A satellite account for research and development.
Carson, Carol S. ; Grimm, Bruce T. ; Moylan, Carol E. 等
BEA has prepared a satellite account that arrays information about
research and development (R&D). First, the satellite account
provides estimates of expenditures on R&D that are designed to be
used in conjunction with the national income and product accounts
measures, Second, it treats R&D expenditures as a form of
investment, recognizing the role R&D plays in adding to knowledge
and in developing new and improved processes and products that lead to
increases in productivity and growth. Third, it provides estimates of
the stock of knowledge capital To focus on R&D and facilitate its
analysis, the satellite account changes some definitions and
classifications used in the national income and product accounts but
otherwise is designed to be consistent statistically and conceptually
with those accounts. Thus, the satellite account supplements the
existing accounts.
BEA'S economic accounts have always benefited from discussion
and critique of concepts, source data, and estimating methods. The same
is to be expected for the R&D satellite account. Comments are
welcome.
Carol S. Carson
Director, Bureau of Economic Analysis
In Industrial laboratories, agricultural experiment stations,
medical research institutes, and a variety of other settings, the United
States undertakes a sizable research and development (R&D) effort.
This effort plays a critical role in economic growth and in addressing
many specific related concerns. In the words of the National Science
Board:
The absolute magnitude of the [R&D] effort
and the manifold tasks to which it is directed
are indicative of the critical role that R&D plays
in addressing such concerns as national defense,
industrial competitiveness, public health, environmental
quality, and social well-being. Indeed,
the long-term importance Of R&D expenditures to
technological preeminence, military security, and
knowledge growth is axiomatic.(1)
Ideally, to document this role within the economy and thus lay the
foundation for policy and other decisions, one would measure the output
of R&D--the new understanding, or the knowledge, it creates.
However, measures of knowledge created, to the extent that they exist,
do not share a common yardstick--such as dollars--with other measures
with which they might be used. Almost universally then, analysts turn to
expenditures on R&D as a starting point.
Several questions about expenditures on R&D immediately come to
mind:
* How much is being spent on R&D today? How much has R&D
spending grown in recent decades? How large iS R&D compared with GDP in the United States? In other countries?
* Who is performing the R&D? What share is being performed by
government, by nonprofit organizations, and by industries? Which
industries perform the most R&D?
* Who is funding the R&D?
Expenditures on R&D can be viewed as generating future income
and product. With this view, a case is made for treating them as
investment, paralleling the treatment of business expenditures on
structures and durable equipment, and for recognizing a stock of
intangible capital, just as there is a stock of tangible capital.
Further questions then arise:
* How large is the stock Of R&D capital? How has the stock
changed over recent decades?
* How does the stock Of R&D capital compare with the stock of
building's, equipment, and other parts of the Nation's wealth?
Answers to these questions have been less than fully satisfactory.
On the one hand, the national income and product accounts (NIPA'S)
might seem the obvious place to look for expenditure estimates: If
R&D expenditure estimates were in the accounts, they could readily
be compared with GDP or its components, and models could be constructed
to relate changes in R&D tO other parts of the economy represented
in the accounts. However, only a portion Of R&D expenditures are
identifiable within the NIPA'S, and those identified--as well as
the unidentified--expenditures on R&D are treated as consumption
rather than as investment. Further, because R&D expenditures are not
treated as investment, there is no associated stock of capital.(2) On
the other hand, R&D data from other sources are not fully consistent
with the NIPA'S and with the NIPA-based measures of tangible
capital, so they cannot readily be used in conjunction with NIPA
estimates in analysis.
This article introduces a satellite account that is designed to
provide a View Of R&D that has ties to the NIPA'S, while also
using alternative definitions and providing consistent detail that help
to focus on the role Of R&D in the economy. BEA began work on the
satellite account for R&D in 1992, following a preliminary
evaluation of the feasibility and usefulness of such an account.(3)
The estimates presented in the satellite account build on data
published by the National Science Foundation (NSF), which assembles a
wide range of information related to R&D.4 The estimates extend
through 1992, the most recent year for which complete source data are
currently available.
The first section of the article defines R&D and describes its
role in creating knowledge and then sketches the economic accounting
background for the satellite account's investment treatment. The
second section provides a methodological overview. The third section
presents the estimates Of R&D expenditures, investment, capital
stocks, and related data. The fourth section discusses future directions
that work on the satellite account might follow. A technical note at the
end of the article details the construction of the estimates.
Background
R&D and knowledge
R&D is "creative work undertaken on a systematic basis in
order to increase the stock of knowledge, including knowledge of man,
culture and society, and the use of this stock of knowledge to devise
new applications." This definition is from a newly revised manual
(the Frascati Manual) of standard practice for surveys Of R&D
activity, prepared by the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and
Development.(5) It is widely used internationally as the basis for
R&D statistics, such those compiled and analyzed by NSF in the
United States.
More commonly, R&D iS characterized as the sum of three types
of activities--basic research, applied research, and development. These
activities also have been defined in the Frascati Manual although in
practice it is often difficult--perhaps increasingly so--to establish
the boundaries between them:
* Basic research is "experimental or theoretical work
undertaken primarily to acquire new knowledge of the underlying
foundation of phenomena and observable facts, without any particular
application or use in view."
* Applied research is "original investigation undertaken in
order to acquire new knowledge . . . directed primarily towards a
specific practical aim or objective."
* Development is "systematic work, drawing on existing
knowledge gained from research and/or practical experience, that is
directed to producing new materials, products or devices, to installing
new processes, systems and services, or to improving substantially those
already produced or installed."(6)
R&D is to be distinguished from a wide range of related
activities that are linked to R&D both through flows of information
and in terms of operations, institutions, and personnel. The basic
criterion, according to the Frascati Manual, to be used to distinguish
R&D from related activities "is the presence in R&D of an
appreciable element of novelty and the resolution of scientific and/or
technological uncertainty." R&D does not include, for example,
the following: Routine activities (such as product testing, quality
control, experimental production, routine software development, and
monitoring and evaluation of operational programs), patent and license
work, final product or design engineering and manufacturing start-up,
and training of scientific and technical personnel.
R&D may be viewed as increasing the stock of knowledge that
leads to improved understanding or to improved processes or products.
Basic research creates a pool of knowledge that can be drawn upon for
further basic research or for performing applied research.(7) Applied
research draws upon both basic research and earlier applied research to
create knowledge that can be used to develop new or improved processes
and products. Development draws upon both applied research and earlier
development. New or improved processes or products come into being only
at the end of the development process. There are lags between the
creation of knowledge, particularly that produced by basic research, and
its effects on output. The lags reflect both the time needed for R&D
to lead to improved processes and products and the time needed for the
improved processes and products to be fully adopted throughout the
economy.
Neither the creation of knowledge nor the resulting stock of
knowledge are measurable directly. Measures of output, such as the
number of scientific and technical journal articles published and the
number of patents awarded, only roughly approximate the creation of
knowledge because they only cover a portion Of R&D and because many
innovations are not patented. A frequently used method for measuring the
output of knowledge is to equate that output with the expenditures
required to produce it. Those expenditures can be cumulated over
time--with or without depreciation--to measure the stock of knowledge.
R&D in economic accounting
R&D in standard economic accounts.--In accounting for a
nation's production by adding up expenditures to derive gross
domestic product (GDP), two main issues about the treatment of R&D
arise:
* Are expenditures on R&D considered expenditures on final
goods and services--that is, one of the products whose value is added up
in deriving an unduplicated production total such as GDP?
* Even when the expenditures on R&D are considered expenditures
on final goods and services, are they considered investment?
In the NIPA'S, expenditures on R&D by business--whether
actually purchased from others or carried out inhouse--are treated as
intermediate rather than final; they are considered as a current expense
of production and are not among the expenditures added up in deriving
GDP. Treating them as a current expense follows general business
accounting practice; the uncertainty about the future benefits of
individual projects is a key argument for expensing R&D.
Expenditures on R&L) by government and by nonprofit institutions are
treated as expenditures on final goods and services. All expenditures on
R&D by government and nonprofit institutions are treated as part of
consumption in the current period, the former as part of government
purchases and the latter as part of personal consumption expenditures;
none are treated as investment. In the NIPA'S,
investment--specifically gross private domestic investment--consists
solely of purchases of structures, durable equipment, and change in
inventories by the business sector. Expenditures by a U.S. resident for
R&D performed abroad are treated as imports, and expenditures by a
foreign resident for R&D performed in the United States are treated
as exports. These points are summarized in table A, which also indicates
that, with the exception of contractual R&D in Federal national
defense purchases, R&D expenditures are not identified in GDP.
[TABULAR DATA A OMITTED]
The issue of the scope of investment in the economic accounts, and
in particular the issue of including R&D in investment, is a
longstanding one. John Kendrick, in 1951, identified activities related
to improvements in technology and technical innovations as leading to
improved productivity; he noted that technological innovations depend on
advances in knowledge, and he focused on research as a source of these
advances.(8) He viewed research expenditures--whether directed toward
improving structures and equipment, raising the level of health, or
dealing with problems of land and natural resource use--as expenditures
devoted to increasing productivity. Accordingly, he proposed that they
be treated as investment in the economic accounts. He noted that gross
product would be higher by the amount of expenditure by business on
R&D, which would be counted as final product rather than expensed;
because expenditures by nonprofit institutions and government are
already counted as final product, a change to treat them as investment
would not change gross product.
The issue was raised again a few years later at a conference that
led to the volume A Critique of the United States Income and Product
Accounts.9 The case was made that these expenditures "pay" in
terms of yielding future returns and thus fit the general
characterization of investment. Although various conceptual and
statistical difficulties were identified as obstacles, there were some
prospects for better statistics.
The 1968 revision of the System of National Accounts, published by
the United Nations as international guidelines for economic accounting,
referred to the urgent need to clarify the question of R&D
expenditures in dealing with the boundary between current and capital
expenditures. It was noted that the clarification could come only on the
basis of experience.
R&D in extended economic accounts.--A number of analysts, working
with the U.S. economic accounts, have proposed systems that expand the
boundaries of investment by including R&D and several other
categories of expenditures.
Nancy Ruggles and Richard Ruggles, in 1970, proposed a category of
"development" outlays defined as those that meet the criterion
that the value of the services provided by the outlay must accrue in
future periods rather than entirely in the present period.(10) Outlays
on education and training and some outlays on health, as well as outlays
on R&D, were viewed as meeting the criterion. Their proposed system
included stocks of "development" capital. They valued the
services of the R&D portion of the capital stock as the amortization
adjusted to market prices plus an imputed interest charge on the capital
stock.
John Kendrick implemented his view that expenditures on certain
intangibles are "made primarily to improve the quality or
productivity of the tangible. . . factors in which they are
embodied" and should be treated as investment that creates
intangible capital.(11) The intangible investment and capital included
R&D, education and training, health and safety, and labor mobility.
He created gross stock by cumulating investments over their lifetimes
and net stocks by cumulating depreciation on each vintage of investment
and subtracting it from the gross stock. He estimated rental values of
the capital stocks (referred to by other authors as service values or
returns) for the nonbusiness sectors and added them to income) and
product. His effort, published in 1976, was viewed as a pilot study for
determining the feasibility and usefulness of developing estimates of
total investment and capital stocks.
Robert Eisner used "include investment in intangible and human
capital" as one of the guiding principles for his total incomes
system of accounts, published in 1989.(12) His interest in investment
stemmed in major part from its relation to productivity and growth. His
intangible capital comprised R&D, education and training, and
health. His methodology for measuring R&D investment and
capitalizing it was essentially the same as Kendrick's.
Satellite accounts.--Meanwhile, the possibility of treating R&D
and several other activities as investment was discussed at length in
preparing for the System of National Accounts 1993.(13) At the outset of
the discussion, there was strong support for treating at least some
portion of R&D expenditures as investment. Several proposals were
made to identify a portion that was most clearly linked to a future
return--for example, the portion of development expenditures in which
the expenditures are identifiable and the outcome reasonably certain
enough to assure that the costs of the project would be exceeded by the
revenue.
In the end, however, no change was made in the treatment Of
R&D. The explanation of the treatment of business expenditures on
R&D noted that they are undertaken to improve efficiency or to
derive other future benefits and so are inherently investment-type
activities. However, practical difficulties in meeting the accounting
requirements for treating R&D and similar activities as investment
suggested that they be treated as intermediate:
In order to classify such activities as investment
type it would be necessary to have clear
criteria for delineating them from other activities,
to be able to identify and classify the assets
produced, to be able to value such assets in an
economically meaningful way and to know the
rate at which they depreciate over time. In practice
it is difficult to meet all these requirements.
By convention, therefore, all the outputs produced
by research and development, staff training,
market research and similar activities are treated
as being consumed as intermediate inputs even
though some of them may bring future benefits.(14)
Nevertheless, there was strong interest in being able to identify
R&D within the economic accounts, and work toward classification
systems that would help do so was encouraged. In addition, R&D was
recognized as a prime candidate for presentation in a satellite account,
an economic accounting tool that achieved international recognition when
it was incorporated in the System of National Accounts 1993.
In brief, satellite accounts are frameworks designed to expand the
analytical capacity of the economic accounts without overburdening them
with detail or interfering with their general-purpose orientation.
Satellite accounts, which are meant to supplement, rather than replace,
the existing accounts, organize information in an internally consistent
way that suits the particular analytical focus at hand, while
maintaining links to the existing accounts. In their most flexible
application, they may use definitions and classifications that differ
from those in the existing accounts; for example, the R&D satellite
account uses a different definition of investment, and it classifies
transactors into different groupings. In addition, satellite accounts
typically add detail or other information, including nonmonetary
information, about a particular aspect of the economy to that in the
existing accounts; for example, the R&D satellite account includes
information about R&D employment.
The advantages of using R&D information assembled along the
lines of the Frascati Manual to prepare a satellite account have become
increasingly clear. One of the first satellite accounts, prepared in
France in the 1970's, built on such R&D information.(15) More
recently, a framework for an R&D satellite account for the
Netherlands was constructed to use such information.(16) The new
Frascati Manual specifically recognizes the connection between the data
it describes and economic accounting, and it includes an annex that
explains satellite accounts to experts on science and technology who are
not familiar with economic accounting.
Methodological Overview
The R&D satellite account focuses on the value Of R&D
produced in the United States and the use of that output as investment.
Because no direct measure of output is available, R&D produced is
measured by summing the costs of its production, a technique of
measurement used in economic accounting for most nonmarket production.
The resulting total is referred to as R&D expenditures. The
expenditure estimates were prepared by starting with the information
available from surveys conducted for NSF and adjusting it to statistical
and conceptual consistency with the NIPA'S. The decision to work
with information that is not extensively used to prepare the NIPA
estimates was made because the regular source data and estimating
methods do not permit the required level of resolution needed to focus
on R&D.(17)
The satellite account groups organizations in a way that reflects
the features of their institutional structures and purposes that are
relevant tO R&D. In light of the interest in academic R&D,
universities and colleges (along with their affiliated institutions,
agricultural experiment stations, and associated schools of agriculture)
need to be shown separately. Federally funded research and development
centers (FFRDC'S),which are R&D organizations financed almost
entirely by the Federal Government, are shown separately and grouped
with the several kinds of entities that administer them. (At present,
there are 39 FFRDC'S, including the RAND Corporation, Argonne
National Laboratory, E.O. Lawrence Livermore Laboratory, and Brookhaven
National Laboratory.) The satellite account shows two major groups:
"Private" organizations and "government."
"Private" organizations consist of business (labeled
"industry"); private universities and colleges, private
hospitals, charitable foundations, and other nonprofit institutions
serving households; and most FFRDC'S. "Government"
consists of the Federal Government, State and local governments
(excluding universities and colleges), public universities and colleges,
and FFRDC'S administered by State and local government
organizations, primarily public universities and colleges.
Constant-dollar R&D expenditures are derived by deflation, the
method most often used in the NIPA'S. In deflation, constant-dollar
estimates are obtained by dividing the most detailed current-dollar
components by appropriate price indexes. In the case Of R&D, the
current-dollar components are its costs of production. The expenditure
estimates are treated as investment and cumulated to yield R&D
capital stocks using methodologies developed by BEA to estimate fixed
reproducible tangible capital stocks.
The most important of the methodological issues encountered in
preparing the satellite account are described in this section.
Current-dollar expenditures
The measure of expenditures--reflecting labor costs, the costs of
materials and supplies, and overhead costs (including a charge for the
capital used in producing R&D)--IS based on data by performer, when
available, from NSF surveys. Only the data by performer provide the cost
components needed to construct constant dollars.
BEA supplements the coverage of the survey-based data and extends
it back in time. Missing data, primarily for State and local government
R&D and the R&D of some types of nonprofit institutions, are
interpolated and extrapolated from years for which data are available.
Estimates for years prior to the first NSF survey in 1953 (which are
needed to estimate stocks and related measures but are not presented in
this article) are primarily based on outside studies that estimated
R&D for selected years.(18) Some supporting data-in particular, for
pre-1953 FFRDC'S--are estimated by BEA using various sources.
A number of adjustments are made to the NSF survey-based spending
data to make them statistically and conceptually consistent with the
NIPA'S. The statistical adjustments are for timing and geographic
coverage and to fill gaps with estimates for some industries in some
years. A conceptual adjustment is made to put depreciation of structures
and equipment used in producing R&D on a basis that reflects the
valuation and consistency appropriate for economic accounts.
BEA has implemented three disaggregations of R&D expenditures
for analytical use in the satellite account: By performer, with industry
detail; by source of funding; and by type. R&D by performer serves
the same purposes for R&D as breakdowns by sector or industry of
origin in analyses of production, which are often a first step in
studies of structural change. R&D by funder is useful because a
substantial portion Of R&D is not financed by the performer. R&D
by type is useful because the different types interact with the economy
in different ways and with different lags. Other disaggregations would
also be useful, but are not practical given current resources. For
example, R&D disaggregated by purpose, such as defense or health,
would help relate R&D expenditures to other issues. Geographic
breakdowns would also be of interest--for example, in location
decisions, for which proximity to research resources may be a factor.
Constant-dollar expenditures
The R&D satellite account provides estimates of constant-dollar
expenditures by performer. In the absence of outputs and output price
measures, costs of inputs are deflated by weighted indexes of input
prices. The costs of inputs are derived, at the finest level of detail
possible, from the limited cost information available from NSF surveys.
The cost components are matched as closely as possible with
"proxy" prices. The individual constant-dollar cost components
are summed. to derive constant-dollar expenditures by performer.
(Implicit price deflators for R&D by performer are a byproduct of
the procedure.
Constant-dollar estimates derived in this way take into account the
changing Mix Of R&D performers over time. The estimates of
constant-dollar compensation of employees, which overall is about 45
percent of inputs, reflect changes in labor productivity only to the
extent that the price indexes used reflect a procedure that picks up
changes in the mix of employee skills. For example, the indexes that
include Federal employee compensation reflect changes in the skill mix
estimated by taking into account changes over time in the level of
experience and education. Consistent with NIPA practice, the estimates
do not include any additional, specific adjustment, such as an assumed
rate of increase in labor productivity based on observations in related
fields.
Ideally, the same breakdowns available for current-dollar
expenditures would be prepared in constant dollars--that is, by funder
and by type as well as by performer. However, because most performers
have multiple sources of funding and because all groups of performers do
at least some of each type Of R&D, more detail on cost components is
necessary to deflate R&D by funder or type. It is possible that
constant-dollar estimates by funder could be derived by allocating cost
components in the cases for which performer and funder do not coincide.
Deriving constant-dollar estimates by type Of R&D will be more
problematic.
Stocks OFR&D Capital
It is generally agreed that stocks of intangible capital, such as
R&D, are best obtained by cumulating investment flows rather than
surveying stocks directly. BEA's review of the methods available
led to reliance on the following three elements: (1) The performer
breakdown currently available for constant-dollar R&D investment;
(2) BEA's current methodology for fixed reproducible tangible
capital stocks; and (3) uniform service lives for an R&D capital.
The resulting R&D capital stock estimates are the first ones that
are fully consistent with BEA's estimates of tangible capital.
Scope Of R&D capital.--Some researchers have questioned whether
expenditures on all types of R&D and in all fields should be treated
as capital formation. Some have excluded basic research because they
view it as being undertaken for the purpose of improving understanding
of the world and not for the purpose of increasing productivity or
adding to production.(19) Other researchers have excluded specific
fields of research--for example, defense or space R&D--because they
view those fields as having little applicability to commercial
production.(20) Alternatively, if R&D is regarded solely, as an
input to the production process, comparable to the blueprints for a new
building, only businesses' development expenditures for commercial
applications might be included. Some researchers, particularly those who
have constructed a broadened view of investment and wealth, have
included all R&D.(21) Including all types of R&D in all fields,
as the satellite account does, is consistent with a view Of R&D as a
new kind of wealth. Ideally, an R&D satellite account would publish
R&D capital stocks showing detailed information that would allow
users of the account to decide which categories Of R&D to include or
exclude, depending on their use of the estimates, but the satellite
account does not yet do so.
Others have questioned whether all R&D, both successful and
unsuccessful, should be treated as capital formation.(22) The R&D
satellite account is consistent in this respect with the existing NIPA
treatment of mineral exploration expenditures, which are all treated as
investment in line with the view that returns from the successes are
sufficient overall to pay for the failures.
Allocation Of R&D capital and consumption of fixed capital-in
doing analytical work on R&D, some researchers have allocated most
R&D capital financed by government and by nonprofit institutions to
the business sector.(23) The Congressional Budget Office allocated all
R&D to the economy at large.(24) In a more general setting, most
presentations of capital stocks, including BEA's fixed reproducible
tangible wealth, are on an ownership basis, allocating stocks to the
sectors that own them.
For R&D capital in the satellite account, an allocation by
funder would be closer to an ownership basis than an allocation by
performer. However, the constant-dollar estimates Of R&D
expenditures by funder needed to prepare the capital stocks by funder
will require additional work (see the section "Future
Directions"). The R&D satellite account thus allocates the
total R&D capital stock on the basis of performer to private and
government components. Similarly, the consumption of fixed capital is
allocated on the basis of performer.
Timing.--R&D projects typically take more than a year from the
time they are started until their results are embedded in new knowledge
or in new processes or products. Researchers have identified two types
of lags: Gestation lags and applications lags. Gestation lags refer to
the time needed to complete an R&D project. Applications lags refer
to the time between completion of the R&D and its initial commercial
use. The sum of the two lags yields the time needed for R&D
investments to increase the stocks of knowledge that are actually being
used. Survey-based research has found that gestation lags range from 1
to 2 years and that applications lags range from somewhat less than 1
year to somewhat more than 2 years.(25) Researchers have also studied
the total lag between R&D and its peak effects on productivity or
profits.(26) They have generally found long lags, particularly for basic
research, because most new products and processes that result from
R&D are adopted only gradually.
The R&D satellite account only needs to take into account the
gestation lag, which is assumed to be 1 year. However, because the U.S.
economic accounts measure production at the time that capital and labor
are used in the production process, the gestation lag means that another
category of output--R&D inventories--must be introduced. These
inventories are the equivalent of work-in-progress for some tangible
fixed capital goods whose production requires more than one time period.
R&D inventories are converted to stocks Of R&D intangible fixed
capital at the end of the gestation lag.
Depreciation patterns and rates.--Some researchers have treated some,
or all, capital created by R&D as immortal--that is, as a permanent
part of the capital stock once it is added.(27) Other researchers have
assumed that once R&D capital has entered the capital stock, it is
gradually removed by depreciation--or, more formally, in economic
accounting terms, by consumption of fixed capital. They used a variety
of patterns and rates of depreciation.(28) In the satellite account,
R&D is assumed to depreciate over a finite lifespan. The
depreciation is due to obsolescence as knowledge from newer R&D
supplants the knowledge from older R&D, or as applied R&D
produces newer processes and products that supplant older ones. (For
those who wish to treat R&D capital as immortal, the satellite
account includes supplemental series that show cumulative R&D
expenditures since 1929.)
The choice of a depreciation pattern for R&D stocks is of
necessity somewhat arbitrary. There are no R&D capital markets to
provide information on the value of "used" R&D. A study of
patent renewal rates in several European countries was inconclusive; its
findings could support assumptions about the pattern of depreciation
ranging from geometric to slower-then-faster-than-straight-line.(29)
In the R&D satellite account, the stock of R&D capital is
constructed using the same methodology that is currently used to
construct BEA's estimates of fixed reproducible tangible capital:
The perpetual inventory method is used with uniform average service
lives, straight-line depreciation, and a bell-shaped distribution within
each vintage of capital to determine discards. The current-dollar stock
Of R&D is measured at replacement cost rather than at historical
cost.(30)
Empirical estimates have been made using geometric depreciation
patterns. Among more recent studies, Ariel Pakes and Mark Schankerman
found rates of 0.11 to 0.12 per year in some countries, but they
reported estimates of 0.17 to 0.26 in the United Kingdom.(31) James
Adams estimated depreciation rates of 0.09 to 0.13 for basic
research.(32) M. Ishaq Nadiri and Ingmar Prucha estimated a rate Of 0.12
for industrial R&D.(33)
The R&D satellite account uses the straight-line lifespan that
corresponds most closely to a geometric depreciation of o.11 per year, a
rate chosen because it is near the center of a plausible range of rates.
This straight-line average service life is i8 years. A study that
compared R&D net capital stocks estimated using an 18-year average
service life with alternative estimates made using geometric
depreciation and a rate of depreciation of 0.11 per year revealed only
modest differences that exhibited no particular time trends.
Estimates Of R&D Flows and Stocks
Table B summarizes some results from the R&D satellite account.
It shows the following:
[TABULAR DATA OMITTED]
* Industry has performed two-thirds or more Of R&D for the last
40 years.
* The Federal Government has funded a large, but declining, share
Of R&D. The decline was steep after 1987.
* By 1992, basic research was 17 percent of all R&D, almost
double its 196o share. The offsetting decline was in development, which
was 59 percent of all R&D in 1992. The share of applied research has
changed little.
* R&D funded by government and nonprofit institutions was equal
to 1.2 percent Of GDP in 1992, and R&D funded by industry was equal
to 1.7 percent. Since 1960, the sum of the two has ranged from 2.2
percent in 1978 to 2.9 percent in the mid-1960's, in 1985, and in
1992.
* Constant-dollar expenditures increased at an average annual rate
of over 7 percent from 1953 to 1968. Constant-dollar expenditures then
leveled off for nearly a decade before resuming an uptrend, but at a
more moderate rate.
* With lags and moving more smoothly, the constant-cost R&D net
fixed capital stock mirrored the pattern of constant-dollar
expenditures. In 1992, R&D capital would have added almost 9 percent
to the net wealth of government and business.
* The average age of the constant-cost R&D gross fixed stock, a
rough indicator of the age of the knowledge in the stock, increased from
about 6.5 years in 196o to a high of 8.9 years in 198o. It then
decreased to 8.2 years in 1992.
The tables that make up the R&D satellite account are in five
groups. The tables numbered 1 are summary tables that present
expenditures and investment for 1953-92, and stocks for 1959-92, in
current dollars (or at current cost) and in constant dollars (or at
constant cost)--tables 1.1 and 1.2, respectively. The tables numbered 2
present expenditures in current dollars by performer, by funder, and by
type. The tables numbered 3 present estimates by industry in current
dollars. The tables numbered 4 present constant-dollar expenditures,
including expenditures by performing industry along with the number of
scientists and engineers by industry. The tables numbered 5 present
implicit price deflators.
Current-dollar R&D expenditures
Table 2.1 shows R&D expenditures by performer, and within each
performer, by source of funds. Chart i, which is based on this table,
shows shares Of R&D expenditures by performer for 1992. Industry,
with expenditures of $119.5 billion, was the largest performer Of
R&D, accounting for 71 percent of total R&D expenditures. It has
maintained at least a two-thirds share for most of the last 40 years.
Public and private universities and colleges combined, with $18.9
billion, were the second largest performers of R&D. The Federal
Government followed with $16.3 billion. Expenditures on R&D
activities performed within the Federal Government, which had a share of
23 percent in 1953, had a 10-percent share in 1992. The combined
expenditures for R&D performed by State and local governments,
nonprofit institutions, and FFRDC's--at $14.6 billion--accounted
for the remaining share of 9 percent.
[TABULAR DATA OMITTED]
For 1992, the Federal Government, in addition to funding all the
R&D it performs, funded a majority of the R&D performed by
universities and colleges (59 percent), FFRDC's (99 percent), and
other nonprofit institutions (57 percent). However, the share of R&D
funded by the Federal Government has declined steadily over time.
Industry and State and local governments fund most of their own R&D
work, 81 percent and 71 percent, respectively.
Table 2.2 shows R&D expenditures by source of funds, and within
each source, by performer. Five sources of funds are shown in the
R&D satellite account: Industry, the Federal Government, State and
local governments, private universities and colleges, and
"other." Because of data limitations, some small flows are
combined with the major sources of funding; for example, industry's
funding Of R&D performed by industry includes funds from the rest of
the world, because this funding source cannot be separately identified.
[TABULAR DATA OMITTED]
Chart 1 also shows shares Of R&D expenditures by source of
funds for 1992. Industry, providing $99.4 billion, is the largest source
Of R&D funds, with a 59-percent share. The Federal Government,
providing $6i.2 billion, is the second largest source. Together, these
two sources provided 95 percent, or $160.8 billion, of the total spent
on R&D in 1992. Over the 40-year period covered by the satellite
account, these two sources of funds have always accounted for most
R&D expenditures, but the shares of the two have changed over time.
The Federal Government's share reached a high of 67 percent in 1964
and fell to 36 percent in 1992. By contrast, the industry share of
R&D funding has steadily increased over time.
Tables 2.3 and 2.4 show R&D expenditures as the sum of
expenditures on the three types of R&D--basic research, applied
research, and development. Chart 1 also shows shares Of R&D
expenditures by type for 1992. Development, at $99.8 billion, is over
half the total (59 percent). Applied research, with $40.2 billion, or a
24-percent share, is less than half as large. Basic research, at $29.3
billion, is 17 percent of the total. The share of basic research has
increased steadily: By 1992, it had almost doubled its 1960 share. The
increases in the share of basic research were offset by declines in
development. The share of applied research has remained steady.
[TABULAR DATA OMITTED]
Basic research is increasingly being performed at universities and
colleges: In 1953, universities and colleges performed less than 30
percent of basic research; by 1992, they performed over 40 percent of
it. Most applied R&D is performed by industry. Industry currently
performs over two-thirds of applied research and well over 80 percent of
development. The Federal Government performs about 10 percent of applied
R&D.
Table 3.1 shows expenditures by major R&D performing
industries.(34) Manufacturing industries are shown at the two-digit
standard industrial classification, except that transportation equipment
is split into "aircraft and missiles" and "other
transportation equipment" because the share of federally funded
R&D in the former is, so large. All nonmanufacturing R&D
expenditures are combined.
[TABULAR DATA OMITTED]
Expenditures on R&D performed by industry were $122.3 billion
in 1992. Until 1992, the aircraft and missile industry consistently had
the largest R&D expenditures, with a peak of $24.6 billion in 1987.
In 1992, chemicals and allied products took top ranking, with
expenditures of $16.8 billion. These two industries were followed by
industrial machinery, electronic and other electrical equipment, and
other transportation equipment. The nonmanufacturing industries,
continuing a sharp uptrend, had R&D expenditures of $30.4 billion.
(Nonmanufacturing industries include communication services; computer
programming, data processing, other computer-related engineering,
architectural, and surveying services; and research, development, and
testing laboratories.
The federally funded share of industry R&D has been steadily
declining over the last 30 years, from a high Of 59 percent in 1959 to a
low of 2o percent in 1992. The Federal share has shrunk rapidly since
the mid-1980's, particularly in the aircraft and missiles industry.
Federal funding accounted for 6i percent of funding in this industry in
1992, down from 76 percent in 1987. When Federal funding is removed, the
aircraft and missile industry drops from second place to sixth place
($6.3 billion). Chemicals and allied products led non-federally funded
manufacturing R&D performance with expenditures of $16.5 billion.
Nonmanufacturing industries, continuing a sharp uptrend, reached $24.4
billion in non-federally funded R&D.
Table 3.2 shows company-funded R&D expenditures performed
outside the United States by U.S. companies and their foreign
subsidiaries. The chemicals and allied products industry is the leader,
with expenditures of $2.7 billion, in 1992. This industry accounted for
28 percent of the 1992 industry-funded expenditures of foreign
subsidiaries.
[TABULAR DATA OMITTED]
Constant-dollar R&D expenditures
Table 4.1 shows R&D expenditures by performer in constant
dollars. Total R&D expenditures grew at an average annual rate of
7.3 percent in 1953-68. (Over much of the period, Federal spending on
defense-related and space R&D increased sharply. Expenditures then
leveled off for nearly a decade, with an average decline of 1.3 percent
in 1968-75. An uptrend then resumed, but at a more moderate rate; the
average annual rate of increase in 1975-92 was 4.0 percent. (During this
period, R&D spent on energy, following the 1973 oil embargo, and on
health stepped up. Chart 2 presents expenditures by performer group.
Expenditure patterns have been similar for each of the groups performing
R&D. Expenditures increased steadily until the late 1960's,
leveled off or declined somewhat for a decade, and, except for Federal
performance, then increased through 1992. Federal performance has been
flat since the late 1980's.
Table 4.2 shows constant-dollar expenditures by industry (including
FFRDC'S administered by industry). The recent growth in R&D
expenditures for industry has been uneven. From 1987 tO 1992, real
R&D performed by industry increased at an average annual rate of 2.1
percent; however, 7 of the 14 industry groups had declining R&D
expenditures during this period. The fastest rates of decline were in
stone, clay, and glass products and in aircraft and missiles. The
fastest growth has been in nonmanufacturing, which tripled its R&D
expenditures between 1987 and 1992.
Table 4.3 shows the number of R&D scientists and engineers by
industry, an additional input series. Like the constant-dollar
expenditure series, it abstracts from price change over time, but it is
narrower in coverage than expenditures. From 1987 to 1992, the picture
of uneven growth across industry groups seen in the constant-dollar
estimates is also seen in the number of scientists and engineers. Again,
the fastest growth is in nonmanufacturing, but the number of scientists
and engineers doubled rather than tripling as the constant-dollar
expenditures did.
Tables 5.1 and 5.2 show implicit price deflators (IPD'S) for
each of the performers. IPD's are constructed to derive
constant-dollar estimates; the overall IPD for R&D is a byproduct of
the constant-dollar estimates.(35) The IPD'S of most performers do
not greatly differ from the IPD for total R&D, which grew at an
average annual rate of 3.7 percent during 1987-92. Notable exceptions
are universities and colleges and FFRDC'S. During 1987-92, the
IPD's for private and public universities and colleges grew at
average annual rates of 5.9 percent and 5.8 percent, respectively. On
the other end of the scale, the IPD'S for FFRDC'S administered
by nonprofit institutions and by governments grew at average annual
rates of 2.5 percent and 2.6 percent, respectively.
Stock of R&D capital
Investment, consumption of R&D Capital, and gross and net stocks
are shown in tables 1.1 and 1.2 in current dollars and in constant
dollars, respectively. Stocks and consumption of R&D Capital are not
shown prior to 1959, because the perpetual inventory method for deriving
R&D net fixed intangible capital stock would require additional
years of constant-dollar investment data, which are not available.
In 1992, constant-dollar fixed tangible investment was $725
billion; the constant-cost net stock of fixed reproducible tangible
capital of government and business (including nonprofit institutions)
was $12,020 billion. Adding constant-dollar R&D fixed intangible
investment would increase fixed investment by 19 percent, or $140
billion; adding the resulting R&D Stock would increase the
constant-cost net stock of fixed reproducible capital by almost 9
percent, or $1,049 billion.
Chart 3 compares the constant-cost net stock of R&D fixed
capital with the constant-cost net stock of fixed reproducible tangible
capital of government and business. The chart shows that while the
constant-cost fixed reproducible tangible capital stock grew rather
steadily from 1959 to 1992 (left scale), the stock of R&D capital
grew rapidly until 1970, slowed sharply from 1970 to 1981, and then grew
somewhat more rapidly thereafter (right scale). The ratio of the R&D
stock to the fixed reproducible tangible stock increased sharply until
1970, fell until 1981, and has increased thereafter.
The average age of the R&D gross fixed intangible capital
stock, a rough indicator of the age of the knowledge in the stock, is a
byproduct of the perpetual inventory method. As shown in the addenda to
table 1.2, the average age of the total constant-cost gross R&D
stock increased from about 6-. years in 196o to a high of 8.9 years in
198o, then deceased to 8.2 years in 1992. The age of private stock,
which makes up about three-quarters of the total stock, showed a very
similar pattern. The age of the government stock started higher, at
almost 8 years, decreased about half a year over the decade to 1970, and
then increased to 9 years at the end of the 1980's; it stood at 8.8
years in 1992.
Future Directions
The R&D satellite account now presents basic information about
R&D--the value of its production by performer, by funder, and by
type in current dollars and by performer in constant dollars--and treats
the expenditures that measure that production as investment to obtain a
stock of R&D fixed intangible capital. Future work could proceed in
several directions: Rounding out the view of R&D within an economic
accounting framework, refining the existing estimates and providing
additional information, and enhancing the international comparability of
the satellite account presentation of R&D. Rounding out the economic
accounting view of R&D.-- The satellite account presents the total
value of R&D produced in the United States by adjusting the best
available source of information about R&D to prepare estimates
consistent with the NIPA'S. The restructured GDP that is implied is
shown as follows:
Personal consumption expenditures
Less: Expenditures on R&D
Plus: Consumption of fixed R&D capital Gross domestic
investment
Gross fixed investment
Tangible fixed investment
R&D fixed investment Change in inventories
Business tangible inventories
R&D inventories Net exports of goods and services Government
purchases
Less: Expenditures on R&D
Plus: Consumption of fixed R&D capital
Nonprofit institution and government expenditures on R&D are
subtracted from personal consumption expenditures and government
purchases, respectively. Those expenditures are added to business
expenditures on R&D to obtain total R&D investment, split as
described earlier between fixed investment and change in inventories.
(The term "tangible" is introduced to distinguish investment
in the existing accounts from R&D.) Consumption of fixed R&D
Capital is allocated to nonprofit institutions and to government;
consumption of fixed R&D capital allocated to business does not
appear because it is intermediate consumption. GDP is increased by the
addition of business expenditure on R&D (which had been intermediate
consumption) and the addition of the difference between expenditures on
R&D and the consumption of fixed R&D capital that is included in
personal consumption expenditures and in government purchases.
This view of the production of R&D is useful, but could be more
fully rounded out within an economic accounting framework. To do so
within the national income and product (NIP) account--the first of the
five accounts in the NIPA summary set of accounts--would call for
identifying components on the product and income sides of the NIP
account that include subcomponents that relate to R&D. For example,
tangible investment indudes investment that provides the capital used to
produce R&D, and identifying that investment within the total may be
useful. Rounding out the treatment in the NIP account would lead to
changes in the other four accounts of the NIPA summary set. In
particular, the gross saving and investment account would reflect
changes in the coverage of investment, consumption of fixed capital, and
sector saving.
Further, the investment allocated to government and nonprofit
institutions might be expected to have a net return (over and above
costs, such as consumption of fixed capital) that would appear both on
the product (or expenditure) side of the account and on the income side.
At present, the NIPA'S do not include such a return for nonprofit
institutions' investment, and they do not treat any government
expenditure as investment (so that there is no return to be considered).
However, BEA, as part of an ongoing modernization of the accounts, is
considering treating government expenditures on structures and durable
equipment as investment, and a major issue is whether a net return on
the capital created should be estimated. Especially if a net return is
calculated for government fixed reproducible tangible capital, the
R&D satellite account should be brought into line to have a
consistent treatment for all government capital.
These points are raised within the context of the existing
NIPA'S and the associated capital stock estimates. However, BEA is
reviewing the appropriateness of the concepts and methods underlying its
capital stock estimates, and future estimates may be based on somewhat
different concepts and measurement methods.(36) In keeping with the
approach of constructing the R&D satellite account measures to be
consistent with the more general measures with which they might be used
and compared, the satellite account measures could change also. Further,
as the U.S. accounts are modernized along the lines of the international
guidelines in the System of National Accounts 1993, further
modifications might be made. Refining the estimates.--Refining the
estimates and providing additional breakdowns would strengthen the
satellite account. R&D expenditures funded by the Federal Government
by agency would provide a proxy for a partial breakdown of R&D by
purpose. This breakdown also could lead to a defense-nondefense split;
the defense portion would include both purchases of contractual R&D
and R&D performed inhouse. Such additional detail could be expected
to be of wide interest and also improve the NIPA estimates.
Sources of data on R&D Other than NSF have the potential of
improving the accuracy of the estimates and of facilitating the
provision of additional information. One possibility is that other
sources of R&D data could be used to supplement the information from
NSF'S surveys. These sources could be useful, for example, in
developing the analytically interesting but difficult breakdowns by
purpose or region. For example, health-related R&D, by all
performers, might be separately identified. Another possibility is that
BEA'S survey data on direct investment--foreign direct investment
in the United States and U.S. direct investment abroad--and on
international trade in services could be further mined for information
about international R&D expenditure flows. Because the knowledge
gained from R&D iS highly mobile internationally, and because there
is some evidence that the internationalization of R&D is
intensifying, there is substantial interest in tracing the flows.
Further work to refine the deflation of R&D could yield
constant-dollar estimates by source of funding and by type of R&D.
These constant-dollar estimates would yield, in turn, R&D capital
stocks that would allow users to examine whether R&D capital from
different sources of funding have different effects. For example, this
refinement would allow further examination of the finding by some
analysts that government-funded R&D has different effects on
productivity than other R&D. Similarly, stocks of R&D capital by
type would allow the examination of whether the different types have
effects on productivity with different time patterns. International
comparability.--Because of the substantial interest in comparing R&D
across countries, several strands of work in the international area
could contribute to, and benefit from, the U.S. R&D satellite
account. First, further work on R&D and other forms of intangible
capital formation and capital stock is on the research agenda that
emerged from the preparation of the System of National Accounts 1993.
This work might lead to some useful standardization on aspects for which
empirical work is not likely to lead to firm answers--for example, on
the issue of longevity of basic research capital. Second, several
international classifications that identify purpose, or function, are to
be completed or updated in the future. One of the specific goals of the
work is to include R&D--for example, in the classification of
functions for government and for nonprofit institutions. The
classification work is likely to draw upon the Frascati Manual Third, as
noted earlier, several countries prepare or are exploring the
preparation of R&D satellite accounts.
In looking to the future of BIBA'S R&D satellite account,
it is especially fitting to note that satellite accounts are sometimes
called economic accountants' laboratories. The work in these
laboratories--both in the United States, reflecting comments from users
and BEA'S experience, and abroad--can be expected to add to
knowledge. This knowledge, combined with resources, would help set a
course for future improvements.
Technical Note
This note provides additional information about the construction of
the R&D satellite account. It covers the sources of data, estimating
methods, and assumptions used to construct the three major segments of
the account: Current-dollar expenditures, constant-dollar expenditures,
and. current-cost and constant-cost gross and net capital stocks.
Because the R&D satellite account is designed to supplement the U.S.
economic accounts, the methods used to estimate R&D FLOWS and stocks
are consistent with those used to construct the U.S. national income and
product accounts (NIPA's) and the associated estimates of capital
stocks. As it does with other estimates, BEA has modified available
source data to tailor them to the statistical and conceptual
requirements of the account.
Current-dollar expenditures
The estimates of R&D expenditures are largely based on, or are
extensions of, data that began in 1953 from four annual surveys
published by the National Science Foundation (NSF): Federal Funds for
Research and Development, Federal Support to Universities, Colleges, and
Selected Nonprofit Institutions, Academic Science and Engineering.
R&D Expenditures, and Research and Development in Industry.(37) The
two Federal surveys are universe surveys, the academic survey is close
to a universe survey, and the industry survey uses a sample that is
redrawn every 5 years.(38) The surveys are intended to cover an formal
R&D activities, not just the activities assigned to separate R&D
units.
The first survey measures obligations and outlays by Federal
agency, and the second survey measures obligations by Federal agency.
The last two surveys measure expenditures. These survey measures differ
with respect to the kind of information they collect about the tangible
capital used in performing R&D. For example, the two Federal surveys
include a separate measure of tangible capital spending, but exclude its
depreciation. The academic and industry surveys do not include a
separate measure of capital spending, but include its depreciation as an
unidentifiable part of overhead costs. All of these measures are broken
down by type of R&D, and each survey includes at least some
geographic detail. In addition, the industry survey provides tabulations
of the net sales of R&D performing companies and the
full-time-equivalent number of industry R&D scientists and
engineers.
Data from surveys of State and local R&D expenditures and of
nonprofit institution R&D eXpenditures, published occasionally by
NSF, were also used.(39) These data were interpolated and extrapolated
to obtain estimates for missing, years. Performer-based estimates.--The
R&D satellite account features estimates of R&D expenditures
that are largely based on data reported by performers of the R&D
rather than by funders of the R&D. This approach attempts to avoid
at least two problems. First, the data reported by funders would have to
be adjusted to convert them from a time-of-payment-to-the-performer
basis to a time-of-expenditure-by-the-performer basis in order to be
consistent with the timing with which purchases of goods and services
are generally recorded in the NIPA'S. Second, the data reported by
funders would have to be adjusted to avoid double-counting. Otherwise,
R&D that is subcontracted would be counted twice--once by the
primary source of funding and once by the secondary source of funding
that subcontracted the R&D.
Expenditures for R&D performed by industry, by public and
private universities and colleges, and by academically administered,
federally funded research and development centers (FFRDC'S) are
prepared from data reported by R&D performers. In recent years,
these performers have accounted for roughly 85 percent of all R&D
expenditures. For the remaining 15 percent, performer reports are not
available, and expenditures are based on data reported by funders.
Adjustments to the survey data.--BEA adjusts the survey-based data to
make them conceptually and statistically consistent with the
Nipa's. The adjustments raised the level of current-dollar
expenditures, on average, 2.5 percent in 1953-92; in 1987-92, the
adjustments raised the level somewhat less, an average of 1.5 percent.
The four major types of adjustments to the NSF survey data are
summarized in table C.
[TABULAR DATA C OMITTED]
First, BEA adjusts the R&D expenditures from NSF surveys to
obtain consumption of fixed tangible capital used in performing R&D.
Two methods are used, depending on the handling of this capital in the
surveys. For the Federal Government and for State and local governments,
BEA removes expenditures on fixed reproducible tangible
capital--structures and equipment--and adds an estimate of the
consumption of that capital based on BEA'S perpetual inventory
methodology. For other performers, BEA converts the depreciation implied
in the R&D survey (part of overhead) to a basis that reflects the
valuation and consistency (for example, of service lives) appropriate
for economic accounts.
To make the conversion for private and public universities and
colleges and for FFRDC'S administered by universities and colleges,
an estimate of expenditures on R&D structures and equipment is made
as a first step. Equipment is then split between capital equipment and
expensed "research" equipment. (Research equipment is
purchased by the academic institution from current fund accounts. Next,
the implied depreciation of structures and capital equipment is
calculated using the depreciation patterns and the service lives
prescribed for NSF reporting purposes. This implied depreciation and the
expenditures on research equipment are then subtracted from reported
R&D expenditures. Finally, BEA'S estimate of consumption of
structures and equipment, which is estimated using BEA'S perpetual
inventory methodology and the same service lives used in preparing fixed
tangible capital stocks, is added back in; it is valued at current cost.
To make the conversion for industry performers, the information on
capital expenditures needed to develop an estimate of implied
depreciation is not available. BEA developed estimates based on the 1958
survey-based depreciation reported by NSP and the 1982 depreciation
charges of R&D auxiliaries from the Bureau of the Census 1982
Enterprise Statistics [6]. For each industry, the depreciation is
converted to an economic basis using the ratios of historical-cost to
current-cost valuation from the estimates of academic expenditures
described above.
Second, two timing adjustments are made. Data from the Federal
Government are on a fiscal year basis, and data from universities and
colleges are on an academic year basis. These data are converted to a
calendar year basis by using weighted averages of adjacent years.
Federal obligations by performer--for example, contracts awarded or
other binding commitments made that will require outlays--are converted
to expenditures using statistically estimated phasing patterns prepared
by BEA.
Third, data from the academic surveys are adjusted to exclude
R&D performed in geographic areas--primarily U.S. territories and
possessions--that are not included in the NIPA'S. Because these
academic surveys tabulate expenditures by individual school or FFRDC,
these expenditures could be removed.
In the fourth adjustment, BEA developed R&D, expenditure
estimates for industries and years that had been suppressed by NSF in
order to avoid disclosure of confidential information from the industry
survey. The BEA estimates are based on statistical techniques (primarily
interpolations), on fragmentary data from other sources, and on
judgment; they do not disclose confidential company data.
Backward extensions of the survey data.--In order to develop the
necessary statistical foundation to construct capital stock estimates
using the perpetual inventory method, BEA prepared estimates of R&D
expenditures for years prior to 1953, when the NSF surveys began. Using
various data sources, BEA extended the R&D expenditure estimates
back to 1920. Estimates of R&D expenditures are not made for years
before 1920, because little information is available; it is assumed that
R&D expenditures before 1920 were quite small.
The BEA estimates of expenditures by R&D performers for 1920-52
are made using a methodology generally similar to that described by John
Kendrick.(40) First, expenditures are established for benchmark years.
Benchmark years are 1921, 1930, 1940, and 1951 for total R&D
expenditures and 1921, 1927, 1931, 1933, 1938, 1940) 1946, and 1951 for
industry R&D, and the expenditures are from Nestor Terleckyj.(41)
Expenditures in the non-benchmark years in 1920-41 are estimated by
interpolation or extrapolation, using estimates of R&D reported by
Vannevar Bush as indicators when available.(42) Expenditures for
nonbenchmark years in 1942-52 are estimated using data published by the
Research and Development Board.(43)
The BEA estimates for 1920-52 are supplemented in two ways.
Expenditures for FFRDC'S, from their inception in 1942, are based
on data published in a study by the Denver Research Institute.(44)
Expenditures on the Manhattan project (which developed the first atomic
bomb) for 1942-46 are based on data reported by Richard Hewlett and
Oscar Anderson, Jr.(45) At its peak in 1944, the Manhattan project
accounted for nearly one-tenth of all R&D performed in the United
States.
Issues with R&D by funder and by type.--As discussed above, the
basic framework for the R&D satellite account iS R&D arrayed by
performer. In addition, R&D is shown broken down by source of
funding and by type.
In the R&D satellite account, a maximum of five sources of
funding are distinguished: Federal Government, State and local
governments, industry, universities and colleges, and other (which
includes nonprofit institutions and foreign sources). The satellite
account shows less source-of-funding detail for some performers because
of varying source data. For example, three sources of funding are
distinguished for R&D performed by industry (see table 2.1),
although industry source data divide R&D performed into only two
funding categories--Federal funds and all other, funds. Within the other
funds category, BEA estimated State and local government funding using
data from surveys of State and local R&D. BEA assumed that the
funding of industry R&D from universities and colleges and from
other nonprofit institutions is negligible and that foreign funding is
small enough so that the remainder of industry R&D funding could be
labeled "from industry."
The breakdowns by type embody substantial uncertainty. Because
there are no clear-cut distinctions between the types, uncertainties
must be resolved by the judgment of the survey respondents. It is
unlikely that these resolutions will be the same among reporting groups.
For example, academic respondents may be less likely to report research
as applied or development. In addition, the breakdowns by type are
voluntary on industry and academic surveys, and not all surveys ask for
the full three-way breakdown.
Constant-dollar expenditures
Table D provides an overview of the source data and methods used in
deriving constant-donar R&D expenditures. For each group of
performers, constant-dollar expenditures are calculated by dividing
current-dollar expenditures by price deflators at the most detailed cost
level available. Constant-dollar estimates begin in 1929, the year NIPA
price indexes become available. The methodology of using cost components
that are matched with existing indexes builds on both existing BEA work
and work done by others--most notably John Jankowski of NSF and Edwin
Mansfield of the University of Pennsylvania for industry R&D
expenditures and D. Kent Halstead of Research Associates of Washington
for academic R&D expenditures.(46)
[TABULAR DATA D OMITTED]
Typically, the cost components are compensation of employees,
materials and supplies, and overhead. Data used for deflation include
information on prices paid by the Federal Government, the NIPA price
index for noncommercial research organizations, the producer price index
for industrial commodities published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), average hourly earnings and median weekly salaries of managers
and administrators from BLS, annual mean salaries of engineers from the
Engineering Manpower Commission, component price indexes from the
National Institute of Health's biomedical R&D price index, and
higher education price indexes published by Research Associates of
Washington.47 The base year is 1987, for which each price index is set
equal to 100.
Capital stocks
R&D investment is broken into two components--fixed investment
and change in R&D inventories. In the R&D satellite account, it
is assumed that expenditures on R&D are inventoried for 1 year
before they are included in R&D fixed capital in order to allow for
the time needed to complete R&D projects. When measured in constant
dollars, R&D fixed investment is equal to the R&D expenditures
for the preceding year, and for each year, the change in R&D
inventories is equal to the change in R&D expenditures. Because the
beginning and ending inventory levels reflect different price levels,
current-dollar R&D inventories from the end of the preceding year
are revalued to correspond to the prices for the current year by using
an inventory valuation adjustment.(48)
R&D fixed capital stocks are constructed using the methods BEA
uses to construct capital stocks associated with the NIPA'S,
including the same perpetual inventory method that is used for gross and
net stocks of fixed reproducible tangible capital. Thus, the estimates
of fixed intangible R&D capital are comparable with those of fixed
reproducible tangible capital.
With the perpetual inventory method, the gross capital stock for a
given period is obtained by cumulating past investment and deducting the
cumulated value of investment that has been discarded, using estimated
average service lives and retirement patterns.(49) The gross stock of
fixed capital is a measure of the cumulative value of past investment
still in existence, The net capital stock is equal to the gross stock
less the accumulated depreciation on the assets in the gross stock.
The perpetual inventory method used by BEA is based on uniform
service lives, straight-line depreciation, and replacement cost. To
adjust for varying retirement patterns, discards (retirement years) are
based on a Winfrey S-3 distribution, which is a bell-shaped distribution
around the expected service life of the R&D capital. Discards of
capital begin as early as 45 percent of, and end as late as 155 percent
of, the average lifespan.
In deciding how to apply its methodology to R&D, BEA examined
several alternative depreciation patterns and performed sensitivity
studies. Geometric depreciation is the pattern typically used in R&D
studies, and a rate of 11 percent per year for R&D fixed capital is
a plausible midpoint of a range published by academic researchers. (Some
recent studies had estimates that ranged from 9 to 13 percent per year
and tended to concentrate near 11 percent.) BEA'S studies showed
that using a depreciation rate for R&D fixed capital of 12 percent
yielded a real stock of R&D capital for 1991 that was $65 billion
lower (1987 dollars) than a stock constructed using a rate of 11
percent. Using a rate of 10 percent yielded a real stock of R&D
capital that was $74 billion higher. Regardless of which rates are used,
the general patterns Of R&D stock are similar over time.
Because BEA currently uses the straight-line perpetual inventory
method for fixed tangible capital, an average service life for R&D
capital was chosen that yields a net stock comparable to a net stock
from a geometric depreciation rate of 11 percent; an 18-year service
life for straightline depreciation yields the closest match. The gross
and net stocks constructed in the account for 1959-92 are based on
current- and constant-dollar R&D investment for 1930-91.
As with the constant-dollar expenditure estimates, constant-cost
net and gross stocks are expressed in 1987 prices. Net and gross stocks
valued at replacement cost are constructed by multiplying the
constant-cost stocks by the corresponding R&D implicit price
deflator.
RELATED ARTICLE: Acknowledgments
This article was written by Carol S. Carson, Bruce T. Grimm, and
Carol E. Moylan. Carol E. Moylan led the team, which included Chris W.
Garner and Bruce T. Grimm, that prepared the estimates. The project was
under the general direction of Carol S. Carson. The project depended to
an unusually large extent on staff members throughout BEA whose areas of
expertise coincided with the methodologies or components incorporated in
the satellite account. In addition, Robert Eisner, of Northwestern
University, played an instrumental role in the initial stages of the
project. BEA also acknowledges the many outside experts who provided
advice and data. In particular, the staff of the Division of Science
Resources Studies of the National Science Foundation was very helpful in
providing most of the source data that underlie the account; John Gawalt
served as the principal contact, and John Jankowski provided especially
helpful advice on making estimates to supplement the survey data.
RELATED ARTICLE: Comparison Of R&D Capital Stock Estimates
The accompanying table shows BEA's estimates of the total
R&D capital stock, and of selected components, together with
estimates that others have published. In addition, it shows an
alternative set Of BEA estimates that is based on 11-percent per year
geometric depreciation (rather than straight-line depreciation). The
upper panel of the table contains estimates Of R&D Stocks for
selected years. The lower panel shows BEA's estimates less the
estimates by others. The comparison should be viewed as rough, because
it was necessary to convert most of the other estimates to 1987 dollars
from other base periods by using the ratios Of BEA's R&D
deflator in various base years to its 1987 value of 100. Because of
weight shifts over time, the conversion factors yield only
approximations of what would be the actual values of rebased deflators.
The alternative BEA stock estimates are not very different from the
BEA estimates in the satellite account, and the two series show no
tendency to diverge over time. Estimates made by John Kendrick [32] are
increasingly higher than the BEA estimates over time. Estimates made by
Robert Eisner [24] begin slightly higher than the BEA estimates and
become increasingly higher over time. Estimates made by the Office of
Management and Budget (OMB)--which appeared in the Analytical
Perspectives volume of the fiscal year 1995 Budget of the United States
Government [40]--begin at about the same level and become increasingly
higher.
A major reason for these divergences is that BEA's methodology
depreciates basic research capital, while the others' methodologies
treat it as immortal and do not depreciate it. The rebasing of prices
may also explain some of the differences between the Kendrick and Eisner
estimates and the BEA estimates. Other differences result from different
methodologies for calculating depreciation and from the others' use
Of NSF estimates Of R&D expenditures rather than BEA's
estimates; Eisner's use of a 20-year life for other R&D capital
also contributed to the differences.
Estimates of the federally financed R&D capital stock made by
OMB are increasingly larger than those produced using a rough BEA
approximation of BEA's constant-dollar expenditures with geometric
depreciation. This divergence reflects OMB's assumption that basic
research capital is immortal. In addition, OMB's estimates assume a
10-percent rate of depreciation for other research, somewhat lower than
the 11-percent depreciation rate underlying BEA's alternative
estimates. Other differences arise because OMB Used Federal outlays on a
fiscal year basis, whereas BEA's estimates are primarily based on
performers' reports of expenditures on a calendar year basis.
Estimates of industry R&D capital stock from a study by the
Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) [11] are increasingly lower than the
corresponding BEA estimates from 1960 to 1965 and are roughly the same
amount lower thereafter. The principal reason for the lower values is
that the BLS study did not include development expenditures in their
capital formation estimates. Other differences arise from the BLS
study's assumption that basic research capital is immortal, its
lower--10 percent per year--rate of depreciation for applied research,
its longer gestation lags, and its different method of deflation.
Estimates of industry R&D capital stock made by Nadiri and
Prucha [38] are somewhat higher than BEA's corresponding estimates
for 1965. Thereafter, their estimated capital stocks grow a little more
slowly, on average, and are modestly lower in 1985. The initial
difference may be due to the assumed seed value that begins their
capital stock estimates. Thereafter, the slower growth reflects a
12-percent per year estimate for the rate of depreciation, somewhat
higher than BEA's effective rates of depreciation.
[TABULAR DATA OMITTED]
RELATED ARTICLE: Data Availability
A complete set of data in the R&D satellite account is
available on a microcomputer diskette. The data set includes the tables
published in the article, but for an years rather than just the selected
years shown in the article. The first year of data shown in most tables
is either 1953 or 1959, depending on the availability of source data.
The disk also includes supplemental tables.
The BEA accession number for the diskette, which is a 3 1/2-inch HD
diskette, is 53-94-40-001. Its price is $20.
For more information about the contents of the diskette, call Carol
Moylan at 202-606-9711 or Bruce Grimm at 202-606-9623. To order the
diskette using MasterCard or Visa, call BEA'S public information
office at 202-606-9900. To order by mail, write to the Public
Information Office, Order Desk, BE-53, Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S.
Department of Commerce, Washington, DC 20230. Specify the R&D
Satenite Account diskette, accession number, and its price, For foreign
shipment, add 25 Percent to the total amount of the order. A check or
money order payable to "Bureau of Economic Analysis" must
accompany all written orders. Be sure to include a return address.
(1.) National Science Board, National Science Foundation [39], page
89. (2) In an integrated set of economic accounts, flows of fixed
investment are viewed as forming stocks of reproducible capital. BEA
however, estimates the stocks of consumer durables and of government
equipment and structures as if personal consumption expenditures on
durable goods and government purchases of dumble goods and structures
had been treated as fixed investment flows. Flows derived from the NIPA
series are used to estimate the stocks, which are, therefore, consistent
with the NIPA'S. (3.) For an early presentation about the
preliminary work, see Carol Carson and Bruce Grimm [13]. (4.) See, for
example, National Science Board, National Science Foundation [39]. (5.)
See Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development [43], page
29. This is the fifth edition of the Frascati Manual. The manual was
first prepared in 1961. (6.) The definitions of R&D and the three
types of activities that are found elsewhere--for example, in financial
accounting standards and in NSF'S specific surveys--are similar to
these definitions but place emphasis on elements of the definitions that
are relevant to the context. (7.) See James Adams [1] and [2]. (8.) John
Kendrick 1331, PP. 79-81. (9.) See Eric Schiff [51], pp. 434-435 and
George Jaszi [31], PP. 454-455. (10.) See Nancy Ruggles and Richard
Ruggles [50], especially page 99. (11.) See John Kendrick [32],
especially pp. 1-21. (12.) See Robert Eisner [24], especially pp. 8-20.
(13.) See [52]. (14.) See System of National Accounts 1521, paragraph
6.163. (15.) See Michael Braibant [5]. (16.) See Fritz Bos, et. al. [4].
(17.) In BEA'S input-output accounts, neither current expenses nor
receipts for R&D are identified at the published level of detail. A
portion Of R&D iS identified at the level of detail at which the
estimates are prepared. (18.) See Nestor Terleckyj [54] and Vannevar
Bush (19.) See, for example, Federal Republic of Germany, Federal
Statistical Office [26]. (20.) See, for example, Zvi Griliches [28].
(21.) See, for example, John Kendrick [32]. (22.) Eric Schiff [51] and
Fritz Bos, et. al. [4]. (23.) See, for example, Robert Eisner [24] and
John Kendrick [32]. (24.) See Congressional Budget Office [14]. (25.)
See John Kendrick [32], John Rapoport [46], and Lenore Wagner [57].
(26.) See, for example, James Adams [1], James Adams and Leo Sveikauskas
[3], Gellman Associates [271, Edwin Mansfield [37], Ariel Pakes [44],
David Ravenscraft and F.M. Scherer [47], and Nesor Terieckyj [53] and
[55]. (27.) See, for example, Zvi Griliches [28], John Kendrick [32],
David Levy and Nestor Terleckyj [34], Frank Lichtenberg and Donald
Siegel [35], and Nestor Terleckyj [53] and [55]. (28.) See, for example,
Bureau of Labor Statistics [11], Congressional Budget Office [14],
Robert Eisner [24], and M. Ishaq Nadiri and Ingmar Prucha [38]. (29.)
See Ariel Pakes and Mark Schankerman [45]. (30.) A full description of
BEA's estimates of tangible capitol stock may be found in Bureau of
Economic Analysis [7]. Bea is now reviewing the appropriateness of the
concepts and measurement methods underlying these estimates. Future
capital estimates May be based on somewhat different concepts and
measurement methods. (31.) See Ariel Pakes and Mark Schankerman [45].
(32.) See James Adams [1]. (33.) M. Ishaq Naditi and Ingmar Prucha [39].
(34.) In the tables showing industry detail, administered by industry
are combined with the remainder of industry because source data do not
provide administered by industry separately by industry classifications.
(35.) BEA constructed the R&D IPD at the finest level of detail
possible. In contrast, NSF and others have used the GDP implicit price
deflator or other summary price measures to produce estimates of
constant-dollar R&D expenditures. A comparison of the total R&D
IPD and the GDP IPD shows that the latter provides a reasonable
approximation to the former for deflating total R&D expenditures.
Use of the GDP IPD overstates the historical growth in performed in
public and private universities and colleges and understates the
historical growth in R&D performed in many FFRDC's. NSF views
the deflator as an "opportunity cost" of the real resources
forgone in engaging in R&D rather than as measuring the costs of
doing R&D, and recognizes that the deflator is less useful for
calculating finer-level components of R&D. See National Science
Board, National Science Foundation [39]. (36) See Jack E. Triplett [56].
(37.) See Division of Science Resource Studies, National Science
Foundation [15], [16],[17], [18], [20], and [22] for more information.
(38.) Beginning in 1992, the industry samples will be redrawn annually.
(39.) See Division of Science Resources Studies, National Science
Foundation [20] and [22] for more information. (40.) See John Kendrick
[32]. (41.) See Nestor Terleckyj [54]. (42.) See Vanevar Bush [12l.
(43.) See Research and Development Board, Department of Defense [54].
(44.) See Denver Research Institute [15]. (45.) See Richard Hewlett and
Oscar Anderson, Jr. [29] (46.) See John Jankowski [30], Edwin Mansfield
[36], and Research Associates of Washington [48]. (47.) Additional
information on BEA'S deflators for Federal purchases of R&D may
be obtained from the Bureau of Economic Analysis [8]. Additional
information on BEA'S deflators for higher education and research
may be obtained from the Bureau of Economic Analysis [10]. Additional
information on the biomedical R&D price index may be obtained from
Office of Science Policy and Technology Transfer, National Institutes of
Health [42]. (48.) See Bureau of Economic Analysis [9] for more
information about the NIPA inventory valuation adjustment. (49.) For a
more complete description of the NIPA perpetual inventory method, see
Bureau of Economic Analysis [9), page M-3.
REFERENCES
[1.] Adams, James. "Fundamental Stocks of Knowledge and
Productivity Growth." Journal of Political Economy 98 (August
1990): 673-702. [2.] Adams, James. "Science, R&D and Invention
Potential Recharge: U.S. Evidence." Center for Economic Studies
Discussion Paper CES 93-2. Washington, DC: Census Bureau, 1993. [3.]
Adams, James, and Leo Sveikauskas. "Academic Science, Industrial
R&D, and the Growth of Inputs." Center for Economic Studies
Discussion Paper CES 93-1. Washington, DC: Census Bureau, 1993. [4.]
Bos, Fritz, Hugo Hollanders, and Steven Keuning. "A Research and
Development Module Supplementing the National Accounts.". Review of
Income and Wealth 40 (September 1994): 273-286. [5.] Braibant, Michel.
Satellite Accounts. Paris: Institut National de la Statistique et des
Etudes Economiques, 1994. [6.] Bureau of the Census. 1982 Enterprise
Statistics: Auxiliary Establishment Report. Washington, DC: U.S.
Government Printing Office, 1986. [7.] Bureau of Economic Analysis. U.S.
Department of Commerce. Fixed Reproducible Tangible Wealth in the United
States, 1925-89. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1993.
[8.] Bureau of Economic Analysis. U.S. Department of Commerce.
Government Trans actions. Methodology Paper Series MP-5. Washington, DC:
U.S. Government Printing Office, 1988. [9.] Bureau of Economic Analysis.
U.S. Department of Commerce. National Income and Product Accounts of the
United States: Volume 2, 1959-88. Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Printing Office, 1992. [10.] Bureau of Economic Analysis. U.S.
Department of Commerce. Personal Consumption Expenditures. Methodology
Paper Series MP-6. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office,
1990. [11.] Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). U.S. Department of Labor.
The Impact of Research and Development on Productivity Growth. BLS
Bulletin 2331. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1989.
[12.] Bush, Vannevar. Science, The Endless Frontier. A Report to the
President on a Program for Postwar Scientific Research. Washington, DC:
U.S. Government Printing Office, 1945. [13.] Carson, Carol, and Bruce
Grimm. "Satellite Accounts in a Modernized and Extended System of
Economic Accounts." Business Economics 26 (January 1991): 58-63.
[14.] Congressional Budget Office. Trends in Public Investment.
Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1987. [15.] Denver
Research Institute. Contract Research and Development Adjuncts of
Federal Agencies. Denver, co: University of Denver, 1969. [16.] Division
of Science Resources Studies. National Science Foundation (NSF).
Academic Science and Engineering. R&D Expenditures. Washington, DC:
NSF, annually. [17.] Division of Science Resources Studies. National
Science Foundation. Federal Funds for Research and Development.
Washington, DC: NSF, annually. [18.] Division of Science Resources
Studies. National Science Foundation. Federal Support to Universities,
Colleges, and Selected Nonprofit Institutions. Washington, DC: NSF,
annually. [19.] Division of Science Resources Studies. National Science
Foundation. National Patterns Of R&D Resources, 1992. NSF 92-330.
Washington, DC: NSF, 1992. [20.] Division of Science Resources Studies.
National Science Foundation. Research and Development Expenditures of
State Government Agencies. Washington, DC: NSF, 1970, 1979, 1990. [21.]
Division of Science Resources Studies. National Science Foundation.
Research and Development by Industry. Washington, DC: NSF, annually.
[22.] Division of Science Resources Studies. National Science
Foundation. Scientific Activities of Nonprofit Institutions. Washington,
DC: NSF, 1960, 1964, 1970, 1973. [23.] Division of Science Resources
Studies. National Science Foundation. Scientific and Engineering
Research Facilities at Universities and Colleges. Washington, DC: NSF,
1986, 1988, 1990, 1992. [24.] Eisner, Robert. The Total Income System of
Accounts. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1989. [25.]
Engineering Manpower Commission. Engineers' Salaries: Special
Industry Report Washington, DC: American Association of Engineering
Societies, Inc., annually. [26.] Federal Republic of Germany. Federal
Statistical Office. "Capital Consumption on Expenditures for
Research and Development." Wiesbaden, Germany: Federal Republic of
Germany, 1988. [27.] Gellman Associates. "Indicators of
International Trends in Technological Innovation." Unpublished
report to the National Science Foundation. Washington, DC, 1976. [28.]
Griliches, Zvi. "Returns to Research and Development Expenditures
in the Private Sector." In New Developments in Productivity
Measurement and Analysis. Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 44, edited
by John Kendrick and Beatrice Vaccara, 419-454. Chicago, IL: University
of Chicago Press, for the National Bureau of Economic Research, 1980.
[29.] Hewlett, Richard, and Oscar Anderson, Jr. The New World,
193911946. A History of the United States Atomic Energy Commission, vol.
I. University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University Press, 1962. [30.]
Jankowski, John E. Jr. "Do We Need a Price Index for industrial
R&D?" Research Policy 22 (June 1993): 195-205. [31.] Jaszi,
George. "Comment on the Schiff Paper." In A Critique of the
United States Income and Product Accounts. Studies in Income and Wealth,
vol. 22, 454-455. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, for the
National Bureau of Economic Research, 1958. [32.] Kendrick, John. The
Formation and Stocks of Total Capital New York: Columbia University
Press, for the National Bureau of Economic Research, 1976. [33.]
Kendrick, John. "National Productivity and Its Longer Term
Projection." In Long-Range Economic Projections. Studies in Income
and Wealth, vol. 16, 67-104. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,
for the National Bureau of Economic Research, 1954. [34.] Levy, David,
and Nestor Terleckyj. "Government R&D, Private Investment and
Productivity Growth." NPA Working Paper 1-7-82. Washington, DC:
National Planning Association, i982. [35.] Lichtenberg, Frank, and
Donald Siegel. "The Impact Of R&D Investment on
Productivity--New Evidence Using Linked R&D-LRD Data." Economic
Inquiry 29 (April 1991): 203-229. [36.] Mansfield, Edwin. "Price
Indexes for R and D and Inputs, 1969-1983." Management Science 33
(january 1987): 124-129. [37.] Mansfield, Edwin. "R&D and
Innovation: Some Empirical Findings." In R&D, Patents, and
Productivity, edited by Zvi Griliches, 127-148. Chicago, IL: University
of Chicago Press, 1984. [38.] Nadiri, M. Ishaq and Ingmar Prucha.
"Estimation of the Depreciation Rate of Physical and R&D
Capital in the U.S. Total Manufacturing Sector." Working Paper
4591. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1993. [39.]
National Science Board. National Science Foundation. Science &
Engineering Indicators, 1993. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Office, 1993. [40.] Office of Management and Budget. Budget of the
United States Government, Fiscal Year 1995: Analytical Perspectives.
Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1994. [41.] Office of
Management and Budget. Budget of the United States Government. Appendix.
Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, annually. [42.] Office
of Science Policy and Technology Transfer, National Institutes of Health
(NIH). Biomedical Research and Development Price Index. Bethesda, MD:
NIH, 1993. [43.] Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD). Frascati Manual 1993: The Measurement of Scientific and
Technological Activities: Proposed Standard Practice for Surveys of
Research and Experimental Development. Paris: OECD, 1994. [44.] Pakes,
Ariel. "Patents, R&D, and the Stock Market Rate of
Return." Working Paper 786. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research, 1981. [45.] Pakes, Ariel, and Mark Schankerman.
"The Rate Obsolescence of Patents, Research Gestation Lags, and the
Private Rate of Return to Research Resources." In R&D, Patents,
and Productivity, edited by Zvi Griliches, 73-88. Chicago, IL:
University of Chicago Press, for the National Bureau of Economic
Research, 1984. [46.] Rapoport, John. "The Anatomy of the
Product-Innovation Process: Cost and Time." In Research and
Innovation in the Modern Corporation, edited by Edwin Mansfield,
110-135. New York: W.W. Norton, 1971. [47.] Ravenscraft, David, and F.M.
Scherer. "The Lag Structure of Returns to R&D." Applied
Economics 14 (1982): 603-620. [48.] Research Associates of Washington.
Inflation Measures for Schools and Colleges. Washington, DC: annually.
[49.] Research and Development Board. Department of Defense. The Growth
of Scientific Research and Development. Washington, DC: Department of
Defense, 1953. [50.] Ruggles, Nancy, and Richard Ruggles. The Design of
Economic Accounts. New York: Columbia University Press, for the National
Bureau of Economic Research, 1970. [51.] Schiff, Eric. "Business
Plant and Equipment." In A Critique of the United States Income and
Product Accounts. Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 16, 431-435.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, for the National Bureau of
Economic Research, 1958. [52.] System of National Accounts 1993.
Brussels: Commission of the European Communities, International Monetary
Fund, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, and World
Bank, 1993. [53.] Terleckyj, Nestor. "The Economic Effects of
Government R&D Spending in the United States." NPA Discussion
Paper 8-31-84. Washington, DC: National Planning Association, 1984.
[54.] Terleckyj, Nestor. Research and Development. Its Growth and
Composition. Studies in Business Economics No. 82. New York: National
Industrial Conference Board, 1963. [55.] Terleckyj, Nestor.
"R&D as a Source of Growth of Productivity and of Income."
NPA Working Paper 5-18-82. Washington, DC: National Planning
Association, 1982. [56.] Triplett, Jack E. "Measuring the Capital
Stock: A Review of Concepts and Data Needs." Paper given at the
Conference on Research in Income and Wealth, Workshop on the Measurement
of Depreciation and Capital Stock. Washington, DC: Bureau of Economic
Analysis, (June 5, 1992). [57.] Wagner, Lenore. "Problems in
Estimating Research and Development Investment and Stock."
Proceedings of the Business and Economic Statistics Section, American
Statistical Association (ASA). Washington, DC: ASA, 1968.