Measuring the services of commercial banks in the NIPAs: changes in concepts and methods.
Fixler, Dennis J. ; Reinsdorf, Marshall B. ; Smith, George M. 等
As part of the comprehensive revision of the national income and
product accounts (NIPAs) scheduled for release on December 10, 2003, a
definitional change will be introduced that recognizes the implicit
services of commercial banks to borrowers. This change is briefly
described in the June 2003 issue of the SURVEY OF CURRENT BUSINESS, and
some associated table changes are described in the August 2003 issue.
(1) This article provides a more detailed explanation of the new measure
of banking output and its effect on the NIPAs.
The revised measures of banks' implicit financial services will improve the consistency of the NIPAs with the recommendations for
the treatment of banks in the 1993 System of National Accounts (SNA),
the principal international guidelines for national accounts. (2) The
Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) continues to be a leader in
incorporating major innovations of the SNA, such as chain-type indexes
and the recognition of software as investment. For banking, the SNA
recommends measuring implicit financial services to depositors using the
difference between a risk-free "reference rate" and the
average interest rate paid to depositors, and it recommends measuring
implicit services to borrowers using the difference between the average
interest rate paid by borrowers and the reference rate. To implement
this approach, BEA will measure the reference rate by the average rate
earned by banks on U.S. Treasury and U.S. agency securities. Measured in
this way, the reference rate is consistently above the average rate of
interest paid to depositors and consistently below the average rate of
interest paid by borrowers.
Background
How to value bank output has been a topic of much discussion in the
national accounts literature because banks do not explicitly charge for
all the financial services that they provide, relying instead on net
receipts of interest for much of their revenue. In national income
accounting, interest payments are generally treated as a distribution of
income by businesses to investors who have provided them with funds, not
as a payment for services. In particular, the domestic portion of the
"net interest" component of national income is defined as
interest paid by private business less interest received by private
business. Applied to banks, the usual treatment of interest flows would
yield a negative contribution to national income. Moreover, much of the
value of the services that banks provide to their customers would be
missed by the NIPAs. To avoid these results, an imputation for implicit
financial services produced by banks is included in the NIPAs.
Depositors purchase these implicit services with imputed interest income
that eliminates the gap between the total interest received by banks and
the total interest paid by banks. (3)
The view that all the implicit services of banks go to depositors
is based on the notion that depositors are the ultimate lenders and that
the net interest belongs to them. This view, however, does not
adequately account for the implicit services of commercial banks to
borrowers in their role as financial intermediaries. In that role, banks
transform deposits into earning assets by providing many financial
services. In particular, banks provide services related to the provision
of credit that overcome problems of asymmetric information and that
transfer risk to the bank. Banks devote staff time and other resources
both to activities that serve depositors, such as clearing checks, and
to activities that serve borrowers, such as making loan-underwriting
decisions. Historically, banks were virtually the only source of credit
to many households and businesses, and burgeoning needs for credit
services were a major impetus for growth of this industry. Accordingly,
a measure of bank output should reflect borrower services along with
depositor services.
Interest margins as values of implicit services of banks
By treating banks' net interest income as imputed sales of
services, the NIPAs recognize that adjustments to interest rates are
substitutes for explicit fees to cover the cost of providing services to
bank customers. If the reference rate represents the rate that banks
earn on their investments after deducting expenses of providing services
to borrowers, banks could, in principle, charge depositors explicitly
for services and pay them the reference rate of interest. Similarly,
banks could charge borrowers explicitly for services that they receive
and reduce the rate of interest on loans to the reference rate. Indeed,
over the last two decades banks have substituted fee income for net
interest income: In 1980, net receipts of interest constituted 80
percent of commercial banks' gross income (which does not reflect
taxes, noninterest expenses, loan-loss provisions, and gains or losses
on sales of securities), but in 2000, they constituted 58 percent of
banks' gross income. (4) Therefore, the exclusion of implicitly
priced services would result in a substantial overstatement of
banks' output growth.
Rather than offsetting lower net interest margins by higher revenue
from fees for services, banks with low net interest margins may simply
provide fewer services. In these cases, interest rate differentials
represent an implicit price for financial services. For example, in
2002, an Internet bank with limited services paid an average rate of 4
percent on deposits while small conventional banks paid an average rate
of 3 percent. (5) Depositors who chose the lower average deposit rate in
order to obtain more services from a conventional bank thus paid an
implicit price of 1 percent per year for those services.
Taking this logic one step further, depositors could dispense with the services of a bank entirely and keep their money in securities
paying the reference rate of interest. Depositors who forego the
opportunity to earn the reference rate in order to obtain the services
of a bank choose to pay an implicit price for depositor services equal
to the margin between the reference rate and the deposit rate.
The reference rate also represents an opportunity cost in the
banks' investment decisions. If a highly liquid security with no
credit risk is available to banks, the banks forego the opportunity to
earn this security's rate of return--assumed to be the reference
rate--when they invest in loans instead. The spread between this
reference rate of return and the lending rate is the implicit price that
the bank receives for providing financial services to borrowers, which
include the cost of bearing risk. The spread must equal the marginal
cost of providing borrower services if the bank is indifferent at the
margin between investing in the reference-rate asset and investing in
higher yielding loans. In a marketplace where competition keeps loans
from being priced at levels that yield economic profits (profits in
excess of a normal return on capital), we can expect an equilibrium where banks are indifferent between investment opportunities at the
margin.
Borrowers from banks are willing to pay a margin over the reference
rate because they require or want lender services that issuers of
credit-market instruments bearing the reference rate of interest do not
receive. For many, borrowing in capital markets is very costly or
impossible because of the problems of asymmetric information noted
earlier, and liquidating financial assets as an alternative to borrowing
is also impossible. However, for marginal loan customers, liquidating
assets that earn the reference rate or borrowing at approximately the
reference rate in capital markets are alternative ways to obtain needed
funds. In particular, both household and business borrowers often choose
to hold financial assets when they could liquidate those assets and
reduce their loan balances. For the marginal users of the borrowed
funds, the difference between the loan rate and the reference rate
represents the net marginal cost borne by borrowers for liquidity
management, inducing the bank to accept their risk, and for any other
services provided by the lender. This difference can therefore be viewed
as an implicit price paid for credit services.
Finally, if the bank's net return on investments funded by
deposits equals the reference rate, then the implicit price that the
bank receives for providing services to depositors equals the spread
between the reference rate and the rate paid on deposits. This spread
equals the marginal cost of providing services to depositors if the bank
is indifferent to marginal changes in amounts on deposit. In the short
run, regulatory constraints on a bank's growth based on the amount
of its equity capital could prevent it from accepting deposits until it
reaches the point of indifference; however, in a longrun competitive
equilibrium for the industry, deposit rates will just permit banks to
cover their costs. In addition, large banks that are perceived as very
safe are able to borrow at approximately the reference rate in
securities markets, thereby avoiding the costs of providing services to
depositors. If these banks are indifferent at the margin between raising
funds from depositors and raising funds in securities markets, the
spread between the reference rate and the rate paid on deposits must
approximately equal the marginal cost of providing services to
depositors.
Theoretical framework
According to the "user cost of money" framework set out
in Donovan (1978), Diewert (1974), and Barnett (1978) and applied to
banking by Hancock (1985), Fixler (1993), and Fixler and Zieschang
(1999), the reference rate plays an important role in models of economic
decisionmaking by banks. The user cost of financial assets is an
extension of a concept originally developed for nonfinancial assets. In
a competitive marketplace where renting out a fixed capital asset yields
economic profits of zero, the rental payment or user cost, u[c.sub.t],
must equal the difference between the starting value of the asset,
[p.sub.t], and the present value of the asset at reference rate of
interest, [r.sub.r], at the end of the rental period, or [p.sub.t+1]/(1
+ [r.sub.r]). If the growth rate of the asset's value from period t
to period t + 1 reflects depreciation, [[delta].sub.t], and an expected
rate of increase in asset prices of [[pi].sub.t], then substituting into
the equation u[c.sub.t] = ([p.sub.t] - [p.sub.t+1])/(1 + [r.sub.r])
yields:
(1) u[c.sub.t] = [p.sub.t][1 -(1 + [[pi].sub.t] -
[[delta].sub.t])/(1 + [r.sub.r])] = [p.sub.t]([r.sub.r] - [[pi].sub.t] +
[[delta].sub.t])/(1 + [r.sub.r]).
Alternatively, if u[c.sub.t] is to be paid at the end of the
period, then u[c.sub.t] = [p.sub.t]([r.sub.r] - [[pi].sub.t] +
[[delta].sub.t]). A parallel expression for a user cost formula for a
financial asset with a rate of return of [r.sub.A] would equal the
difference between its immediate cash value in period t, assumed to be
[y.sub.At], and the present value of selling the asset for an expected
price of [y.sub.At+1] = (1 + [[pi].sub.t])[y.sub.At] in period t + 1
after receiving income of [r.sub.Ay.sub.At]. Here, [[pi].sub.t],
represents both changes in asset prices and, if the asset is a debt
instrument, expected changes in value due to creditworthiness developments. On the assumption that the opportunity is available to
earn a rate of [r.sub.r] on an asset that requires no costly services to
the borrower, including the bearing of credit risk, [r.sub.r] measures
the banks' opportunity cost of financial capital. (6) Hence
[r.sub.r] can be used as the discount rate to calculate the present
value of the future cash flows. The user cost of holding an asset with a
rate of return of [r.sub.A] then becomes: (7)
(2) [y.sub.At][1 - 1 + [r.sub.A] + [[PI].sub.t]/1 + [r.sub.r] =
[y.sub.At][r.sub.r] - [r.sub.A] - [[pi].sub.t]/1 + [r.sub.r].
A modified version of the user cost expression on the right-hand
side of equation (2) can be used to measure the implicit services
associated with financial assets of banks, such as loans. This version
of the user cost formula omits [[pi].sub.t], which represents expected
net holding gains. Changes in the market value of a debt instrument
usually have no effect on the value of the liability recognized by the
debtor, and the NIPAs must treat the creditor and the debtor
symmetrically. More importantly, holding gains and losses are excluded
from the concept of income measured by the national accounts, which is
limited to the income that originates from current production of goods
and services. Since credit losses can be treated as a kind of holding
loss, the effect of omitting [[pi].sub.t], is significant. (8)
The user cost formula in equation (2) assumes that interest is paid
at the end of the period and that the asset and its user cost are valued
at the beginning of the period. In practice, interest flows occur
throughout the year, and measures of economic activity usually do not
use beginning-of-year present values for sales that occur at different
times over the course of the year. An alternative formula that values
the user cost as of the end of the period is consistent with these
practices. The end-of-period expression for the user cost of financial
assets is [r.sub.r] - [r.sub.A] (or, if the holding gains term is
included, [r.sub.r] - [r.sub.A] - [[pi].sub.t]). In implementing the
revised treatment of banks, average interest rates will be calculated as
ratios of interest accrued throughout the year to the average value of
assets over the course of the year. In effect, these procedures adopt a
mid-year perspective to value both interest payments and assets, using a
simple sum of interest accruals to approximate a sum of interest
accruals that are discounted to the middle of the year. The product of
the interest rates and the asset values equals the total interest
accrued over the course of the year.
Typically, banks' financial assets have negative user costs
and their liabilities have positive user costs because the rate of the
return on assets usually exceeds the reference rate, which in turn
exceeds the rate paid on liabilities. To make the signs more intuitive
for our purposes, the user-cost price of an asset is defined as the
negative of the user cost, and the user-cost price of a liability is
defined as its user cost. As a result, whenever a financial product
contributes positively to economic profits, its price is positive.
Because holding gains or losses are not part of the national accounts
concept of current production, the term in the user cost expression for
expected holding gains or losses is omitted from the user-cost price.
The arbitrary asset i then has a user-cost price of:
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
For liability products, the user-cost price is
(4) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
These user-cost price formulas do not include a term for service
charges and other fees to borrowers or to depositors. For modeling
economic decisionmaking by banks, fees to borrowers and to depositors
should be included in user-cost prices, but for measuring banks'
implicit sales of services, they should be treated as explicit sales.
Effect on the measure of imputed output
User cost of "own funds" The gross output of banks
consists of explicit sales of services, which are booked as fee income,
and implicit sales of services, which are currently measured by
banks' net interest income, or [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. Although the most important effect of the
revised treatment of the implicitly priced services is the division of
their value between borrowers and depositors, the revised treatment also
reduces the total measure of implicit services. This reduction occurs
because the difference between the total value of loans and other
interest-earning assets and the total value of deposits and other
interest-bearing liabilities is generally positive. The SNA terms this
difference "own funds" because banks use their own funds to
acquire the assets whose acquisition is not funded by the issuance of
liabilities. Own funds represent stockholders' equity that is held
in financial assets, or money furnished directly or indirectly (via
retained earnings) by the banks' stockholders. (9)
To show how the lending of banks' own funds affects the
revised measure of implicit financial services, express the total
imputed output of banks, V, as the user-cost price of assets times the
volume of assets plus the user-cost price of liabilities times the
volume of liabilities, or:
(5) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
In the last line of equation (5), the first term represents the
value of implicitly priced services that the bank provides to borrowers,
and the second term in equation (5) shows the value of the implicitly
priced services that it provides to depositors and other lenders to the
bank. A rearrangement of the terms in equation (5) reveals that V equals
the current NIPA measure of imputed output minus the user cost of the
own funds used to acquire assets:
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The difference between the current measure of banks' imputed
output and the revised measure equals the user cost of the assets
acquired with banks' own funds. When a bank lends its own funds
instead of funds from depositors, it does not need to use a portion of
interest that it receives to cover the cost of providing services to
depositors. Hence, less of the interest received from the borrower
represents implicit fees for services and more of it represents net
interest income earned by the bank. The measure of imputed output is
reduced by an amount that is broadly consistent with an SNA
recommendation that the return to lending of own funds he excluded from
imputed output. (10)
Defining assets and liabilities. The measure of own funds in
equation (6) is sensitive to which types of assets and liabilities are
included. Arguments are sometimes made that only loans and deposits
should be counted because banks have no control over other interest
rates. However, BEA's measures of imputed bank output reflect all
bank assets and liabilities that earn interest or imputed interest.
(Imputed interest is earned by deposits.) As a result, substitution by
banks between different types of assets, or between different types of
liabilities, does not directly affect the measure of imputed output. For
example, loans rose from about one-third of financial assets in 1951 to
about two-thirds of financial assets in 2001, while deposits fell from
almost 100 percent of liabilities to about 70 percent of liabilities.
Inclusion of all interest-bearing assets and liabilities also
results in a better estimate of own funds used for lending. In
particular, banks generally have more deposits than loans, so if only
these items were counted, the estimate of own funds would generally be
negative. Negative own funds result in estimates of imputed output that
exceed the net interest received by banks. Since the justification for
imputed output rests on net interest being a substitute for fee income,
imputed output that is not "paid for" by net interest is hard
to justify.
A narrow definition of assets that excludes amounts loaned to other
banks or deposited at other banks can also lead to inconsistencies. The
estimate of the gross output delivered to the customers of the banking
industry should equal the value that could be calculated from a
consolidated balance sheet for the industry, which would net out assets
and liabilities that represent claims of one bank on another bank. For
example, federal funds and repurchase agreements (which are combined in
the data sources used for the estimates) are reported both as assets and
as liabilities by banks. Like deposits, their interest rates are usually
lower than the reference rate. The estimate of the implicit services
associated with federal funds and repurchase agreements equals the user
cost of the net liability position of the banking industry, but it is
calculated by including a negative number for implicit services of
federal funds and repurchase agreement gross assets (which consist
primarily of interbank transactions) that partly offsets the positive
number for implicit services of federal funds and repurchase agreement
gross liabilities.
Table 1 shows the assets and liabilities included in an
illustrative calculation of banks' imputed output for 2001. In
column 1 of the table are average values for the year of major balance
sheet items, including those that have no role in the calculations of
domestic imputed output. One asset, "cash items in process of
collection" is displayed as a negative liability below deposits in
order to show that it is netted out from deposits when calculating
implicit depositor services. Items in process of collection are deducted from deposits because, in an accrual-accounting framework, these funds
belong to the payee, not the check writer.
Column 2 in table 1 displays either the interest income or the
interest expense for the year, depending on whether the item is an asset
or a liability. Column 3 shows the book-value interest rate implied by
dividing the interest income or expense by the average balance sheet
value. Column 4 shows the user-cost prices, calculated as the margin
between the item's interest rate and the reference rate shown on
line 8. Column 5 shows expansion factors needed to account for domestic
output of foreign banks, which are calculated using ratios of balance
sheet items for the total domestic banking industry to corresponding
items for domestic offices of banks chartered in the United States.
Column 6 shows the contribution to imputed output from each included
item, calculated as the product of the average balance sheet value, the
user-cost price, and the expansion factor for foreign-owned offices.
The negative values for imputed output for assets associated with
interbank transactions on lines 12 to 15 of table 1 prevent the implicit
services that banks provide to each other from being included in the
output delivered to other kinds of customers. These negative entries are
offset elsewhere in table 1 by amounts included in imputed output on
liabilities or in implicit services from Federal Reserve Banks. For
example, the net output associated with Federal funds and repurchase
agreements is the difference between the positive entry in the liability
section of the table and the smaller negative entry for the asset.
The implicit borrower services on loans and leases in lines 4-5 of
table 1 represent 41.9 percent of total imputed output. Implicit
services to depositors, calculated as the sum of the entries on lines
24-30 and the adjustments on lines 13 and 14, represent 54.3 percent of
imputed output or $101.3 billion. Further, the user cost of own funds
and foreign office deposits used for domestic lending on line 47 is
$45.7 billion. This $45.7 billion can be decomposed into $19.9 billion
from the user cost of own funds of U.S. banks, $23.7 for the user cost
of foreign office deposits used for domestic lending, and $2.1 billion
for the user cost of funds from foreign sources that foreign banks lend
domestically. Finally, a comparison of estimates of imputed output with
and without the adjustment for domestic offices of foreign banks also
shows that imputed output of $11.2 billion out of a total of $186.6
billion originates in the foreign-owned banking offices.
The assets of commercial banks also include balances due from
Federal Reserve Banks, which include required reserves. In exchange for
the user cost of these balances due (which equals the amount they would
have earned if they had been invested at the reference rate of interest)
banks are assumed to receive implicit services from the Federal Reserve
Banks of equivalent value. To be consistent, implicit services from the
Federal Reserve Banks are also imputed to the Federal Government on
Treasury deposits, to the rest of the world on international deposits,
and to business in connection with other deposits. Therefore, the total
output of the Federal Reserve Banks equals the user cost of their
deposit liabilities; no output is imputed in connection with their
assets because they consist primarily of securities that earn the
reference rate of interest. In the revised measures, the implicit
services of Federal Reserve Banks that are consumed by commercial banks
are treated as an intermediate input. Currently in the NIPAs, the output
of the Federal Reserve Banks is estimated by their expenses, and a
portion of this output is included in implicit services to customers of
the banking industry.
Foreign output of U.S. banks and domestic output of foreign banks.
The primary data source for the estimates, the Federal Financial
Institutions Examination Council's Call Reports, cover domestic and
foreign offices of banks chartered in the United States. (11) Two
adjustments to the basic estimates from the Call Reports are therefore
necessary to estimate the domestic output of all banks. First, an
estimate of the output produced in the foreign offices of U.S. banks
must be deducted from U.S. banks' total output. Second, the output
of U.S. offices of foreign banks must be added.
The output of foreign offices of U.S. banks is currently measured
as the excess of their interest receipts from borrowers over their
interest payments to depositors. In recent years, the interest rate on
loans in foreign offices has been roughly twice the rate on deposits,
and the amount of deposits has been roughly twice the amount of loans.
Consequently, interest received has approximately equaled interest paid
in the foreign offices, so virtually no imputed output has been
attributed to them.
In the revised measures of bank output, a significant amount of
output will be attributed to foreign offices of U.S. banks. The revised
measure of foreign office output equals the user cost of foreign office
loans plus the user cost of foreign office deposits. Therefore, the
increase in foreign office output equals the reference rate times the
excess of foreign office deposits over foreign office loans. The excess
deposits represent a source of funds for domestic lending that, like own
funds, involve no domestically produced implicit services to depositors.
The output of U.S. offices of foreign banks is also affected by the
change in the definition of imputed output. The domestic output of
foreign banks is currently measured by scaling up the estimates of the
output of U.S. banks using ratios of balance sheet items for all banking
offices located in the U.S. to corresponding items for the offices of
U.S. banks alone. The implicit assumption--which is made necessary by
unavailability of data--is that the U.S. offices of foreign banks pay
and receive the same interest rates as other banks in the United States.
Rather than scaling up gross interest flows, the new procedure will
scale up user costs of assets and liabilities. This will change the
estimates of the domestic output of the foreign banks because the assets
that are attributed to foreign banks do not exactly equal the
liabilities. However, a more important source of revision to these
estimates will be revisions to the estimates of the balance sheet ratios
to incorporate new source data.
Measurement of interest rates
Estimation of user cost measures of imputed output requires a
number of decisions about the specification of key concepts. One of
these decisions concerns interest rates. From a theoretical standpoint,
the use of either market interest rates or book-value interest rates can
be defended. The book-value rates are computed by dividing the interest
receipt or payment for a financial product by the book-value of that
financial product on the balance sheet.
Market interest rates should be used in conjunction with the market
values of assets (whose use is sometimes called the "creditor
approach"), and book interest rates should be used in conjunction
with the book-value of assets (the "debtor approach"). For
most interest-bearing assets, banks report book values rather than
market values. Perhaps for this reason, tests using market rates
resulted in excessively volatile estimates of implicit services to
depositors and to borrowers, including some negative values. In
contrast, with book value rates, the user-cost prices of both loans and
deposits are consistently positive and behave plausibly. The variation
over time in relative positions of the book-value reference rate, loan
rate, and deposit rate is shown in chart 1.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
To compute the book-value reference rate, the interest received
from Treasury and Federal agency securities is divided by the average
book value of these securities over the period during which the interest
was received. This method of calculating the reference rate results in
estimates of zero for implicit borrower services consumed by the Federal
Government. Although imputing no borrower services to Federal Government
debt may seem inconsistent with imputing services to other types of bond
issuers, Federal debt imposes virtually no liquidity or credit-risk
costs on the bank. Letting implicit services for Federal debt equal zero
makes GDP invariant to the proportion of Federal debt held by the
banking sector.
Book-value interest rates for other assets and liabilities are
calculated similarly to the reference rate. However, interest income
from securities issued by state and local governments must be adjusted
to reflect its tax-exempt status. The interest expense on liabilities
used to fund purchases of these securities may be completely deductible,
80-percent deductible, or nondeductible, depending on the nature of the
issuer and the data of purchase of the security. If the interest expense
is completely deductible, then:
taxable rate = book-value rate/1 - bank's marginal income tax
rate
Beginning with 1985, adjustments for taxable equivalency are from
the Federal Reserve Board. For earlier years, adjustments are calculated
using the above formula, with banks' average tax rate serving as a
proxy for their marginal rate and an assumption that the user-cost price
of state and local securities is nonnegative.
Effect on GDP and on gross domestic income
As discussed above, the revised measure of banks' imputed
output will be lower than the current measure. The amount of the
reduction caused by the change in the definition of the imputed output
equals the sum of (1) the user cost of own funds; (2) the user cost of
foreign office deposits available for domestic lending; and (3) part of
the change in the estimate of imputed output of domestic offices of
foreign banks.
GDP will fall more than the imputed output of banks will fall,
because intermediate consumption will absorb some output that is
currently counted in final demand. Implicit services count as
intermediate consumption when consumed by businesses, household
owner-occupiers, or nonprofit institutions serving households, and these
sectors are the primary borrowers from banks. Consequently, when imputed
output that is currently allocated to depositors is instead allocated to
borrowers, some imputed output will shift from final demand to
intermediate consumption.
While the recognition of borrowers' implicit services reduces
the importance of banks' imputed output to GDP, it also opens up a
new channel of influence on the rate of change of current-dollar GDP. In
chart 1, the reference rate is sometimes closer to the asset rate,
implying that borrowers received a smaller share of implicit financial
services, but at other times, it is closer to the liability rate.
Although trends in the split of implicit services between borrowers and
depositors are meaningful, shortrun fluctuations of this split may not
reflect equilibrium behavior. Because the reference rate demonstrates
more inertia than the other rates, abrupt declines in interest rates
tend to result in a temporary reclassification of imputed output from
intermediate consumption (by borrowers) to final demand (by depositors),
first raising and then lowering the growth rate of GDP. Abrupt increases
in interest rates have the opposite effect. The Treasury and Federal
agency securities that furnish the reference rate tend to have rates
that are fixed for longer periods than the rates paid on liabilities and
the rates earned on loans. Nevertheless, this troublesome effect is
expected to be small, and it will have almost no effect on real growth
rates.
The revision in the measure of imputed output will change gross
domestic income (GDI) by the same amount as it changes GDR Imputed
expenditures on financial services by households, by government, and by
the rest of the world, which raise GDP, are matched by imputed interest
flows, which raise GDI. Imputed expenditures by business have no effect
on GDP because they are intermediate inputs, and imputed net interest
payments by businesses to banks do not affect GDI because banks are also
in the business sector.
Even though the balance between GDI and GDP will be unaffected by
the revision, some elements of the calculation of the interest component
of GDI will change. To be consistent with the guidelines of the SNA, the
implicit services provided by banks to borrowers will be shown as a
negative amount of imputed interest paid by borrowers. (12) The sum of
monetary interest and imputed interest paid by borrowers, which is the
total amount of interest paid by borrowers, will therefore decline. In
effect, a portion of the interest paid by borrowers will be reclassified
as a payment for implicit services; borrowers' imputed expenditures
on services will rise by the same amount that their payments of interest
fall. Note that negative imputed interest paid by nonbusiness borrowers
to banks increases the "net interest" component of GDI in the
same way as positive imputed interest paid by banks to nonbusiness
customers.
Effects on quantity and price indexes
To estimate changes in the real value of imputed output, BEA will
continue to use the method that it adopted in 1999. Thus, the rates of
change of real total output and of real explicitly priced output will
not be revised because of the change in the treatment of banking.
However, the level of real total output and real imputed output will be
revised for all years to reflect the revised level of current-dollar
imputed output in the base year. In addition, the revisions to the
weight of explicitly priced output will cause revisions to the rate of
change of real imputed output because real imputed output is estimated
as a residual.
Beginning with 1968, annual changes in the real value of
banks' imputed output are estimated by assuming that banks'
total output grows at the same rate as the output of the banking
industry in the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) estimates of
productivity by industry. The BLS estimate of banks' total output
is based on a weighted average of various indexes of bank activity,
including bank transactions (for example, checks cleared, ATM
transactions, and electronic funds transfers), the number of outstanding
loans of various types, and the number of trust accounts. (13) To
estimate chain-dollar real imputed output, BEA calculates a Fisher
aggregate of a Laspeyres constant-dollar measure and a Paasche
constant-dollar measure. Each constant-dollar measure of banks'
imputed output equals (a) the constant-dollar value of banks' total
output, estimated by extrapolating the base-year current-dollar estimate
of banks' total output by the BLS estimate of the growth in
banks' total output less (b) the constant-dollar real value of
banks' explicitly priced output, estimated by deflating banks'
service charges on deposit accounts and other noninterest income with
the CPI for checking account and other bank services and then adding an
estimate of banks' real fiduciary activities based on the growth of
the number of trust department discretionary accounts.
Prior to 1968, annual changes in the real value of imputed output
will continue to reflect the rate of growth in the hours worked by
banks' employees with no adjustment for changes in these
employees' productivity. Annual changes in the real value of
explicitly charged output will continue to reflect the post-1968
methodology, and annual changes in the real value of total output will
continue to equal the sum of changes in real imputed output and real
explicitly priced output.
Results for 2001
Table 2 shows the breakdown by sector and by legal form of
organization of the consumption of commercial banks' imputed
output. As a result of the revision, the imputed output of commercial
banks included in GDP falls by $91.9 billion. A rise in intermediate
consumption from about a fourth to about half of the total consumption
of implicit services accounts for $22.8 billion of the fall in GDP.
Borrower services to household owner-occupants and nonprofit
institutions account for much of this rise, but borrower services to
corporations and to sole proprietorships and partnerships also
contribute.
The remaining $69.1 billion of the fall in GDP reflects a fall in
imputed domestic output. One source of the fall in imputed domestic
output is a $13.0 billion fall in imputed output of U.S. offices of
foreign banks attributable to revisions in estimates these offices'
assets and liabilities. (14) The other source is a $56.0 billion change
in imputed domestic output attributable to the adoption of the reference
rate approach, which consists of (1) a $13.4 billion fall in imputed
output of U.S. offices of foreign banks; (2) an $18.9 billion fall in
the total imputed output of U.S. banks; and (3) a $23.7 billion rise in
the portion of the imputed output of U.S. banks allocated to their
offshore offices.
Table 3 shows how the downward revision to GDP and GDI for 2001
affects the new seven-account summary of the NIPAs. (15) The product
side of account 1 shows that the $91.9 fall in GDP consists of a
reduction of $78.1 billion in implicit services to persons, a reduction
of $8.9 billion in net exports of implicit services, and a reduction of
$4.9 billion in implicit services to governments. On the income side,
the net operating surplus of private enterprises falls by $91.9 billion.
(16)
Account 2 shows the effect on the sources and uses of private
enterprise income, which includes income of private businesses, imputed
income from owner-occupied housing, and net interest paid by nonprofit
institutions serving households. Imputed interest paid by banks to
depositors falls by $147.5 billion, and private enterprises borrowers
pay -$64.8 billion in imputed interest to banks. (As is explained above,
implicit banking services to borrowers are shown as negative imputed
interest paid by borrowers.) Private enterprises will also receive
$120.4 billion less in imputed interest, consisting of a reduction of
$42.0 billion in imputed interest received by private enterprises on
deposits and a new entry of-$78.4 billion representing imputed interest
received by banks from borrowers. Hence, net interest paid by private
enterprises falls by $91.9 billion, and GDI also falls by this amount.
Account 3, the personal income and outlay account, shows that the
$78.1 billion reduction in personal consumption expenditures consists of
a $90.1 billion reduction in implicit services to depositors that is
partly offset by the new entry for implicit services to borrowers of
$12.0 billion. Account 5, the foreign transactions current account,
shows that the $8.9 billion decrease in net exports of implicit services
shown in account 1 consists of a decrease of $10.3 billion in imputed
interest received by foreign depositors that is partly offset by imputed
interest of-$1.4 billion received from foreign borrowers. (Imputed
interest on foreign borrowing excludes loans booked in foreign offices
of U.S. banks because production in these foreign locations does not
belong in U.S. domestic product.) Accounts 6 and 7 show that measures of
saving, investment, and net lending to the rest of the world are
unaffected by the revised treatment of implicit services of banks.
Future Research
The new measures of implicit services to bank borrowers are an
important advance for the NIPAs. Nevertheless, many questions remain for
future research. One question is how to treat off-balance sheet
commitments, such as derivatives. A second is whether improvements are
possible in the measures of real bank output. A third concerns the
treatment of expected holding gains and losses and of credit losses.
(17) An allowance for credit losses is deducted from the value of loans
and leases in calculating imputed output in order to place the timing of
the recognition of these losses on an accrual basis. However, credit
losses are not directly reflected in the measures of interest income
that are used to calculate imputed output. If banks use a portion of
interest income to offset credit losses, that portion is not available
to pay for financial services. Furthermore, estimates of expected losses
will be excluded from the measure of imputed output elsewhere in the
revised NIPAs; see the discussion of insurance in Moulton and Seskin
(2003, 19-21).
Table 1. Revised Computation of Imputed Output, Commercial Banks in
the United States, 2001
[Billions of dollars]
(1) (2)
Average Interest
Line balance income or
expense
2001 2001
Balance sheet item
1 Total assets 6,034.5
2 Loans and leases, net of
allowance for losses and
unearned income 3,757.8 312.5
3 Domestic offices 3,487.6 288.1
4 Loans 3,341.0 278.3
5 Leases 146.6 9.8
6 Foreign offices 270.2 24.4
7 Investment securities, book
value 1,042.5 65.2
8 Treasury and U.S. Government
agency securities 736.8 46.0
9 Other securities, book
value, adjusted for
taxable-equivalence 305.7 19.2
10 Cash and all balances due from
depository institutions 251.2
11 Currency and coin 38.1
12 Balances due from the
Federal Reserve 24.8 0
13 Other balances due from
depository institutions 54.0 0
14 Interest-bearing balances
due from depository
institutions 133.5 5.4
15 Federal funds sold and
securities purchased under
agreement to resell 3,27.3 12.7
16 Trading amount assets 150.4 9.5
17 Other real estate 3.5
18 Bank premises and equipment 76.3
19 Intangible assets 113.1
20 All other assets 312.4
21 Total liabilities 5,703.8
22 Total deposits 4,169.2 132.5
23 In domestic offices 3,519.5 106.9
24 Demand deposits 506.6 0.0
25 Interest-bearing
deposits 3,012.9 106.9
26 Other checkable
deposits 155.9 3.1
27 Savings
(including
MMDAs) 1,522.0 33.3
28 Large time
deposits 549.6 27.7
29 Other time
deposits 785.3 42.7
30 Cash items in
process of
collection -129.2 0
31 In foreign offices 649.7 25.6
32 Borrowed funds 1,131.7 56.4
33 Federal funds purchased
and securities sold
under agreement to
repurchase 510.7 19.6
34 Other interest-bearing
liabilities 621.1 36.8
35 Other liabilities 402.8
36 Total equity capital 330.7
37 Plus: Implicit services from
Federal Reserve Banks 1.5
38 Equals: Total imputed output
Addenda:
39 Assets used to calculate imputed
output, U.S. banks (2,3) 5,221.0 380.8
40 Liabilities used to calculate
imputed output, U.S. banks
(3,4) 4,522.0 163.3
41 Net interest income or total
imputed output, U.S. banks (3) 217.5
42 Plus: User cost of own funds and
foreign office funds used for
domestic lending, U.S.-
chartered banks 699.0
43 Equals: Net interest income,
U.S.-chartered banks
44 Assets used to calculate imputed
output, including foreign
banks (2) 5,840.8 425.5
45 Liabilities used to calculate
imputed output, including
foreign banks 5,108.4 194.6
46 Net interest income or total
imputed output, including
foreign banks 230.9
47 Plus: User cost of own funds and
foreign office funds used for
domestic lending, including
foreign banks 732.4
48 Equals: Net interest income,
including foreign banks
(3) (4)
Average Average
Line rate of user cost
interest price
(2) / (1) (3)-6.24%
Balance sheet item
1 Total assets
2 Loans and leases, net of
allowance for losses and
unearned income
3 Domestic offices
4 Loans 8.33 2.09
5 Leases 6.72 0.48
6 Foreign offices
7 Investment securities, book
value
8 Treasury and U.S. Government
agency securities 6.24 0
9 Other securities, book
value, adjusted for
taxable-equivalence 6.28 0.04
10 Cash and all balances due from
depository institutions
11 Currency and coin
12 Balances due from the
Federal Reserve 0 -6.24
13 Other balances due from
depository institutions 0 -6.24
14 Interest-bearing balances
due from depository
institutions 4.01 -2.23
15 Federal funds sold and
securities purchased under
agreement to resell 3.87 -2.37
16 Trading amount assets 6.34 0.10
17 Other real estate
18 Bank premises and equipment
19 Intangible assets
20 All other assets
21 Total liabilities
22 Total deposits
23 In domestic offices
24 Demand deposits 0 6.24
25 Interest-bearing
deposits
26 Other checkable
deposits 1.96 4.28
27 Savings
(including
MMDAs) 2.19 4.05
28 Large time
deposits 5.05 1.19
29 Other time
deposits 5.44 0.80
30 Cash items in
process of
collection 0 6.24
31 In foreign offices
32 Borrowed funds
33 Federal funds purchased
and securities sold
under agreement to
repurchase 3.84 2.40
34 Other interest-bearing
liabilities 5.93 0.31
35 Other liabilities
36 Total equity capital
37 Plus: Implicit services from
Federal Reserve Banks
38 Equals: Total imputed output
Addenda:
39 Assets used to calculate imputed
output, U.S. banks (2,3) 7.29 1.05
40 Liabilities used to calculate
imputed output, U.S. banks
(3,4) 3.61 2.63
41 Net interest income or total
imputed output, U.S. banks (3)
42 Plus: User cost of own funds and
foreign office funds used for
domestic lending, U.S.-
chartered banks 6.24
43 Equals: Net interest income,
U.S.-chartered banks
44 Assets used to calculate imputed
output, including foreign
banks (2) 7.29 1.05
45 Liabilities used to calculate
imputed output, including
foreign banks 3.81 2.43
46 Net interest income or total
imputed output, including
foreign banks
47 Plus: User cost of own funds and
foreign office funds used for
domestic lending, including
foreign banks 6.24
48 Equals: Net interest income,
including foreign banks
(5)
(6)
Ratio of all Imputed
Line banks to U.S: gross
chartered output
banks
in the U.S. (1) (1 x 4) x (5)
Balance sheet item
1 Total assets
2 Loans and leases, net of
allowance for losses and
unearned income
3 Domestic offices
4 Loans 1.107 77.3
5 Leases 1.107 0.8
6 Foreign offices
7 Investment securities, book
value
8 Treasury and U.S. Government
agency securities 1.102
9 Other securities, book
value, adjusted for
taxable-equivalence 1.325 0.2
10 Cash and all balances due from
depository institutions
11 Currency and coin
12 Balances due from the
Federal Reserve 1.000 -1.5
13 Other balances due from
depository institutions 1.154 -3.9
14 Interest-bearing balances
due from depository
institutions 1.154 -3.4
15 Federal funds sold and
securities purchased under
agreement to resell 1.097 -8.5
16 Trading amount assets 1.080 0.2
17 Other real estate
18 Bank premises and equipment
19 Intangible assets
20 All other assets
21 Total liabilities
22 Total deposits
23 In domestic offices
24 Demand deposits 1.017 32.1
25 Interest-bearing
deposits
26 Other checkable
deposits 1.001 6.7
27 Savings
(including
MMDAs) 1.001 61.7
28 Large time
deposits 1.690 11.1
29 Other time
deposits 1.001 6.3
30 Cash items in
process of
collection 1.154 -9.3
31 In foreign offices
32 Borrowed funds
33 Federal funds purchased
and securities sold
under agreement to
repurchase 1.064 13.0
34 Other interest-bearing
liabilities 1.296 2.5
35 Other liabilities
36 Total equity capital
37 Plus: Implicit services from
Federal Reserve Banks 1.5
38 Equals: Total imputed output 186.6
Addenda:
39 Assets used to calculate imputed
output, U.S. banks (2,3) 56.5
40 Liabilities used to calculate
imputed output, U.S. banks
(3,4) 118.9
41 Net interest income or total
imputed output, U.S. banks (3) 175.4
42 Plus: User cost of own funds and
foreign office funds used for
domestic lending, U.S.-
chartered banks 43.6
43 Equals: Net interest income,
U.S.-chartered banks 219.0
44 Assets used to calculate imputed
output, including foreign
banks (2) 62.5
45 Liabilities used to calculate
imputed output, including
foreign banks 124.1
46 Net interest income or total
imputed output, including
foreign banks 186.6
47 Plus: User cost of own funds and
foreign office funds used for
domestic lending, including
foreign banks 45.7
48 Equals: Net interest income,
including foreign banks 232.3
(1.) Ratios are for (by line): Loans and leases (4 and 5), Securities
other than U.S. government securities in bank credit (9); Cash assets
(13, 14, 30); Interbank loans (15); Other assets (16); Transaction
deposits (24); Nontransaction deposits other than large time deposits
(26, 27, 29); Large time deposits (28); Borrowing from banks in the
U.S. (33); Borrowing other than from banks in the U.S. (34).
(2.) Sum of lines 4-5, 8-9, and 12-16. Imputed interest from Federal
Reserve Banks on line 37 is also included in imputed gross output.
(3.) Imputed gross output shown excludes the effect of the adjustment
for foreign banks using the factors in column (5).
(4.) Sum of lines 24, 26-30, 33, and 34.
MMDAS Money market deposit accounts
Table 2. Consumption of Imputed Output of Commercial Banks by
Sector and Legal Form of Organization, 2001
[Billions of dollars]
Based on Currently Revision in
user costs published level
Total 186.6 255.7 -69.1
Final consumption 93.6 185.5 -91.9
Persons 78.8 156.9 -78.1
Federal Government (1) 0.3 0.8 -0.5
State and local governments
(1) 5.1 9.6 -4.5
Rest of the world 9.4 18.3 -8.9
Intermediate consumption 93.0 70.2 22.8
Corporate 52.5 51.3 1.7
Financial 7.3 9.9 -2.6
Nonfinancial 45.2 41.3 3.9
Sole proprietorships and
partnerships 20.3 18.8 1.5
Farm 1.6 1.0 0.6
Nonfarm 18.6 17.8 0.8
Other private business 2.4 0.1 2.3
Households and nonprofit
institutions 17.8 0 17.8
(1.) In the comprehensive revision, the value of the services produced
by general government, which represents governments' contribution to
final demand, will be estimated by the cost of inputs, including
purchases of implicit output of banks. The revised treatment of
banking will indirectly reduce the services produced by general
government because purchases of implicit output of banks will be
reduced. Final demand of general government, which will equal the
services produced by governments less their sales of services in the
market, will also reflect the downward revision to governments'
purchases of implicit output of banks.
Table 3. Revisions to Summary National Income and Product Accounts,
2001
[Billions of dollars]
Account 1. Domestic Income and Product Account, Proposed Less
Published Estimates
Net operating surplus -91.9
Private enterprises -91.9
Imputed interest paid -212.3
By banks to depositors -147.5
By borrowers to banks (1) -64.8
Less: Imputed interest received -120.4
By depositors from banks (1) -42.0
By banks from borrowers -78.4
Gross domestic income -91.9
Statistical discrepancy 0.0
GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT -91.9
Personal consumption expenditures -78.1
Implicit services furnished by banks -78.1
Net exports of goods and services -8.9
Exports -8.9
Implicit services furnished by banks -8.9
Government consumption expenditures and gross investment -4.9
Federal -0.4
Implicit services furnished by banks -0.4
State and local -4.4
Implicit services furnished by banks -4.4
GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT -91.9
(1.) Includes domestic business, owner-occupied housing, and nonprofit
institutions serving households.
Account 2. Private Enterprise Income Account, Proposed Less Published
Estimates
Income payments on assets -212.3
Interest and miscellaneous payments -212.3
Interest payments -212.3
Imputed interest -212.3
By borrowers to banks (1) -64.8
By banks to depositors -147.5
USES OF PRIVATE ENTERPRISE INCOME -212.3
Net operating surplus private enterprises -91.9
Income receipts on assets -120.4
Interest receipts -120.4
Imputed interest -120.4
By banks from borrowers (1) -78.4
By other private enterprises on deposits -42.0
SOURCES OF PRIVATE ENTERPRISE INCOME -212.3
(1.) Includes domestic business, owner-occupied housing, and nonprofit
institutions serving households.
Account 3. Personal Income and Outlay Account, Proposed Less Published
Estimates
Personal current taxes 0.0
Personal outlays -90.1
Personal consumption expenditures -78.1
Implicit services furnished by banks -78.1
Personal interest payments -12.0
Imputed interest paid -12.0
To banks on borrowed funds -12.0
Personal saving 0.0
PERSONAL TAXES, OUTLAYS, AND SAVING -90.1
Personal income receipts on assets -90.1
Personal interest income -90.1
Imputed interest income -90.1
On deposits -90.1
PERSONAL INCOME -90.1
Account 4. Government Receipts and Expenditures Account, Proposed Less
Published Estimates
Consumption expenditures -4.9
Implicit services furnished by banks -4.9
Federal -0.4
State and local -4.4
Interest payments -0.2
Imputed interest paid -0.2
To banks on borrowed funds -0.2
Federal 0.0
State and local -0.2
GOVERNMENT CURRENT EXPENDITURES AND NET SAVING -5.0
Income receipts on assets -5.0
Interest and miscellaneous receipts -5.0
Interest receipts -5.0
Imputed interest received -5.0
On deposits -5.0
Federal -0.4
State and local -4.6
GOVERNMENT CURRENT RECEIPTS -5.0
Account 5. Foreign Transactions Account, Proposed Less Published
Estimates
Exports of goods and services -8.9
Services -8.9
Implicit services furnished by banks -8.9
Income receipts from the rest of the world -1.4
Income receipts on assets -1.4
Imputed interest paid by the rest of the world -1.4
To banks on borrowed funds -1.4
CURRENT RECEIPTS FROM THE REST OF THE WORLD -10.3
Income payments to the rest of the world -10.3
Income payments on assets -10.3
Interest payments -10.3
Imputed interest received by the rest of the world -10.3
On deposits -10.3
CURRENT PAYMENTS TO THE REST OF THE WORLD AND BALANCE ON
CURRENT ACCOUNT -10.3
Account 6. Domestic Capital Account, Proposed Less Published Estimates
GROSS INVESTMENT, CAPITAL, TRANSFERS, AND NET LENDING 0
GROSS SAVING AND STATISTICAL DISCREPANCY 0
Account 7. Foreign Transactions Capital Account, Proposed Less
Published Estimates
BALANCE ON CURRENT ACCOUNT, NIPAs 0
CAPITAL TRANSFERS (NET) AND NET LENDING, NIPAS 0
NOTE. Components may not add up to totals shown because of rounding.
Effect on GDP by Industry and Gross State Product
The changes in the methods for measuring banks' imputed output
and for allocating it to bank customers will affect the estimates of GDP
by industry. GDP by industry measures the contribution of each private
industry and of government to the Nation's GDP. It equals an
industry's value added. For any private industry, GDP by industry
is defined as gross output (which consists of sales or receipts and
other operating income, commodity taxes, and inventory change) less
purchases of intermediate inputs (which consist of energy, raw
materials, semi-finished goods, and services, including services of
banks).
Identifying inputs and outputs is less straightforward for banking
than it is for most industries. (1) In the NIPA treatment, banks use
primary and intermediate inputs to produce the financial services that
constitute their output. Financial products such as deposits and loans
are packages of financial services; thus deposits, though an inflow to
banks, are not an input. The implicity priced services associated with
financial products are banks' output, along with the services that
carry explicit fees.
The changes in the treatment of the banking industry will not
affect banks' purchases of intermediate inputs, so the change in
this industry's value added will equal the change in its gross
output. For other private industries, intermediate inputs will rise,
reducing value added. Private industries consume relatively more
borrower services than households and government, so their consumption
of implicit services of banks will be higher when services currently
shown as going to depositors are allocated to borrowers. Under the new
treatment of government (described in Moulton and Seskin (2003, 30-31),
GDP by industry for general government will not change, but government
consumption expenditures and government gross output will fall by an
amount equal to the reduction in governments' final purchases of
banks' imputed output. For the economy as a whole, the increase in
intermediate consumption of private industry will generally have a
larger affect on GDP than the reduction in banks' total imputed
output.
These revisions to GDP by industry will be reflected in revised
estimates of gross state product (GSP). GSP measures the value added in
production by the labor and property located in a state, and us
controlled to national estimates of GDP by industry. GSP for a state is
derived as the sum of the GSP originating in all industries in the
state.
(1) There is a considerable literature on the identification of
inputs and outputs in banking, and the choice of a classification
framework depends on the measurement question to be addressed. For
examples of different framework, see Allen Berger and David Humphrey (1992).
(1.) Brent R. Moulton and Eugene E Seskin, "Preview of the
2003 Comprehensive Revision of the National Income and Product Accounts:
Changes in Definitions and Classifications" SURVEY OF CURRENT
BUSINESS 83, June 2003: 24-27; and Nicole Mayerhauser, Shelly Smith, and
David F. Sullivan, "Preview of the 2003 Comprehensive Revision of
the National Income and Product Accounts: New and Redesigned
Tables" SURVEY or CURRENT BUSINESS 83, August 2003: 21.
(2.) Commission of the European Communities, International Monetary
Fund, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, United
Nations, and World Bank, System of National Accounts 1993
(Brussels/Luxembourg, New York, Paris, and Washington, DC, 1993).
(3.) Many European countries currently treat the implicit financial
services of banks as an intermediate input to a fictitious sector,
thereby keeping them out of GDP.
(4.) The percentages are calculated from data from the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation at <www2.fdic.gov/hsob>. The growth
of fee income partly reflects banks' entry into new kinds of
activities, but the trend predates the repeal in 1999 of the
Glass-Steagall Act's restrictions on bank activities.
(5.) This example is based on individual bank data at
<www3.fdic.gov/ idasp/main.asp>.
(6.) Barnett (1978) describes the reference rate as a minimum rate
of return that accounts for risk, but most applications of the reference
rate, including the 1993 SNA, view it as a risk-free rate.
(7.) Barnett (1978) uses a different approach to derive equation
(2). He considers a consumer who maximizes life cycle utility subject to
a set of budget constraints that the change in wealth in any period
equals current income received minus current expenditures and who is
able to invest in an instrument that earns the reference rate of return.
(8.) Since 1974, commercial banks' provision for credit losses
has usually ranged from about 10 percent to about 20 percent of their
net interest income. These ratios are calculated using data from the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, available at
<www2.fdic.gov/hsob>. Realized net credit losses have been
slightly lower than provisions for credit losses, partly because of
timing differences and survivorship bias.
(9.) However, the measure of banks' lending of own funds
differs from the accounting entry for stockholders' equity on
banks' balance sheets because own funds do not reflect all the
assets and liabilities reflected in stockholders' equity.
(10.) SNA 1993, paragraph 6.125.
(11) Beginning with 1985, the Call Report data are adjusted by the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System to take account of
mergers; see Carlson and Perli (2003). Call Report data for 1984 and
earlier are taken from the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation,
Historical Statistics on Banking, at <www2.fdic.gov/hsob>.
(12.) SNA 1993, Annex III, paragraphs 5-7.
(13.) The BLS methodology is explained in Kent Kunze, Mary
Jablonski, and Mark Sieling (1998). BLS does not have a separate measure
of the imputed output of banks.
(14.) Note that this revision would have occurred even without the
change in the treatment of banks.
(15.) In the comprehensive revision of the NIPAs, the traditional
five summary accounts will be expanded to seven accounts; see
Mayerhauser, Smith and Sullivan (2003, 8-15).
(16.) Net operating surplus is a measure of business income that
equals gross value added less the costs of compensation of employees,
taxes on production and imports--that is, indirect taxes such as sales
and
property taxes--less subsidies and consumption of fixed capital;
financing costs, such as net interest, and business transfers are not
subtracted.
(17.) See Fixler and Moulton (2001).
References
Anderson, Richard G., Barry E. Jones, and Travis D. Nesmith. 1997a.
"Monetary Aggregation Theory and Statistical Index Numbers."
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review (January/February 1997): 31-52.
<research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/97/01/ 9701ra2.pdf>.
Anderson, Richard G., Barry E. Jones, and Travis D. Nesmith. 1997b.
"Building New Monetary Services Indexes: Concepts, Data, and
Methods." Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review
(January/February 1997): 53-82.
<research.stlouisfed.org/publications/ review/97/01/9701ra3.pdf>.
Barnett, William A. 2000. "The User Cost of Money." In
The Theory of Monetary Aggregation, edited by William A. Barnett and
Apostolos Serletis. Amsterdam: North Holland. First published in
Economic Letters 2 (1978): 145-49.
Barnett, William A. 2000. "Economic Money Aggregates." In
The Theory of Monetary Aggregation, edited by William A. Barnett and
Apostolos Serletis. Amsterdam: North Holland. First published in Journal
of Econometrics 14 (1980): 11-48.
Berger, Allen, and David Humphrey. 1992. "Measurement and
Efficiency Issues in Commercial Banking." In Output and Measurement
in the Service Sector. Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 56, edited by
Zvi Griliches. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Carlson, Mark, and Roberto Perli. 2003. "Profits and Balance
Sheet Developments at U.S. Commercial Banks in 2002." Federal
Reserve Bulletin (June): 243-270.
<www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/bulletin/2003/06031ead.pdf>.
Commission of the European Communities. 2002a. "Report From
the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament Concerning the
Allocation of Financial Intermediation Services Indirectly Measured
(FISIM)." Mimeo. europa.eu.int/eur-lex/en/
com/rpt/2002/com2002_0333en01.pdf>.
Commission of the European Communities. 2002b. "Commission
Regulation (EC) No. 1889/2002 of 23 October 2002 on the Implementation
of Council Regulation (EC) No. 448/98 Completing and Amending Regulation
(EC) No. 2223/96 with Respect to the Allocation of Financial
Intermediation Services Indirectly Measured (FISIM) Within the European
System of National and Regional Accounts (ESA). Official Journal of the
European Communities 45 (October 24): 11.
<europa.en.int/eur-lex/pri/en/oj/
dat/2002/1_286/1_28620021024en00110012.pdf
Commission of the European Communities, International Monetary
Fund, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, United
Nations, and World Bank. 1993. System of National Accounts 1993.
Brussels/Luxembourg, New York, Paris, Washington, DC.
Diewert, W. Erwin. 1974. "Intertemporal Consumer Theory and
the Demand for Durables." Econometrica 42, (May): 497-516.
Donovan, Donald. 1978. "Modeling the Demand for Liquid Assets:
An Application to Canada," IMF Staff Papers 25,676-704.
Fixler, Dennis J. 1993. "Measuring Financial Service Output of
Commercial Banks." Applied Economics 25, 983-999.
Fixler, Dennis J., and Brent R. Moulton. 2001. "Comments on
the Treatment of Holding Gains and Losses in the National
Accounts?' Paper presented at the OECD Meeting of National Accounts
Experts, Paris, October 2001.
Fixler, Dennis l., and Kimberly Zieschang. 1999. "The
Productivity of the Banking Sector: Integrating Financial and Production
Approaches to Measuring Financial Service Output" Canadian Journal
of Economics 32 (April): 547-569.
Hancock, Diana. 1985. "The Financial Firm: Production with
Monetary and Nonmonetary Goods?' Journal of Political Economy 93
(October): 859-880.
Kunze, Kent, Mary Jablonski, and Mark Siding. 1998. "Measuring
Output and Labor Productivity of Commercial Banks (SIC 602): A
Transactions-Based Approach." Paper presented at the Brookings
Institution Workshop on Banking Output, Washington, DC, November 20.
Mayerhauser, Nicole, Shelly Smith, and David E Sullivan. 2003.
"Preview of the 2003 Comprehensive Revision of the National Income
and Product Accounts: New and Redesigned Tables." SURVEY OF CURRENT
BUSINESS 83 (August):7-31. <www.bea.gov/bea/
Articles/2003/08August/0803NIPA-Preview.pdf>.
Moulton, Brent R., and Eugene R Seskin. 2003. "Preview of the
2003 Comprehensive Revision of the National Income and Product Accounts:
Changes in Definitions and Classifications." SURVEY OF CURRENT
BUSINESS 83 (June):17-34. <www.bea.gov/bea/Articles/
2003/06June/0603NIPArevs.pdf>.
Michael Murphy, Bonnie Retus, and Shaunda Villones contributed to
the preparation of the estimates.