.
Net interest will be equal to the imputed gross output less the
implicit financial services consumed by domestic business, by households
on borrowing for owner-occupied housing, by nonprofit institutions
serving households, and by the rest of the world. Net interest from
services to depositors will equal the imputed interest paid by banks,
less the imputed interest received by domestic business and by the rest
of the world. Net interest from services to borrowers will equal the
imputed interest paid by domestic business, by households on borrowing
for owner-occupied housing, by nonprofit institutions serving
households, and by the rest of the world, less the imputed interest
received by banks. Imputed income payments to the rest of the world will
equal the imputed interest received by the rest of the world for
depositor services. Imputed income receipts from the rest of the world
will equal the imputed interest paid by the rest of the world for
borrower services.
Preliminary estimates. Based on preliminary estimates, the gross
output of banks will be revised down about $69 billion for 2001. The
imputed output of foreign-owned bank offices in the United States will
be revised down about $26 billion, the upward revision to the imputed
output of foreign offices of U.S. banks will reduce domestic output
about $24 billion, and the imputed output of the domestic offices of
U.S. banks will be revised down about $19 billion. (26) Because of the
reallocation of part of the implicit services from depositors to
borrowers which reallocates consumption of these services from final
expenditures to intermediate purchases--the downward revision to GDP
will be larger than the downward revision to bank gross output. Again,
based on preliminary estimates, GDP will be revised down about $93
billion for 2001: PCE will be revised down about $78 billion, net
exports will be revised down about $9 billion, and government
consumption expenditures and gross investment will be revised down about
$6 billion.
Farm inventories
In the production account of the farm sector, inventories of farm
materials and supplies will be added to the change in private farm
inventories and subtracted from intermediate goods and services
purchased. This change will improve the measures of GDP and gross farm
product, maintain consistency with the 1997 I-O accounts, and move the
NIPA's closer to SNA 1993. The change, which will be carried back
to 1991, will affect GDP and GDI by small, but differing, amounts and
will eliminate a small discrepancy between the product side and the
income side of the NIPA's.
Currently, the change in private farm inventories reflects
inventories of crops and of livestock. However, materials and
supplies--such as feed, seed, and fertilizer--are not reflected in
inventories. Consequently, the NIPA estimates of GDP, gross farm
product, national income, and personal income are misstated if materials
and supplies are purchased but not "consumed" in the same
period: For example, GDP will be understated because measured nonfarm
inventories of the supplier are reduced with no corresponding addition
to measured farm inventories; and in the farm production account, gross
farm product and farm proprietors' income will be understated
because intermediate purchases are not reduced by the materials and
supplies added to farm inventories.
When the change in farm inventories of materials and supplies is
added to GDR only the proprietors' share of this inventory change
will be added to GDI (to farm proprietors' income). The residual
corporate share of the inventory change is already accounted for in the
source data from the IRS Statistics of Income program, which are used to
estimate the income of corporate farms.
Mass transit benefits
Mass transit benefits to Federal Government employees will be
incorporated into the estimates of Federal Government compensation
in-kind in order to improve the estimates of total compensation received
by Federal employees. Currently, these benefits are not included in the
compensation estimates, but they are included in PCE for transportation
services. Therefore, the incorporation of these benefits in Federal
compensation, which will be carried back to 1998, will eliminate a small
discrepancy between the product side and the income side of the
NIPA's. Federal consumption expenditures and gross investment will
not be affected, because the mass transit benefits will be reclassified
from intermediate inputs to compensation expense, leaving the total
value of the services produced by government unchanged. (27)
On October 1, 2000, all Federal Government employees in the
Washington, DC region became eligible for mass transit benefits of up to
$65 per month; in January 2002, the maximum monthly benefit rose to $100
per month. The benefits received by Federal employees now amount to
about $140 million annually.
The primary source data for the estimates of wages and salaries of
Federal Government employees do not include the mass transit benefits.
Annual estimates of the benefits will be based on data from the
Department of Transportation. Current estimates will be extrapolations
using data on monthly transit ridership from a trade association that
tracks these data for numerous mass transit systems.
Consistency and Integration With Other Accounts
The following changes in definitions or classifications will
improve the consistency and integration of the NIPA's with other
accounts, such as BEA's I-O accounts, the Federal Reserve
Board's flow of funds accounts, and the BLS productivity
statistics. These changes will also make the accounts more informative
by providing improved estimates covering the economic activities of
Indian tribal governments, by separately identifying owner-occupied
housing as a unique activity in the NIPA's, and by classifying the
rental value of nonprofit institutions' fixed assets and military
grants-in-kind in a more intuitive manner.
Changes in sector classification
The following paragraphs describe reclassifications that will
result in the movement of certain components across sectors of the
national accounts.
Indian tribal governments. Indian tribal governments and
enterprises will be reclassified from the private sector to the state
and local government sector. Conceptually, a reclassification from one
sector to another should not affect GDP, GDI, or the statistical
discrepancy. However, as discussed below, this reclassification, which
will be carried back to 1990, will increase GDP and GDI by differing
amounts.
Beginning with 2001, the primary source data used to estimate wages
and salaries--BLS tabulations of wages and salaries of workers covered
by the state unemployment insurance program--reclassified the wages of
Indian tribal governments and of Indian-owned enterprise employees from
the private sector to the state and local government sector. The BLS
reclassification followed a court decision mandating that Indian tribes
be treated similarly to governments in accordance with the Federal
Unemployment Tax Act. In the 2002 annual NIPA revision, the wages for
tribal governments were reclassified from private wages and salaries to
government wages and salaries. However, they were not added to the
portion of wages that is included in government consumption
expenditures, so the reclassification did not affect GDP.
In the upcoming comprehensive revision, the compensation of
employees of tribal governments whose primary activities are public
administration or provision of public services will now be classified as
state and local general government noneducation compensation, which is a
cost that contributes to the value of state and local government
consumption expenditures. The compensation of employees of tribal
governments whose primary activities are provision of goods or services
for sale--including employment in casinos, retail stores, and industrial
activities--will be classified as state and local government enterprise
compensation, which is not included in the value of state and local
government consumption expenditures. (28) For years prior to 2001,
compensation of tribal government employees will be subtracted from a
number of private-sector industries, including amusements, restaurants,
hotels, and membership organizations.
If the output of tribal governments had been fully captured in
BEA's source data, the reclassification would not affect GDP. The
governmental activities of tribal governments would have been classified
as nonprofit institutions serving households, and the sales of the
tribal enterprises would have been captured in PCE or in other GDP
components. Although the coverage of sales of enterprises (primarily
casinos in PCE) is reasonably good, the governmental activities of
tribal governments have largely been omitted from the source data used
to estimate the nonprofit components of PCE. Therefore, GDP will
increase as a result of the reclassification, because the additional
compensation of employees in state and local general government will be
larger than the offsetting reductions in the nonprofit components of
PCE.
The reclassification will also raise GDI because BEA will use a new
method to measure income from casinos operated by Indian tribes. About
half of the federally recognized Indian tribes operate casinos that are
classified as government enterprises. The revenue from these casinos
will continue to be recorded in the recreation component of PCE for
services. The profits of these casinos are not included in the source
data used for estimating corporate profits. The profits will now be
added to the current surplus of government enterprises, which will
increase GDI. Estimates of casino profits and expenses will be based on
publicly available financial report data. (29)
The increase in GDP associated with the additional wages in state
and local government consumption expenditures will differ from the
increase in GDI associated with the newly added casino profits in the
current surplus of government enterprises, so the statistical
discrepancy will be affected.
Farm housing services. The production of services of farm housing
owned by farm operators will be reclassified from the farm industry to
the real estate industry. (30) This change will make the industry
classification of these housing services in the NIPA's consistent
with that in the I-O accounts. Moreover, the treatment of these services
will be the same as that for farm housing owned by nonoperator landlords
and for all nonfarm housing. The reclassification, which will be carried
back to 1929, will not affect GDP or GDI, though it will affect the
composition by sector within these aggregates.
Currently, the services of farm housing are recorded as gross farm
output, and related maintenance and insurance expenses are recorded as
farm nonrent intermediate purchases. Consumption of fixed capital,
property taxes (in indirect business tax and nontax liability), and
mortgage interest (in net interest) are included in GDI. After the
reclassification, these items will be recorded in the households and
institutions sector. The related net income will be added to rental
income of persons with capital consumption adjustment (and offset by a
subtraction from farm proprietors' income). In addition, farm
housing units owned by farm operators will be reclassified from farm
capital stock to nonfarm (real estate) capital stock.
The U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), the source of most of
the farm-sector data for the NIPA's, will continue to classify the
services of farm housing owned by farm operators as farm production.
However, USDA will provide BEA with the detailed data necessary to
prepare the estimates on the NIPA basis.
Owner-occupied housing services. The production of services of
nonfarm and farm owner-occupied housing and their corresponding gross
products will be reclassified from the business sector to the households
and institutions sector. The reclassification will improve the
institutional composition of GDP, because the gross product of
owner-occupied housing is produced for the own final use of households
rather than sold on the market. In addition, the reclassification will
eliminate one difference between the sector classification used in the
NIPA's and that used by BLS in its productivity estimates. (31) The
reclassification will also improve consistency with the Federal Reserve
Board's flow of funds accounts, which classify owner-occupied
housing as part of the households sector rather than as part of the
nonfarm noncorporate business sector. This change, which will be carried
back to 1929, will not affect GDP or GDI.
Although owner-occupied housing services will be reclassified to
the households and institutions sector, the treatment of the
transactions associated with owner-occupied housing as business-type
transactions will be retained. Owner occupancy of a home is similar to
the activities of other business enterprises because it involves
incurring expenses (for example, mortgage interest, depreciation, and
property taxes) to produce a service. (32) Yet it differs from other
business activities because the housing service is produced solely for
the homeowner and does not involve a sale of the service to another
party. Because the services of owner-occupied housing are considered
production, property taxes will continue to be included in indirect
business taxes (not in personal taxes), mortgage interest will continued
to be included in net interest (not in interest paid by persons), and
expenditures for homeowners' insurance will be treated as
intermediate purchases (not in PCE).
Rental value of fixed assets used by nonprofit institutions serving
households. The rental value of fixed assets owned and used by nonprofit
institutions serving households (NPISH's) will be reclassified from
the business sector to the households and institutions sector. (33) The
reclassification will make the gross product of NPISH's more
comprehensive. In addition, the reclassification will eliminate a
difference between the sector classification used in the NIPA's and
that used by BLS in its productivity program. This change, which will be
carried back to 1929, will not affect GDP or GDI.
Conceptually, the gross product of NPISH's should equal the
sum of their expenses for labor and for property. Currently, the gross
product of NPISH's consists only of their labor expenses
(compensation of employees). The property expenses (net interest,
consumption of fixed capital, and indirect business tax and nontax
liability) are recorded implicitly in the business sector.
Currently, net interest is defined as the interest paid by private
business less the interest received by private business, plus the
interest received from the rest of the world less the interest paid to
the rest of the world. Interest payments on mortgage and
home-improvement loans and on home-equity loans are included in interest
paid by business because home ownership is treated as a business in the
NIPA's. Interest payments by NPISH's are included in interest
paid by "other" private business. As a result of the
reclassifications affecting farm housing services, owner-occupied
housing services, and the rental value of fixed assets used by
NPISH's, the definition of net interest will be expanded to include
mortgage interest paid by households for owner-occupied housing and the
interest paid by NPISH's.
Military grants-in-kind
The treatment of military grants-in-kind will be changed in order
to eliminate an inconsistency between the NIP's and the ITA's.
In the national income and product account (account 1), these grants
will be reclassified from Federal defense consumption expenditures to
exports of goods and services. In the government receipts and
expenditures account (account 3), these grants will be reclassified from
consumption expenditures to transfer payments to the rest of the world
(net). In the foreign transactions account (account 4), the increase in
transfer payments to the rest of the world (net) will be offset by an
increase in exports of goods and services. These changes, which will be
carried back to 1959, will not affect GDP, because the change in Federal
Government consumption expenditures will be offset by the change in
exports of goods and services.
Currently, economic and military cash assistance to foreign
governments, as well as nonmilitary assistance-in-kind, are classified
as transfer payments to the rest of the world. In contrast, military
assistance-in-kind, such as purchases of new military goods or services
that are delivered to foreign governments, are classified as defense
consumption expenditures. (Gifts to foreign governments of goods from
existing U.S. military stocks would have been included in defense
consumption expenditures in earlier time periods.)
The ITA's do not distinguish between cash and in-kind military
assistance: Both are treated the same as nonmilitary assistance, that
is, as exports of services, and the military portion is recorded as
"transfers under U.S. military agency sales contracts." This
treatment is consistent with international guidelines set forth in SNA
1993 and the International Monetary Fund's 1993 Balance of Payments
Manual. (34)
Consistency with International Guidelines
The following changes in definition and classification are largely
motivated by BEA's efforts to improve conformity with the
international guidelines contained in SNA 1993. In many cases, these
changes will also make the presentation of economic data in the
NIPA's more informative by separately identifying distinct types of
transactions, such as tobacco settlements and capital transfers, or by
presenting useful new aggregates, such as operating surplus and net
saving.
Services of general government
Governments serve several functions in the economy--as producers of
nonmarket services, as final consumers of these services (the value of
the services provided to the general public is treated as government
consumption expenditures), and as providers of transfer payments. These
functions are financed through taxation and through contributions to
social insurance funds. In the NIPA's, the consumption expenditures
of general government are currently presented as expenditures for
compensation of employees (except the labor services of employees
engaged in construction or software production that are classified as
investment), for consumption of fixed capital (CFC), and for goods and
services (net of sales). The value of general government GDP (or value
added) equals the sum of the expenditures for compensation of employees
and CFC, which is a partial measure of the services of government fixed
assets (general government purchases of goods and services are included
in the GDP of the business sector). (35) This framework does not
explicitly recognize that governments are engaged in producing
services--using labor, capital, and intermediate inputs.
For the upcoming comprehensive revision, BEA has designed a new
framework for government consumption expenditures--both Federal and
state and local--that will explicitly recognize the services produced by
general government. This change will be carried back to 1929.
The value of the government services, most of which are not sold in
the market, will be measured by the cost of inputs: Compensation, CFC,
and intermediate goods and services purchased. Purchases by general
government of goods and services will be reclassified as intermediate
purchases. The value of consumption expenditures and gross investment
will not change, because the value of the newly recognized services
produced by government will be equal to the cost of inputs, including
purchased goods and services. The new conceptual framework of the
services produced by government and of the goods and services purchased
by government will parallel the concepts of output and intermediate
inputs of private business in the I-O accounts and the GDP-by-industry
accounts; however, government output will be measured by costs of inputs
instead of by market prices.
As a result of these changes, the distribution of GDP by type of
product will be affected; services output will increase, and goods
output will decrease. Because the gross output of general government
will increase by the amount of the intermediate inputs, general
government GDP (which equals gross output less intermediate inputs) will
not change. Thus, general government GDP will continue to be measured as
the sum of compensation and CFC.
National income
National income will be redefined to include all net incomes (net
of CFC) earned in production. The current definition of national income
consists of "factor incomes"--that is the incomes accruing to
labor and property of U.S. residents. National income will now also
include "nonfactor charges"--that is, business transfer
payments, indirect business tax and nontax liabilities, and the current
surplus of government enterprises less subsidies. This change will be
carried back to 1929.
SNA 1993 does not distinguish between factor incomes and nonfactor
charges. It recognizes that indirect business taxes "are not taxes
... that can be eliminated from the input and output prices." (36)
The SNA 1993 definition of national income therefore includes all
incomes earned in production. In the NIPA's, national income (which
will also be known as net national income) will equal gross national
income less CFC. (37) Based on currently published 2001 estimates, this
redefinition would increase national income by about $770 billion (or
9.5 percent). GDP, GDI, personal income, personal saving, and national
(gross) saving will not be affected.
Reclassifications
Miscellaneous compensation of employees. Within compensation of
employees, the subcomponent "other" in other labor
income--which consists of judicial fees paid to jurors and to witnesses,
compensation of prison inmates, and marriage fees paid to justices of
the peace--will be reclassified as wages and salaries. The
reclassification, which will be carried back to 1948, will increase wage
and salary accruals (and disbursements) and will decrease other labor
income by the same amount. Total compensation of employees and other
NIPA aggregates will not be affected. After this reclassification, other
labor income will consist of employer contributions to pension and
welfare funds, such as private group health and life insurance plans.
This reclassification will align the definition of the NIPA category,
"supplements to wages and salaries," with the definition of
the SNA 1993 category, "employers' social contributions."
(38)
Nonresident taxes paid by domestic corporations. Nonresident
taxes--that is, taxes paid by domestic corporations to foreign
governments--will be reclassified as part of profits tax liability and
will be included in a new component that consists of tax payments to the
rest of the world. (39) Currently, these taxes are classified in
business transfer payments to the rest of the world, and an offsetting
downward adjustment is made to NIPA profits before tax (see line 17 of
NIPA table 8.25) so GDI is not affected. Under the new treatment, this
downward adjustment to profits before tax will no longer be needed, so
profits before tax will increase by the same amount as profits tax
liability. This change will be carried back to 1959; estimates of
nonresident taxes are not available before 1959.
Based on currently published 2001 estimates, the reclassification
would increase profits before tax and profits tax liability each by
about $9.1 billion and would decrease business transfer payments to the
rest of the world by the same amount. Profits after tax and other NIPA
aggregates will not be affected. The presentation of nonresident taxes
in the foreign transactions account, where they are shown as part of
transfer payments to the rest of the world (net), will not change.
Indirect business tax and nontax liabilities. Most of the nontax
components of indirect business tax and nontax liabilities will be
reclassified, and the remainder of the category will be renamed.
Specifically, Federal deposit insurance premiums and other nontaxes
(which consist largely of fines and of regulatory and inspection fees)
and state and local fines and other nontaxes (which consist largely of
donations and tobacco settlements) will be reclassified as business
transfer payments to government. This new category will also appear as a
current receipt in the government current receipts and expenditures
account. Federal Outer Continental Shelf royalties and state and local
rents and royalties will be reclassified as part of income payments on
assets (see the section "Income payments (or receipts) on
assets"). The remainder of the indirect business tax
category--which includes Federal excise taxes and customs duties and
state and local sales taxes, property taxes (including residential real
estate taxes), motor vehicle licenses, severance taxes, other taxes, and
special assessments--will be renamed taxes on production and imports.
These reclassifications will be carried back to 1929.
The reclassifications of business payments to government will
provide additional information to users by separating special payments,
such as tobacco settlements, from the taxes on production and imports.
In addition, these reclassifications will better align the NIPA
classifications with the classifications used in SNA 1993. (40)
Business transfer payments to government were about $47.2 billion
for 2001, and the rents and royalties that would be reclassified as part
of income payments on assets were about $12.6 billion. Therefore, after
removing these nontax components, taxes on production and imports would
be about $715 billion for 2001. These reclassifications will not affect
GDP, GDI, or government current receipts and current expenditures.
Personal tax and nontax payments. The nontax components of personal
tax and nontax payments will be reclassified. Specifically, Federal and
state and local nontaxes--which include donations, fees, and fines--will
be reclassified as personal transfer payments to government within
personal outlays. In the government current receipts and expenditures
account, personal transfer payments to government will be shown as a
current receipt, together with the newly recognized business transfer
payments to government. These reclassifications will be carried back to
1929.
The reclassified estimates will be more informative because the
taxes will be separated from other payments to government, such as
donations to public universities and recreational fees. In addition,
they will be more in alignment with the classifications used in SNA
1993. (41) As a result of these reclassifications, disposable personal
income would increase by the amount of the reclassified nontax payments,
about $52.5 billion for 2001, and personal outlays would increase by the
same amount. Personal income, personal saving, and government current
receipts and current expenditures will not be affected.
Government current receipts and expenditures. Interest and
dividends received by government, together with the current surplus of
government enterprises, will be shown as current receipts in the
government current receipts and expenditures account. Currently, they
are netted against expenditures. Because of these changes, government
interest receipts and payments will be presented separately rather than
on a net basis, and subsidies paid will be shown as a separate
expenditure category that will not be net of the current surplus of
government enterprises. These reclassifications will be carried back to
1946. (42)
As a result of the reclassifications, government current receipts
would increase by about $113.5 billion for 2001, and government current
expenditures would increase by the same amount. In addition, the
classification of government current receipts and the level of receipts
and expenditures will be affected by other proposals (see the sections
"Indirect business tax and nontax liabilities," "Personal
tax and nontax payments," and "Government transfer payments to
the rest of the world (net)"). The government current surplus or
deficit will not be affected.
Government transfer payments to the rest of the world (net). Taxes
received from the rest of the world, which are currently netted against
gross Federal Government transfer payments to the rest of the world,
will now be shown as a government receipt, along with other tax
receipts. (43) The remaining government transfer payments to the rest of
the world will consist of U.S. Government grants (in-cash or in-kind) to
foreign governments and of U.S. Government benefits (mainly retirement
benefits) paid to former residents of the United States. These two types
of current transfers will be separately identified and will be described
in the August article on presentational changes to the NIPA's. This
change will be carried back to 1959; estimates of taxes received from
the rest of the world are not available before 1959.
This reclassification will better align the NIPA classifications of
these tax and transfer receipts and payments with the classifications
used in SNA 1993. As a result of this change, government transfer
payments to the rest of the world would increase by the amount of the
reclassified taxes received from the rest of the world, about $6.9
billion for 2001. Government current expenditures and government current
receipts would each increase by this amount. The government current
surplus or deficit, net foreign investment, and national saving will not
be affected.
The presentation of these transactions in the foreign transactions
account, where they are shown as part of transfer payments to the rest
of the world (net), will not change. As part of this year's
comprehensive revision, BEA will show many more transactions on a gross
basis (that is, separately identifying payments and receipts rather than
netting them), but some categories, such as personal transfer payments
to the rest of the world, will continue to be available only on a net
basis.
Foreign transactions current and capital accounts
The foreign transactions account will be split into two
accounts--the foreign transactions current account and the foreign
transactions capital account. Net foreign investment will be renamed the
balance on current account, national income and product accounts. In
addition, a new aggregate, net lending or net borrowing, national income
and product accounts, will provide an indirect measure of the
Nation's net acquisition of foreign financial assets less the net
increase in foreign financial assets in the United States. (44) Net
lending or borrowing will be equal to the balance on current account
less capital transfers to the rest of the world (net). Capital transfers
were introduced in the 1999 comprehensive NIPA revision and are shown in
NIPA table 8.29. (45) (Capital transfers are cash or in-kind transfers
that are linked to the acquisition or disposition of an asset.) Capital
transfers to the rest of the world (net) will be shown on the right
(payments) side of the foreign transactions capital account and on the
left (investment) side of the gross saving and investment account as a
use of savings. This definitional change will be carried back to 1929.
(46)
Both SNA 1993 and the Balance of Payments Manual recommend that
current foreign transactions--such as exports, imports, income receipts
and payments, and current transfer receipts and payments--should be
shown in a separate account from capital transactions, such as capital
transfers. (47) Since 1999, the IT, s have shown these two types of
transactions in separate current and capital accounts. (48) The
distinction between current and capital transfers can be important when
major assets are transferred, such as the U.S. Government's
transfer of the Panama Canal to the Republic of Panama in 1999.
New aggregates
Several aggregates will be introduced that will classify
information in new and useful ways for NIPA users. These new measures
will also more closely conform the NIPA's with SNA 1993 and thereby
increase the consistency of the NIPA's with the national accounts
definitions used in other countries.
Operating surplus. Operating surplus is a profits-like measure that
shows business income after deducting the costs of compensation of
employees and taxes on production and imports, less subsidies, from
gross product (or value added), but before deducting financing costs
(such as net interest) or business transfer payments. (49) There will be
two versions of this measure: The first, gross operating surplus, does
not deduct the expense of CFC, while the second, net operating surplus,
is net of CFC. Net operating surplus will equal GDI less the sum of
compensation of employees, taxes on production and imports less
subsidies, and CFC. For private enterprises, the net operating surplus
can be calculated as the sum of the domestic components of
proprietors' income with inventory valuation adjustment (IVA) and
capital consumption adjustment (CCAdj), rental income of persons with
CCAdj, corporate profits with IVA and CCAdj, net interest, business
transfer payments, and rent paid by private enterprises to government.
Operating surplus will serve as a supplement to the other NIPA
business income measures, such as corporate profits, rather than as a
replacement. Because this measure is not dependent on whether financing
comes from debt or stockholder equity, it is useful for such purposes as
measuring the return to fixed investment. In addition, for large,
multiestablishment companies, it is often difficult to match the
financing with the industry in which production occurs. Because
operating surplus can be calculated from establishment data, it is also
a useful tool for studying income at the industry level.
BEA currently produces measures that are similar to operating
surplus under several different names. For example, "other value
added" in the I-O accounts and "property-type income" in
the GDP-by-industry accounts are similar to gross operating surplus.
(50) Likewise, a measure similar to net operating surplus has been used
to calculate the rate of return on investment by nonfinancial corporations. (51)
Although financial-accounting concepts differ in several ways from
the concepts used in the NIPA's, measures similar to gross or net
operating surplus are used in financial accounting. (52) For example,
the relationship between the new NIPA corporate gross operating surplus
and corporate profits with IVA and CCAdj is analogous to the
relationship in financial accounting between earnings before interest,
taxes, depreciation, and amortization (EBITDA) and earnings before
taxes.
Income payments (or receipts) on assets. It is sometimes useful to
group together the interest, dividends, and other types of income
payments or receipts that result from the ownership of assets. Income
payments on assets will denote income payable as interest, dividends,
reinvested earnings on foreign direct investment in the United States,
and rent paid by enterprises to government. Income receipts on assets
will denote income receivable in the form of interest, dividends,
reinvested earnings on U.S. direct investment abroad, and rent received
by government from enterprises. (53) Detailed information on these
payments and receipts will continue to be shown in the NIPA's, and
as will be described more fully in the August article on presentational
changes, more of the income estimates will be presented on a gross basis
(that is, showing payments and receipts separately). (54)
Net saving. Net saving will be added to the presentation of saving
in the NIPA's. The NIPA presentation has traditionally focused on
gross saving--that is, saving from all sources, including CFC--as the
featured measure of national saving. Because CFC represents the charge
for using up or replacing existing fixed assets, it is sometimes useful
to look at the Nation's net saving, a measure of the saving that is
available for adding to the Nation's net stock of fixed assets. Net
saving is calculated as the sum of personal saving, wage accruals less
disbursements, undistributed corporate profits with IVA and CCAdj, and
the government current surplus or deficit. This new aggregate will serve
as a supplement to the NIPA gross saving measure, rather than as a
replacement.
Gross domestic investment. Gross domestic investment, will be added
to the presentation of investment in the NIPA's. The NIPA
presentation has traditionally focused on gross investment--that is,
investment from all sources, including net foreign investment. (55)
Gross domestic investment measures the total investment in fixed assets
(that is, the structures, equipment, and software that are used in
production) and in inventories (the change in private inventories), but
net foreign investment is excluded. Gross domestic investment is
calculated as the sum of gross private domestic investment and gross
government investment, or, alternatively, as the sum of gross fixed
investment and the change in private inventories. (56) This new
aggregate will provide a comprehensive measure of investment on a
domestic basis.
Table 1. Changes in Definitions and Classifications
Initial
Principal components year of
Change affected revision
Addressing data gaps and other shortcomings
Recognize the implicit GDP, GNP, GDI, PCE, exports 1929
services provided by and imports of services,
property and casualty government consumption
insurance and provide a expenditures and gross
more appropriate treatment investment, net interest,
of insured losses. business transfer
payments, ROW income,
personal income, personal
interest income, transfer
payments to persons, DPI,
personal outlays,
government net interest,
and government current
receipts and expenditures.
Allocate a portion of the GDP, GNP, GDI, PCE, exports 1929
implicit services of of services, government
commercial banks to consumption expenditures
borrowers. and gross investment, net
interest, ROW income
payments and receipts,
personal interest income,
personal income, DPI,
interest paid by persons,
personal outlays,
government net interest,
and government current
receipts and expenditures.
Redefine change in private GDP, GNP, GDI, gross private 1991
farm inventories to domestic investment,
include farm materials and change in private
supplies. inventories, proprietors'
income, personal income,
DPI, personal saving,
statistical discrepancy,
gross saving, and gross
product of farm business
sector.
Redefine compensation-in- GDI, wage and salary 1998
kind of Federal Government disbursements, personal
employees to include mass income, DPI, personal
transit benefits. saving, statistical
discrepancy, and gross
saving.
Consistency and integration with other accounts
Reclassify Indian tribal GDP, GNP, GDI, PCE, 1990
governments to state and government consumption
local government sector. expenditures and gross
investment, current
surplus of government
enterprises, personal
outlays, personal saving,
government current
receipts and expenditures,
government current surplus
or deficit, and gross
saving.
Reclassify farm housing to Proprietors' income, rental 1929
real estate industry. income of persons, and
gross product of farm
business sector and of
households and
institutions sector.
Reclassify owner-occupied Gross product of business 1929
housing to households and sector and of households
institutions sector. and institutions sector.
Reclassify rental value of Gross product of business 1929
fixed assets used by sector and of households
nonprofit institutions and institutions sector.
serving households to
households and
institutions sector.
Reclassify military Exports of goods and 1959
grants-in-kind as exports. services, Federal
Government consumption
expenditures and gross
investment, and government
transfer payments to ROW.
Consistency with international guidelines
Recognize explicitly the GDP goods and GDP services. 1929
services produced by
general government and
treat government purchases
of goods and services as
intermediate inputs.
Broaden the definition of National income. 1929
national income to include
all net incomes earned in
production.
Reclassify miscellaneous Wage and salary accruals and 1948
compensation as wages and disbursements, and other
salaries. labor income.
Reclassify nonresident Corporate profits with 1959
taxes paid by domestic inventory valuation and
corporations to tax capital consumption
payments to ROW. adjustments, profits tax
liability, and business
transfer payments to ROW.
Reclassify business nontax Business transfer payments 1929
liability as current and indirect business tax
transfer payments to and nontax liability.
government and rent and
royalties to government.
Reclassify personal nontax Personal tax and nontax 1929
payments as current payments, DPI, personal
transfer payments to transfer payments, and
government. personal outlays.
Reclassify certain Government current receipts 1946 (1)
government current and expenditures.
receipts and expenditures.
Reclassify nonresident taxes Government tax receipts, 1959
received by government as government transfer
tax receipts. payments, and government
current receipts and
expenditures.
Split the foreign Net foreign investment. 1929 (2)
transactions account into
a current account and a
capital account.
(1.) For years prior to 1946, state and local government interest
will be presented as net interest and for years prior to 1960,
Federal and total government interest will continue to be presented
as net interest. For years prior to 1959, subsidies will continue to
be presented net of the current surplus of government enterprises.
(2.) Estimates of capital transfers to the rest of the world are
available, beginning with 1982.
DPI Disposable personal income
GDI Gross domestic income
GDP Gross domestic product
GNP Gross national product
PCE Personal consumption expenditures
ROW Rest of the world
Table 2. Summary National Income and Product Accounts
Account 1. National Income and Product Account
Compensation of employees Personal consumption expenditures
Wage and salary accruals Gross private domestic investment
Supplements to wages and Fixed investment
salaries Nonresidential
Employer contributions for Residential
social insurance Change in private inventories
Other labor income Net exports of goods and services
Proprietors' income with IVA and Exports
CCAdj Imports
Rental income of persons with Government consumption
CCAdj expenditures and gross
Corporate profits with IVA and investment
CCAdj Federal
Profits tax liability State and local
Dividends
Undistributed profits with IVA
and CCAdj
Net interest
National income
Business transfer payments
Indirect business tax and nontax
liability
Less: Subsidies less current
surplus of government
enterprises
Consumption of fixed capital
Less: Income receipts from the
rest of the world
Plus: Income payments to the rest
of the world
Gross domestic income
Statistical discrepancy
GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT
Account 2. Personal Income and Outlay Account
Personal tax and nontax payments Wage and salary disbursements
Personal outlays Other labor income
Personal consumption Proprietors' income with IVA and
expenditures CCAdj
Interest paid by persons Rental income of persons with
Personal transfer payments to CCAdj
the rest of the world (net) Personal dividend income
Personal saving Personal interest income
Transfer payments to persons
Less: Personal contributions for
social insurance
PERSONAL TAXES, OUTLAYS, PERSONAL INCOME
AND SAVING
Account 3. Government Receipts and Expenditures Account
Consumption expenditures Personal tax and nontax payments
Transfer payments Corporate profits tax liability
Net interest paid Indirect business tax and nontax
Less: Dividends received by liability
government Contributions for social
Subsidies less current surplus of insurance
government enterprises Employer
Less: Wage accruals less Personal
disbursements
Current surplus or deficit (-),
NIPA's
GOVERNMENT CURRENT EXPENDITURES GOVERNMENT CURRENT RECEIPTS
AND SURPLUS
Account 4. Foreign Transactions Account
Exports of goods and services Imports of goods and services
Income receipts Income payments
Transfer payments to the rest of
the world (net)
Net foreign investment
RECEIPTS FROM THE REST OF THE PAYMENTS TO THE REST OF THE WORLD
WORLD
Account 5. Gross Saving and Investment Account
Gross private domestic investment Personal saving
Gross government investment Wage accruals less disbursements
Net foreign investment (private)
Undistributed corporate profits
with IVA and CCAdj
Consumption of fixed capital
Government current surplus or
deficit (-), NIPA's
Statistical discrepancy
GROSS INVESTMENT GROSS SAVINGS AND STATISTICAL
DISCREPANCY
CCAdj Capital consumption adjustment
IVA Inventory valuation adjustment
NIPA's National income and product accounts
(1.) The changes in definition and classification that are
discussed in this article are the changes that affect the conceptual
content of the components of the NIPA summary accounts.
(2.) Stephanie H. McCulla and Carol E. Moylan, "Preview of
Revised NIPA Estimates for 1997: Effects of Incorporating the 1997
Benchmark I-O Accounts and Proposed Definitional and Statistical
Changes" SURVEY 83 (January 2003): 10-16.
(3.) One of the presentational changes that will be made in the
upcoming comprehensive revision, a new NIPA presentation that shows
incomes and outlays of households separately from those of nonprofit
institutions, was described in Charles Ian Mead, Clinton P. McCully, and
Marshall B. Reinsdorf, "Income and Outlays of Households and of
Nonprofit Institutions Serving Households," SURVEY 83 (April 2003):
13-17.
(4.) The BEA strategic plan is available on our Web site at
<www.bea.gov>; click on "About BEA" and find the bullet
for "Strategic Plan for 2003-2007" near the bottom of the
page.
(5.) See Commission of the European Communities, International
Monetary Fund, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development,
United Nations, and the World Bank, System of National Accounts 1993
(Brussels/Luxembourg, New York, Paris, and Washington, DC, 1993);
henceforth, SNA 1993.
(6.) See "New International Guidelines in Economic
Accounting," SURVEY 73 (February 1993): 43.
(7.) Under the current treatment, the terrorist attacks of
September 11, 2001, resulted in a decrease in domestic final
expenditures for insurance services of about $21 billion (current
dollars, annual rate) in the third quarter of 2001. Within imports of
services, claims by domestic insurers for reinsurance policies with
foreign insurers resulted in a decrease in imports of "other
private services" of about $44 billion. These effects lowered gross
domestic purchases by about $21 billion and raised GDP by about $23
billion. BEA treated these effects as changes in the corresponding
implicit prices for insurance services, so real GDP was not affected.
However, the gross domestic purchases price index and the PCE price
index were each reduced by about 1 percentage point and the GDP price
index was raised by about 1 percentage point.
(8.) For earlier discussions of the measurement of insurance
services, see Obie G. Whichard and Maria Borga, "Selected Issues in
the Measurement of U.S. International Services," SURVEY 82 (June
2002): 36-56; and Dennis J. Fixler, "Rethinking the NIPA Treatment
of Insurance Services for the Comprehensive Revision," paper
presented at the meeting of the BEA Advisory Committee, November 15,
2002 (revised December 23, 2002), available at <www.bea.gov>.
(9.) SNA 1993 recommends that this portion of investment income be
included in the measure of insurance output and treated as a premium
supplement (paragraphs 6.135-6.140).
(10.) See Phillip D. Cagan, "The Monetary Dynamics of
Hyper-Inflation," in Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, ed.
Milton J. Friedman (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1956).
(11.) A paper providing additional details on the estimation methods will be available on BEA's Web site later this summer.
(12.) Because the denominator of these ratios is premiums earned
rather than reserves, these investment gain/loss ratios cannot be
interpreted as rates of return.
(13.) These flows between the policyholder and the insurance
company do not strictly meet the definition of a
"transfer"--that is, a payment for which nothing is provided
in return--because the payment is made as part of the contract between
the policyholder and the insurance company. However, because these flows
are similar to transfers in that they reflect the part of the payments
that are not associated with the purchase of insurance services, they
will be included in business transfer payments in the NIPA's.
(14.) The methodology for estimating the services for which banks
have explicit charges will not change.
(15.) See SNA 1993, paragraph 6.127.
(16.) The imputation that is made for other depository institutions
will not change, but BEA will review the treatment for possible change
in the next comprehensive revision.
(17.) Several articles on the user-cost-of-money theory as it
applies to banking provide a conceptual framework to justify the
reference-rate approach: See Diana Hancock, "The Financial Firm:
Production with Monetary and Nonmonetary Goods," Journal of
Political Economy 93 (October 1985): 859-880; Dennis J. Fixler,
"Measuring Financial Service Output and Prices of Commercial
Banking," Applied Economics 25 (April 1993): 983-993; and Dennis J.
Fixler and Kimberly D. Zieschang, "The Productivity of the Banking
Sector: Integrating Financial and Production Approaches to Measuring
Financial Service Output," Canadian Journal of Economics 32 (April
1999): 547-569.
(18.) See SNA 1993, paragraph 6.128.
(19.) A paper providing additional details of the empirical
analysis will be available on BEA's Web site later this summer.
(20.) See the section "Owner-occupied housing services."
(21.) See U.S. Department of Commerce, Office of Business
Economics, National Income: A Supplement to the Survey of Current
Business, 1954 ed. (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office,
1954): 46-47.
(22.) Imputed output for securities held by banks is generally
small because spreads between their interest rate and the reference rate
tend to be small. (Spreads for securities issued by state and local
governments are based on tax-equivalent yields to make their interest
comparable to interest earned by loans and other types of securities.)
Federal Government securities are not a source of imputed gross output
because, by construction, the spread between their interest rate and the
reference rate is zero.
(23.) The underlying assumption is that foreign-owned offices in
the United States face the same interest rates as U.S.-owned banks. More
specific information is not available, because the foreign-owned offices
do not file Call Report information.
(24.) See SNA 1993, paragraph 7.108.
(25.) For information about a change in the definition of net
interest, see the section "Rental value of fixed assets used by
nonprofit institutions serving households."
(26.) Only about $43 billion of the change in estimated output
should be attributed to the adoption of the reference-rate approach,
because the revision for foreign-owned bank offices should be attributed
mostly to improved source data.
(27.) General government output is measured by the cost of inputs:
Compensation, consumption of fixed capital, and intermediate goods and
services. Government consumption expenditures is equal to general
government output less sales and own-account investment; see the section
"Services of general government."
(28.) The output of government enterprises is valued at market
prices rather than being based on cost of production. If the output is
purchased by persons, by general government, or by the rest of the
world, it is included in PCE, in government consumption expenditures and
gross investment, or in exports, respectively.
(29.) Indian tribes own other enterprises--such as automobile
dealerships, tobacco stores, gasoline stations, and sawmills--but data
are currently insufficient for estimating the associated current
surplus.
(30.) At the same time, the production of services from both farm
and nonfarm owner-occupied housing will be reclassified from the
business sector to the households and institutions sector; see the next
section.
(31.) The other difference will be eliminated by the
reclassification of the rental value of fixed assets used by nonprofit
institutions serving households, which is described in the next section.
(32.) SNA 1993 recommends that home ownership be treated as
ownership of an unincorporated enterprise that produces housing services
consumed by the household (paragraph 6.89).
(33.) The rental value of these assets consists of the expenses
associated with their use, including mortgage interest, consumption of
fixed capital, and property taxes.
(34.) International Monetary Fund (IMF), Balance of Payments
Manual, 5th ed. (Washington, DC: IMF, 1993).
(35.) In contrast, the value of business GDP equals the sum of
business income from production in the form of compensation of
employees, indirect business tax and nontax liability, and property-type
income (that is, corporate profits, proprietors' income, inventory
valuation adjustments, rental income of persons, net interest, private
capital consumption allowances, business transfer payments, and the
current surplus of government enterprises less subsidies).
(36.) See SNA 1993, paragraph 6.230.
(37.) If analysts should need estimates of national income on the
basis of its previous definition, they can be constructed by summing
compensation of employees, proprietors' income with inventory
valuation adjustment (IVA) and capital consumption adjustment (CCAdj),
rental income of persons with CCAdj, corporate profits with IVA and
CCAdj, and net interest.
(38.) See SNA 1993, paragraph 7.43.
(39.) These nonresident taxes are mostly income taxes, though they
do include some taxes on production. However, the data are not
sufficiently reliable to separate the taxes on income from the taxes on
production.
(40.) See SNA 1993, paragraphs 7.49, 7.128, 7.132, and 8.84.
(41.) See SNA 1993, paragraphs 8.52-8.54 and 8.84.
(42.) For years prior to 1946, state and local government interest
will continue to be presented as net interest, and for years prior to
1960, Federal and total government interest will continue to be
presented as net interest. For years prior to 1959, subsidies will
continue to be presented net of the current surplus of government
enterprises. Detailed data to separate the series for these periods are
not readily available.
(43.) Taxes received from the rest of the world are mostly income
taxes, though they do include some taxes on production and current
transfers received by government. The data are not sufficiently reliable
to separate the taxes on income from the taxes on production.
(44.) Direct measures of these financial flows are available in the
ITA's. The new NIPA net lending measure will differ from the
measures shown in the ITA's because of differences in source data
and differences in concepts and coverage.
(45.) See Brent R. Moulton, Robert P. Parker, and Eugene P. Seskin,
"A Preview of the 1999 Comprehensive Revision of the National
Income and Product Accounts: Definitional and Classificational
Changes," SURVEY 79 (August 1999): 7-20.
(46.) Estimates of capital transfers to the rest of the world are
available, beginning with 1982.
(47.) See SNA 1993, paragraphs 2.106 and 2.137 and Balance of
Payments Manual, paragraphs 152 and 175.
(48.) See Christopher L. Bach, "U.S. International
Transactions, Revised Estimates for 1982-98," SURVEY 79 (July 1999): 60-119.
(49.) SNA 1993 recommends that two concepts be used:
"Operating surplus" for corporations or corporate-like
entities and for owner-occupied housing, and "mixed income"
for other unincorporated enterprises (paragraph 7.8). The term
"mixed income" is used in the SNA for the residual income of
most unincorporated enterprises because proprietors often contribute
unpaid labor, as well as capital, to these enterprises. Because BEA is
continuing to review the SNA's recommendations for the sectoring of
unincorporated enterprises and of corporate-like entities, the term
"operating surplus" will be used in the NIPA's for the
residual income of all enterprises. Note that the net operating surplus
of general government is, by definition, equal to zero because the
NIPA's use CFC as a partial measure of the services of general
government capital.
(50.) However, these measures differ from gross operating surplus
because they exclude subsidies received by enterprises, whereas gross
operating surplus will include subsidies. In addition, the I-O accounts
and the GDP-by-industry accounts use some data sources and methods that
differ from those used in the NIPA's.
(51.) See Daniel Larkins, "Note on the Profitability of
Domestic Nonfinancial Corporations, 1960-2001," SURVEY 82
(September 2002): 17-20.
(52.) See Kenneth A. Petrick, "Comparing NIPA Profits with
S&P 500 Profits," SURVEY 81 (April 2001): 16-20 and Corporate
Profits: Profits Before Tax, Profits Tax Liability, and Dividends,
Methodology Paper (Washington, DC: U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis,
September 2002), available at <www.bea.gov/bea/mp.htm>.
(53.) SNA 1993 (paragraph 7.89) classifies these types of income as
"property income," but for clarity and for consistency with
the ITA's, the terms "income payments (or receipts) on
assets" will be used in the NIPA's.
(54.) For years prior to 1948, estimates of business income
received and paid on assets are not available separately and will
continue to be presented on a net basis. For years prior to 1960,
estimates of government income received and paid on assets are not
available separately and will continue to be presented on a net basis.
(55.) Net foreign investment is U.S. exports of goods and services
and income receipts from the rest of the world less U.S. imports of
goods and services, income payments to the rest of the world, and
transfer payments to the rest of the world (net). As mentioned earlier,
net foreign investment will be renamed "balance on current account,
NIPA's" (see the section "Foreign transactions current
and capital accounts").
(56.) At present, the NIPA's do not include an inventory
account for government, because of a lack of source data. The change in
inventories for a few government categories for which data are
available, specifically the Commodity Credit Corporation and the
Strategic Petroleum Reserves, are treated as government consumption
expenditures.
Shelly Smith assisted in preparing the tables and figures for this
article.