Rates of return on direct investment.
Landefeld, J. Steven ; Lawson, Ann M. ; Weinberg, Douglas B. 等
This article updates the alternative measures prepared by the
Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) of the rates of return on foreign
direct investment in the United States (FDIUS) and on U.S. direct
investment abroad (USDIA). It compares these rate of return with those
on all-U.S.-business investment and discusses possible explanations for
the relatively low rates of return on FDIUS.
Last year, BEA introduced two alternative measures of the rate of
return on direct investment that were based on BEA estimates of the
direct investment positions valued at current-period prices: The return
on direct investment positions at market value, which is a measure of
financial return to direct investment, and the return on direct
investment positions valued at current cost, which is a measure of
economic returns on direct investment from current operations.(1) These
alternative measures overcome a major limitation of estimates of rates
of return based on historical costs--the noncomparability of investments
that differ considerably in age and therefore in price--by presenting
estimates on a consistent valuation basis.
Table 1 shows rates of return for USDIA and FDIUS based on market
value and on current cost compared with a market rate of return for all
U.S. businesses; it also shows rates of return for USDIA and FDIUS based
on historical costs.(2) For both USDIA and FDIUS, the rates of return at
current-period prices are lower, on average, than the rates of return at
historical costs. However, the differences are much larger for USDIA
than for FDIUS because the adjustment needed to restate direct
investment positions from historical costs to current-period prices is
much larger for USDIA. This price adjustment is larger for USDIA because
most USDIA occurred in the 1960's and 1970's and thus tends to
be "older" than FDIUS, most of which occurred in the
1980's. [TABULAR DATA 1 OMITTED]
For USDIA, the rates of return at market value and at current cost
are similar, on average, to the rates of return for all U.S. businesses.
However, for FDIUS, the rates of return at market value and at current
cost are considerably below the rates of return for all U.S. businesses.
(The historical-cost rates of return for FDIUS are also quite low.) The
remainder for this article examines the question of why the rates of
return on FDIUS are so low relative to the rates of return on domestic
investments.(3)
Returns on FDIUS
In examining rates of return on FDIUS, it is important to note that
a multinational company tries to maximize its total profits around the
world in deciding where to invest, where to produce, and where to
realize its income. As a result, a multinational company structures its
operations, costs, and product pricing across countries to maximize its
global profits rather than to maximize profits on an individual
investment or even on all of its investments in a single country. It may
accept a below-average profit to gain access to the large U.S. market or
to scarce raw materials. Alternatively, it may accept low returns on
some parts of its operations to take advantage of economies of scale and
technological efficiencies in other parts of its operations. In addition
to these types of operational--or industrial organization--factors,
multinationals also take into account a number of other factors, such as
differences across countries in the cost and availability of capital, in
expected returns on investment, in the tax treatment of income, and in
tariffs and nontariff barriers.(4)
The low rates of return on FDIUS appear to reflect certain
long-term factors associated with the operations of multinational
companies and the effects of a number of transitional factors that led
to a surge in FDIUS in the 1980's. In the 1980's,
current-account surpluses in Japan and several other countries generated
excess funds available for investment. Funds were attracted to the
United States by average yields on U.S. investments that were higher
than those on home-country investments; this spread allowed foreign
investors to accept yields that were below the average yield on U.S.
investments. Further, depreciation of the dollar against most foreign
currencies in the latter half of the 1980's increased potential
long-term yields for those investors who believed that the U.S. dollar
was undervalued. The combination of these factors meant that investments
that had looked attractive from an operations perspective now also
looked attractive from an investment perspective. The resulting surge in
FDIUS in the 1980's meant that much of the investment on which the
rates of return are calculated was relatively new, and new investments
typically have lower rates of return than more mature investments.
Moreover, a considerable portion of this new FDIUS consisted of
acquisitions of financially distressed U.S. companies that foreign
companies presumably hoped to restructure and restore to financial
health.
Long-term factors associated with the goal of maximizing profits on
a global basis rather than on an individual-country basis also may have
held down the rates of return on FDIUS. These factors included the
following: Economies of scale and the advantages of vertical
integration, differences between countries in the treatment of taxes,
and avoidance of tariffs and nontariff barriers.
The analysis that follows covers the rates of return on FDIUS for
10 of the 11 countries that were the largest direct investors in the
United States during the last decade.(5) In 1991, these 10 countries
accounted for over 90 percent of cumulative FDIUS, and the top 5
accounted for over 75 percent (table 2). It should be noted that
underlying economic conditions and motivations for direct investment
vary markedly among these countries, and it is difficult to generalize about the factors leading to low rates of return on their direct
investments. [TABULAR DATA 2 OMITTED]
Transitional factors
Differences in average yields.--During much of the last decade,
average yields on investments in the top 10 investor countries were
below those in the United States (table 3). Between 1982 and 1989, the
average real rate of return on total invested capital--debt and equity
combined--was 6.6 percent in these countries, compared with 7.3 percent
in the United States. The average yield on debt in these countries was
4.8 percent, compared with 6.3 percent; the average yield on equities
was 7.6 percent, compared with 7.8 percent.
For several of these major investor countries, the difference
between returns on direct equity investments was substantial. For
example, Japanese investors received an average yield of 6.5 percent on
their equity FDIUS between 1983 and 1989, compared with a yield of 2.8
percent on Japanese equities. Thus, returns on Japanese investments in
the United States raised Japanese investors' aggregate yields, even
though they were lower than the all-U.S.-business average.
Depreciation of the dollar.--A second and more important factor
increasing FDIUS in the 1980's was the decline in the value of the
U.S. dollar. In the latter half of the 1980's, the real value of
the dollar declined 35 percent, and foreign firms more than doubled
their direct investment position. This surge in FDIUS was similar to one
that occurred between 1975 and 1980, when the dollar depreciated about
15 percent and FDIUS more than tripled.
In the latter half of the 1980's, overseas investors
presumably believed that the dollar was undervalued and that future
returns to dollar-denominated direct investments would be well above
their current values. U.S. firms' assets looked undervalued to
those who believed that the dollar was below its long-run equilibrium
and purchasing-power-parity value. Although it is difficult to determine
the long-run equilibrium value for the dollar, a number of indicators
supported the view of investors who believed the dollar was undervalued.
For example, observed differences in real asset prices--such as those
between Japanese and U.S. real estate and stock market investments--as
well as estimates of the purchasing power of the dollar and of relative
U.S. unit labor costs, suggested the dollar was undervalued.(6) As chart
1 shows, the surges in FDIUS in both the late 1970's and the late
1980's occurred when the dollar was below its 1973 value, which may
be regarded as a rough indicator of the dollar's equilibrium value.
Rates of return on new direct investments.--The combined effects of
higher relative rates of return on investments in the United States and
the depreciation of the dollar made U.S. returns look particularly
attractive to overseas companies that had increased profits from sales
to U.S. markets and had thereby accumulated substantial cash reserves.
For these firms, increasing their U.S. presence through direct
investment was attractive from an investment as well as an operations
perspective. The combination of these factors may even have encouraged
companies abroad to buy financially distressed U.S. companies as
long-term investments. Presumably, foreign companies either believed
that they could turn their U.S. investments around over time by using
their expertise in product development, process technology, and
management, or they believed that they could achieve higher returns from
an appreciation of the dollar.
During the 1980's, about three-fourths of all FDIUS was for
acquiring existing companies, and about one-fourth was for establishing
new companies. For the companies established, rates of return were low
or negative because of the startup costs that all new firms experience.
For the companies acquired, rates of return were already low or
negative: Between 1982 and 1990, the rate of return on assets for U.S.
companies in the year before their acquisition by foreigners was 1.0
percent, compared with 4.6 percent for all U.S. nonfinancial companies
(table 4, chart 2).(7) In addition, the foreign owners' newly
acquired companies not only began with below-average returns, but
presumably these returns were lowered further as owners restructured
these companies by investing in new plant and equipment and in
modernization of older plants, by writing-off and closing obsolete
units, by increasing marketing efforts, and by aggressively pricing
their products to regain market share. [TABULAR DATA 4 OMITTED]
Recent developments.--By 1990, many of the transitional factors
that had encouraged direct investment in the United States were no
longer present. Other countries' current-account surpluses with the
United States were reduced. Multinational companies needed to reduce
debt and rebuild their balance sheets, and their bankers needed to limit
credit and meet higher capital standards. At the same time, the relative
real rates of return on investments were reversed, as U.S. real interest
rates and returns to equities decreased in relation to those abroad
(table 3). In late 1990 and early 1991, the slide in the value of the
dollar stopped, and its value began to increase, which raised the cost
to foreign investors of new direct investments in the United States.
These developments combined to produce a sharp drop in FDIUS from $67.8
billion in 1989 to $11.5 billion in 1991.
With the slowdown in new FDIUS, the rates of return on existing
FDIUS should rise as these investments mature. Rates of return on USDIA
have shown this patter, and there is some evidence that rates of return
on FDIUS have tended to rise over time as well.(8) However, long-term
factors may continue to hold down FDIUS rates of return. [TABULAR DATA 3
OMITTED]
Long-term factors
Vertical integration.--One fundamental reason for foreign companies
to make direct investments in other countries is to achieve vertical
integration.(9) Owning both "upstream" raw material and
production facilities and "downstream" distribution outlets
may make it easier to further penetrate foreign markets. Through U.S.
affiliates, foreign parent companies can better design, manufacture,
distribute, and service products for the special requirements of the
U.S. market. Either through resale of the foreign parent's products
by their U.S. affiliates or through sales of the parent's products
as inputs to the affiliates, increased sales of the parent's
products can achieve economies of scale in home-country production,
resulting in lower unit production costs for their products.
Besides company affiliation, U.S. affiliates of foreign
multinational companies cite other reasons for relying on imports from
the parent company, including product quality, assured sources of
supply, and specialized product needs. Presumably, vertical integration
and maximizing total company profits also play a role. Whatever the
reasons, foreign-owned affiliates do have a higher propensity to import
than do U.S. multinational companies in the United States. Imports by
U.S. affiliates of foreign multinationals accounted for 24 percent of
their total purchases of inputs in 1987, compared with 8 percent for
U.S. multinational companies (table 5). Part of the higher propensity to
import is explained by the practice of using U.S. affiliates mainly as
distribution outlets. Overall, U.S. affiliates' imports for resale
as a share of their total sales was 15 percent in 1987; for several
direct investors, the share was much higher (table 6). [TABULAR DATA 5
OMITTED]
Table 6.--U.S. Affiliate Imports for Resale as a Share
of Total Sales, 1987
[Percent]
All countries 14.7
Top 10 countries:
Japan 33.9
Sweden 21.6
Germany 18.9
Switzerland 11.1
Belgium/Luxembourg 8.7
Canada 5.3
France 4.7
United Kingdom 3.6
Netherlands 3.1
Australia 2.3
Note.--Imports and sales are identified by county of foreign parent.
With a vertically integrated company, the profits resulting from
economies of scale can be allocated among the parent and its affiliates
in order to maximize total returns. Such decisions can affect rates of
return on individual investments. For example, a company that requires
access to a scarce raw material may accept a lower rate of return on its
"upstream" investments in mining because such access will
raise its global profits. Alternatively, a company may accept lower
returns on its "downstream" operations because, through
vertical integration, it can raise total sales and take advantage of
economies of scale and technological efficiencies that raise its total
profits.
Taxes.--Differences in tax treatment across countries can
significantly affect both the location of direct investment and, through
"transfer pricing," the distribution of profits between parent
and affiliate.(10) If the effective tax rate on the domestic income of
the foreign parent is lower parent is lower than that on the income
earned by the U.S. affiliate, the company can raise its total return by
shifting income from the affiliate to the parent. This is achieved
through use of transfer prices for transactions between the affiliate
and its parent, whereby the company raises the price of exports to the
affiliate and lowers the price of imports from the affiliate.
In table 7, effective tax rates on income from investments in U.S.
affiliates are compared with those on income from domestic investments
for the top 10 foreign investor countries (as before, excluding the
Netherlands Antilles). Computations of effective tax rates are subject
to considerable uncertainty and are sensitive to the assumptions made
regarding such variables as inflation and the financing mix. However,
the rates in table 7, which are derived from a recent study on effective
tax rates by the Organisation of Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD), show that foreign parents in all but one of the 10 major
investor countries may have an incentive to transfer income from their
U.S. affiliates to themselves.(11) [TABULAR DATA 7 OMITTED]
Avoidance of tariffs and nontariff barriers.--Tariffs and nontariff
barriers raise the cost of exports and provide an incentive for
foreigners to invest abroad.(12) In recent years, direct investments in
the U.S. auto industry were presumably related to actual and potential
restrictions on vehicle exports to the United States. In addition,
direct investment in several industries--televisions, typewriters,
semiconductors, and automobiles--may have been related to antidumping
suits and antidumping duties against foreign producers of these
products. In these cases, the motive for direct investment may be to
avoid tariffs and nontariff barriers in order to maximize total company
returns, rather than to maximize returns on the direct investment. For
example, a foreign manufacturer can avoid antidumping duties by
exporting parts and components, on which there is no duty, for final
assembly by the U.S. affiliate, rather than exporting the finished
product, on which antidumping duties would be levied.
Importance of country-specific factors
The complex interrelationship among the factors that have caused
rates of return to be lower for FDIUS than for all U.S. businesses is
perhaps best demonstrated by an examination of the direct investment
activities of companies from different countries. This section contrasts
the activities of the two largest investor countries--Japan and the
United Kingdom (table 8). Together, these two countries accounted for
nearly one-half of the FDIUS position on a historical-cost basis in
1991. In 1982, the United Kingdom had the largest position, and it
maintained that standing during the 1980's; Japan had the fifth
largest position in 1982 and the second largest position at the end of
the 1980's. [TABULAR DATA 8 OMITTED]
In terms of Japan's rates of return and the factors that have
driven these returns, Japanese FDIUS was typical of FDIUS as a whole
during the last decade. Large current-account surpluses in the
1980's in combination with relatively low rates of return in Japan
led to large flows of direct investment capital from Japanese companies
that were seeking higher returns in the United States. Low rates of
return for U.S. companies in the year prior to their acquisition, along
with high restructuring costs after acquisition, led to low earnings by
affiliates of Japanese parents. Vertical integration, indicated by U.S.
affiliates' heavy reliance on imports for immediate resale, and
practices related to vertical integration, such as transfer pricing,
further depressed returns on direct investment.(13) Effective tax rates
on the domestic income of Japanese parents were lower than those on the
income of their U.S. affiliates, which created an incentive to shift
profits from the United States to Japan. Finally, tariffs and nontariff
barriers, such as Voluntary Restraint Agreements (VRA'S) and
antidumping suits and duties, may have induced Japanese companies to
substitute assembly and production plants in the United States for final
goods exports from Japan.
By contrast, for British FDIUS, rates of return and the factors
that have driven these returns are largely dissimilar to those for all
FDIUS. Throughout the 1980's, the United Kingdom maintained only
small current-account surpluses and had higher-than-average expected
rates of return at home. Although the flow of direct investment from the
United Kingdom during this period was the largest in absolute terms,
from 1983 to 1991 new flows accounted for a much smaller percentage of
the direct investment position of the United Kingdom than that for
Japan. Thus, while British investors probably also bought some
low-return U.S. companies and encountered similarly high restructuring
costs, these low returns would have been more than offset by higher
returns on the United Kingdom's larger stock of more mature
investments. A primary example of a mature investment is the British
investment in petroleum, which has a diversified structure within the
United States that includes both upstream and downstream activities.
Investment in this industry has boosted the overall British rate of
return; in contrast, Japanese investment in wholesale trade--typically a
more downstream activity--has held down the overall Japanese rate of
return. In addition, effective tax rates in the United Kingdom are
comparable with those on British investments in the United State
producing little incentive for profit shifting. Finally, imports from
the United Kingdom have not generally been in industries subjected to
VRA'S or other nontariff barriers, thus creating no incentive for
earning less than the profit-maximizing return on direct investment.
(1)For a discussion of the various measures, see "Alternative
Measures of the Rate of Return on Direct Investment," Survey of
Current Business 71 (August 1991): 44-45. For a discussion of the
estimates of direct investment at market value and current cost, see
"The International Investment Position of the United States in
1991," Survey 72 (June 1992): 46--59. For a discussion of the
concepts and estimating procedures underlying the current-period
estimates of direct investment, see "Valuation of the U.S. Net
International Investment Position," Survey 71 (May 1991): 40--49.
(2)The date are limited to the period from 1982 or 1983 to 1991 because
the complete information on equity flows and equity positions that is
required for the market-value measure is unavailable for earlier years.
(3)For other recent studies on FDIUS and the low rates of return on
FDIUS, see Harry Grubert, Timothy Goodspeed, and Debrah Swenson,
"Explaining the Low Taxable Income of Foreign-Controlled Companies
in the United States," unpublished, contact author, Harry Grubert,
U.S. Treasury) November 1991; Edward M. Graham and Paul R. Krugman,
Foreign Direct Investment in the United States, 2d edition (Washington,
DC: Institute for International Economics, 1991); and "Review of
Internal Revenue Service Statistics on Foreign Controlled Domestic
Corporations 1983 through 1988," prepared by KPMG Peat Marwick for
the Organization for International Investment, July 1992. (4)There has
been much discussion about the relative importance of cost-of-capital
and macroeconomic explanations versus industrial-organization
explanations for direct investment. Most analysts concede that both have
a role in direct investment but that industrial-organization
explanations tend to have a larger role than the other explanations.
See, for example, Graham and Krugman in Foreign Direct Investment,
35-38. (5)Although the Netherlands Antilles' FDIUS position ranks
eighth among all countries, it is excluded from the analysis because of
the unique nature of its inward investment, which resulted from its
activity as an offshore financial central (offshore financial centers
were created to avoid certain interest-rate controls, bank lending
restrictions and reserve requirements, and other regulatory
constraints). Additionally, it had a favorable tax treaty with the
United States that offered an exemption from the withholding tax on
certain interest payments from U.S. affiliates to their Antillean
parents. Consequently, foreign corporations made large investments in
the United States through their Antillean affiliates rather than
investing directly in the United States. However, over the past decade,
the Netherlands Antilles' share of total FDIUS has declined
substantially. Its current-dollar position has remained fairly constant
since 1984, while its real share of total FDIUS has declined from 7
percent in 1982 to 2 percent in 1991. This downtrend can be partly
explained by the elimination of U.S. withholding taxes on interest
payments to foreigners in 1984, which largely nullified the Netherlands
Antilles' unique tax advantage. (6)According to Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development estimates of purchasing-power
parity, the dollar was undervalued by roughly 19 percent against the
currencies of the major industrialized economies in 1990. Estimates by
the Federal Reserve Board indicated that U.S. unit labor costs were
roughly 15 percent below those of the other major industrialized
countries. For a different perspective on the effect of the dollar on
FDIUS, see Graham and Krugman, Foreign Direct Investment, 44-47 and
80-82. (7)For the most recently published data on U.S. companies in the
year before their acquisition by foreign parents, "U.S. Business
Enterprises Acquired or Established by Foreign Direct Investors in 1991,
"Survey 72 (May 1992): 69-79. (8)For a discussion of the increase
in returns with age on USDIA in manufacturing affiliates, see L.A. Lupo,
Arnold Gilbert, and Michael Liliestedt, "The Relationship Between
Age and Rate of Return of Foreign Manufacturing Affiliates of U.S.
Manufacturing Parent Companies," Survey 58 (August 1978): 60-66.
For a general discussion of the effect of age on profitability, see F.M.
Scherer, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, 3rd
edition (Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company, 1990): 172-174. (9)For a
general discussion of vertical integration as a motivation for foreign
direct investment, see Richard E. Caves, "The Multinational
Enterprise as an Economic Organization," in Multinational
Enterprise and Economic Analysis (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1983): 15-24 and 95; and Scherer, Industrial Market Structure, 94-96 and
109-111. (10)For further discussion of the use of transfer pricing
between parent and affiliate to reallocate income for tax purposes, see
Graham and Krugman, Foreign Direct Investment, 82-83; and Mohammad F.
Al-Eryani, Pervaiz Alam, and Syed H. Akhter, "Transfer Pricing
Determinants of U.S. Multinationals," Journal of International
Business Studies, 3rd quarter, 1990: 409-425. For more information on
how effective tax rates affect the flow of investment to domestic or
foreign locations, see Joel Slemrod, "Tax Effects on Foreign Direct
Investment in the United States: Evidence from a Cross-Country
Comparison," in Taxation in the Global Economy, Assaf Razin and
Joel Slemrod, eds., (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1990):
79-122; and Kan H. Young, "The Effects of Taxes and Rates of Return
on Foreign Direct Investment in the United States," National Tax
Journal (March 1988): 109-121. (11)See OECD, Taxing Profits in a Global
Economy: Domestic and International Issues (Paris: OECD, 1991). (12)For
a discussion of how foreign direct investment is motivated by the desire
to avoid tariffs and nontariff barriers, see "Strengthening GATT Antidumping Rules," Economic Report of the President (Washington,
DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1992); 219; and U.S. Congress, U.S.
Trade Restraints: Effects on Foreign Investment, report prepared by
James K. Jackson (Washington, DC: Library of Congress, 1989). (13)Heavy
reliance on imports for immediate resale by U.S. affiliates of Japanese
parents and, more generally, all U.S. affiliates' substantial
dependence on imports for use in production, probably also contributed
to reductions in rates of return from 1985-87 because of the steep
depreciation of the dollar.