The United Nations System of National Accounts: an introduction.
Carson, Carol S. ; Honsa, Jeanette
The United Nations System of National Accounts: An Introduction
The United Nations System of National Accounts (SNA) is not widely
known in the United States. However, interest is growing. Early this
year, a working group on improving economic statistics, chaired by the
Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers and including the Commerce
Department's Under Secretary for Economic Affairs, recommended that
the United States move to the SNA, and the BEA budget now before
Congress requests funds for such a move by the mid-1990's.
The SNA provides a more comprehensive, integrated picture of the
economy than the present U.S. economic accounts. In particular, it
integrates the recording of the economy's stocks and flows, both
financial and nonfinancial. Thus it provides a better analytical base
for policy. Most other countries follow the SNA, adapting it to fit
their economies and statistical systems; were the United States
following the SNA, U.S. measures of economic growth, inflation, the
saving rate, and other key policy variables would be more comparable
with those from other countries. Because policy is increasingly
formulated in an international setting, comparability across countries
is becoming even more important. The SNA is currently being revised to
reflect advances in economic accounting in the last 20 years and the
emergence of new economic institutions and policy concerns, and thus a
move by the United States to the SNA over the next few years would be
opportune.
This article introduces the SNA. The first part of the article
describes the SNA as a system, comparing and contrasting it with the
U.S. economic accounts in very general terms. The second part presents
estimates prepared by BEA, based on a set of reconciling adjustments,
that approximate some of the major aggregates of the SNA. Although this
part focuses on differences, the many similarities in coverage and
presentation between BEA's national income and product accounts and
the corresponding part of the SNA are noteworthy. The third part
describes the revision of the SNA that is currently under way.
Part 1. The SNA as a System
The origins of the System of National Accounts (SNA) can be traced
back to some of the same theoretical developments and economic
conditions that helped shape the U.S. accounts during the 1930's
and early 1940's. The first SNA was drafted by a group of experts
from various countries (including the United States) under the auspices of the United Nations and was adopted by the U.N. Statistical Commission
in 1953. The 1953 SNA drew on work in a number of countries and by the
predecessor of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development. A central feature was that it placed national income and
product totals, which at one time had been the center of interest, in an
integrated system of economic transactions. This system was similar to
the five-account summary of the U.S. national income and product
accounts (NIPA's). Like the U.S. accounts, it defined the economy
essentially in terms of market transactions, and it presented
consumption, investment, and saving measures in addition to the income
and product totals. A revision of the SNA in 1968 substantially extended
the U.N. system to include input-output accounts, flow of funds accounts, and balance sheets.(1)
The SNA has had two main goals: To facilitate international
comparisons and to serve as a guide to countries as they develop their
own economic accounting systems. Most countries with market economies
use the SNA as a guide. By doing so, they take advantage of the
substantial body of experience that the SNA represents and increase the
comparability of their estimates with those of other countries. The
European Communities adopted a version of the SNA to be followed by its
member countries beginning in 1970. Canada, which--along with the United
Kingdom--cooperated with the United States in developing national income
and product accounts during World War II, follows the broad outline of
the SNA. Japan and Australia moved to the SNA after the 1968 revision.
Until recently, countries with centrally planned economies followed the
System of Balances of the National Economy, also called the material
product system, or MPS. (This system was developed by an economic
organization of which these countries are members to accord with the
theory on which their economies are based, and it is used by the United
Nations to report information from them.) Consistent with their
transition to market-oriented economies, the Soviet Union and a number
of the others either are preparing accounts on both an SNA basis and on
an MPS basis or are moving to the SNA.
The SNA aims to record all the stocks and flows that are defined as
part of the economy. Like other sets of economic accounts, it does so by
grouping transactors and transactions in a way that is meaningful for
economic analysis, forecasting, and policy.(2)
For transactors, the SNA groups households, governments, and
business enterprises (financial and nonfinancial) into sectors (table
1). However, some transactors are not easily grouped because they have
characteristics of more than one of these sectors. The SNA deals with
these transactors either by treating them as a separate sector or by
combining them with one or more of the other sectors. Private nonprofit institutions serving households are grouped into a separate sector. Some
unincorporated enterprises are in the business enterprise sector, and
the others are in the household sector. Foreigners, to the extent that
they have transactions with residents, are treated like a sector, called
the rest of the world. In addition, the SNA groups producing
establishments into industries (or the equivalent).
The SNA groups transactions according to the major categories of
economic activity--production, income and outlay, capital accumulation,
and capital finance. The transactions--often referred to as
"flows"--are supplemented by revaluations for price change;
together the flows and revaluations "explain" the differences
between the opening and closing balance sheets, which record the stocks
of assets and liabilities at a point in time (table 2).
Each group of flows and the stocks are arranged in a two-sided
account in which the totals balance either by definition or by inclusion
of a balancing item. When the transaction (and associated stock)
accounts are set up for each transactor group, the result is a set of
macroeconomic accounts for the Nation and for the several sectors (and
industries). The SNA aggregates--such as gross product, saving, and
national wealth--are usually a total for an account or a balancing item.
Although the derivation of aggregates is not the main purpose of the
SNA, the aggregates are useful summary indicators for analysis and
comparisons over time and space.
The accounts for the Nation and sectors are supplemented in several
ways. A set of tables provides for recording additional
information--either detail not easily shown in account form or
information related, but not integral, to the accounts. Standard
classifications are indicated for industries, the functions of
government, household expenditure on goods and services, capital
formation, etc. Finally, guidelines are provided for constant-price
measures.
Thus, the SNA provides a comprehensive framework: It includes
measures of production, income, saving and investment, and wealth; it
encompasses both domestic and foreign activities; it links financial and
nonfinancial transactions; and it provides for both current and
constant-price measures. Further, the SNA is an integrated system--that
is, the several subsets of accounts use consistent definitions,
classifications, and accounting conventions (valuation, time of
recording, extent of consolidation, extent of netting, etc.).(3)
The SNA includes accounts that are separate systems in the United
States. The NIPA's, prepared by BEA, cover the transactions that
are grouped in the SNA as production, income and outlay, and capital
accumulation. The input-output accounts, also prepared by BEA, cover the
production accounts by industry. The flow of funds accounts, prepared by
the Federal Reserve Board, cover the financial transactions. Finally,
the Federal Reserve Board also prepares revaluation accounts and balance
sheets, but they only cover the private domestic sectors. (The SNA does
not include balance of payments accounts, but the SNA's
rest-of-the-world transactions and the International Monetary
Fund's balance of payments guidelines have moved closer together.)
Compared with the U.S. economic accounts, the SNA is more
comprehensive in coverage. The U.S. accounts do not include a complete
set of either revaluation accounts or of balance sheets. In addition,
the SNA is more fully integrated. For the U.S. accounts, the NIPA's
and input-output accounts are integrated conceptually and statistically.
The NIPA's and BEA's balance of payments accounts differ
conceptually and statistically, but they are reconciled by a few
regularly published items. The NIPA's and the flow of funds
accounts also differ conceptually and statistically; they are not fully
reconcilable.
The SNA's definitions, classifications, accounting structure,
and accounting conventions differ to some extent from those used in the
U.S. accounts. With regard to the sector definitions, the SNA includes
some unincorporated enterprises in the household sector and treats
nonprofit institutions serving households as a separate sector; the U.S.
accounts include all unincorporated enterprises in the business sector
and include the nonprofits in the household sector. With regard to
accounting structure and conventions, the SNA details the sector
accounts more fully. The SNA presents a set of production, income and
outlay, and capital accumulation accounts for each sector; the usual
NIPA presentation of these accounts is more consolidated, although the
separate sector accounts can be derived. The NIPA's five-account
summary presents, for example, a production account that is consolidated
for all sectors combined with the income and outlay account for the
business sector.
These differences and others that will be discussed in part 2 exist
for several reasons. Some arise because the U.S. system has been
constructed to fit the U.S. economy and to use the data that are, or
could reasonably be, available, whereas the SNA is meant to be a
universal system without compromises to fit specific national
situations. Some of these differences exist even for countries that
follow the SNA. Some other differences are with respect to economic
accounting issues that are generally agreed to have no
"correct" answer (and where concern for international
comparability of economic measures might tip the balance toward the SNA
answer).
Part 2. BEA's Estimates of SNA Aggregates
This part of the article focuses on the subset of SNA accounts that
corresponds to the NIPA's. In doing so, it moves the comparison and
contrast of the SNA and the U.S. accounts from the general to the
specific. This part serves two purposes. Pragmatically, it explains how
the estimates of major U.S. aggregates on an SNA basis published by the
international organizations are reconciled with the NIPA estimates
published by BEA. (See the accompanying box for references to
publications that present U.S. estimates on an SNA basis.) More
generally, in explaining the reconciliations, it introduces several
economic accounting issues, some of which are mentioned again in
discussing the revision of the SNA.
The SNA-basis estimates described in this part are prepared by BEA
in response to a questionnaire used by the United Nations and the
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.(4) The annual
estimates prepared for this purpose are conversions of the published
NIPA estimates to the SNA basis by a series of reconciling adjustments
based on underlying detail and related data.(5)
The adjustments are not able to deal with all differences. In
particular, adjustments cannot be made when the information needed to
quantify a definitional or classificational difference is not currently
available. For example, information is not available to adjust
inventories to exclude the kinds of livestock--breeding stock, dairy
cattle, animals raised for wool, etc.--that are treated in the SNA as
fixed capital formation. In addition, some of the adjustments only
roughly approximate the SNA definition or classification. Further, the
adjustments do not deal with some other differences, such as those
related to valuation. For example, the SNA records merchandise exports
on a "free on board," or f.o.b., basis and imports on a
"cost, insurance, and freight," or c.i.f., basis (with
additional f.o.b. information); because of data limitations, BEA records
exports and imports on a "free alongside ship," or f.a.s.,
basis.
Tables 3 and 4 show how the adjustments affect expenditures on
gross domestic product (GDP) and charges against GDP, respectively. For
1988, the latest year for which there is a reconciliation, SNA-basis GDP
is about three-fourths of 1 percent less than NIPA-basis GDP; prior to
1986, the two GDP measures differed by less. These tables also show some
of the differences in magnitudes of the major components and introduce
some of the differences in terminology between the two systems.
The discussion that follows will deal with (1) the principal
measure of production in each system; (2) three differences between the
NIPA's and the SNA that cause differences in total GDP; (3) some
differences that cause NIPA components to differ from their SNA
counterparts but that do not affect total GDP; (4) differences in types
of income and in saving; and (5) differences in presentation.
Principal measure of production
Gross national product (GNP) is the principal measure of aggregate
production in the NIPA's; GDP is the principal measure in the SNA.
The NIPA's focus on GNP, but they show GDP as a subtotal in a table
that presents product by sector. The SNA includes only GDP, but the U.N.
publications show GNP in a reconciliation of commonly used aggregates.
Gross national product is the market value of goods and services
produced by labor and property supplied by residents of a country,
regardless of whether or not that labor and property is located within
the geographical confines of the country. Gross domestic product is the
market value of goods and services produced by labor and property
located within the geographical confines of the country, regardless of
the residence of that labor and property. The difference between the two
measures is net factor income received from abroad, which is included in
GNP but not in GDP (table 5). Net factor income received from abroad is
the difference between factor income earned abroad by U.S. residents, on
the one hand, and factor income earned in the United States by foreign
residents, on the other; it can, therefore, be either positive or
negative.(6) GDP is usually thought to be preferable for analyzing
production and employment, for example, because these variables may need
to be related to a geographic area. GNP may be preferable for analyzing
the sources and disposition of income, because receipts from and
payments to the rest of the world may be relevant parts of the total
picture.
For the United States, annual growth rates of GNP and GDP differ by
less than one-half percentage point because net factor income received
from abroad is small compared with the rest of the economy. For other
countries, however, the two measures can be quite different. For
countries that have had much more investment from abroad than they have
invested abroad, GDP can be significantly higher than GNP. For countries
that have a sizable number of residents who work abroad, GNP can be
noticeably higher than GDP.
Differences that affect GDP
Government nonmilitary structures and equipment, imputed charges
for certain financial services, and Federal Government pensions affect
GDP differently in the NIPA's than in the SNA. As illustrated in
table 5, the treatment of the first and third of these items has tended
to make GDP higher in the SNA than in the NIPA's in recent years,
but this tendency has been more than offset by the treatment of the
second item.
Government nonmilitary structures and equipment.--The NIPA's
do not distinguish between government purchases on current account (that
is, "consumption") and government purchases on capital account
(that is, "investment"); all government purchases are treated
as current-account purchases. The SNA does make this distinction.
Purchases of nonmilitary structures and equipment are assigned to the
capital account (and included in gross capital formation). The rationale
is that these items yield useful services for much longer than a single
accounting period, and their purchase cannot, therefore, be regarded as
a current cost of that accounting period alone. Other nonmilitary
purchases, along with virtually all military purchases, are assigned to
the current account (and included in government final consumption
expenditure).
Treating government structures and equipment as investment requires
that the current account include the value of the services that the
capital assets provide. The value of these services covers depreciation
(that is, the consumption, or using up, of fixed capital) and a net
return on the capital assets. The NIPA treatment can be traced to the
difficulty of estimating these services. In the business sector, the
value of services rendered by capital is reflected in property incomes,
including profit; profit is measured by subtracting the costs of
production from the market value of output. Because government output is
not normally sold on the market, this calculation cannot be made; the
value of services provided by government capital must be imputed.
Although BEA does not make this imputation for the NIPA's, it does
estimate the depreciation on government assets; the depreciation
estimates are part of its capital stock estimates, which include
government structures and equipment.
In the SNA, only capital consumption is included as a measure of
the value of the services of government assets. Further, the SNA does
not provide for capital consumption on all government assets. Because of
the practical difficulties of making the estimates, capital consumption
is not provided for in the case of government assets such as roads,
dams, breakwaters, or other forms of construction except structures.
This treatment is rationalized by suggesting that outlays on repair and
maintenance may be sufficient to maintain the assets in their original
condition.
Thus, both the NIPA and SNA treatments are reflections of the
practical difficulties of imputing the value of the services of
government capital. Several approaches to such an imputation are
available. One approach is to impute a value to the services of
government assets on the basis of the market value of the services of
similar private assets. The value of the services of government-owned
office buildings, for example, might be imputed on the basis of rents
actually earned by privately owned office buildings. (This procedure is
used for the value of services of owner-occupied residential buildings.)
For many government assets, however, close market analogies are not
available. Another approach is a cost-based approach, in which the value
of the services is estimated as the sum of depreciation and an imputed
value that is calculated by applying a rate of return--often a rate on
an alternative investment--to the net stock of government assets.
Several groups of U.S. researchers have applied variants of this
approach, using BEA's depreciation and stock estimates. One of the
problems encountered is in determining the appropriate rate of return to
apply to the stock. This difficulty is suggested by the wide range found
by a study that calculated four estimates using alternative assumptions
about the rate. For 1979, the estimated value of the services of
government capital in the United States ranged from $90.1 billion to
$163.4 billion, and for the 1969-79 decade, the average annual changes
in the four estimates ranged from 8.2 percent to 11.4 percent.(7)
Imputation for financial services.--Measuring the product of
banking has been a continuing source of bedevilment to economic
accountants. It is probably fair to say that no single solution to the
problem enjoys much enthusiastic support. (Other depository institutions
present similar problems. Historically the issue has been discussed
under the rubric of the "banking" imputation, and terminology
for that discussion is followed here for brevity). Banks make explicit
charges for some of the services that they render, but these charges are
by no means the bulk of their income. The bulk of their income is from
interest, dividends, and other property income. Because they pay much
less interest than they receive, the application of standard economic
accounting rules to banks leads to small or negative value added by the
industry.
The view that has been taken in economic accounting is that banks
make implicit charges for other services by paying out to depositors
less interest than they earn in the form of interest, dividends, and
other property income on deposited funds. The SNA and the NIPA's
impute an estimate of this implicit charge and include it in the gross
product of banking. The SNA and the NIPA's also impute an income
payment and include it in net interest paid by banking. In principle,
the imputations are equal to the difference between interest, dividends,
and other property income received on depositors' funds and
interest paid on depositors' funds.
The precise nature of the services for which the value is imputed
is not clear, however. Some explanations refer to the services of
liquidity provided by the financial institution. Others stress checking
and bookkeeping services or safety. In the NIPA's, these services
are assumed to be rendered to depositors; in the SNA, no explicit
allocation is made.
In the NIPA's, the value of these services is allocated to the
accounts of persons, government, business, and the rest of the world in
proportion to the deposit balances of each sector. For persons and for
government, expenditures are increased by the value of imputed bank
service charges paid, and incomes are increased by the (identical) value
of imputed interest received. The increased expenditures by these two
sectors lead directly to increased GDP. For businesses that receive
imputed interest, in contrast, the imputation has no effect on GDP: Net
interest of these businesses declines by the amount of imputed interest
received, but the decline is offset by the (identical) value of imputed
bank service charges paid. For the rest of the world, imputed bank
service charges paid by the rest of the world are considered to be
payments for exports of U.S. services, and higher exports lead directly
to higher GDP. These higher exports are not offset by higher imports
because imputed bank interest received by the rest of the world
(representing payments for U.S. imports of capital) is a part of that
sector's factor incomes, which are excluded from GDP.
The SNA does not allocate the imputation to specific sectors.
Instead, the SNA treats the entire imputation as interest paid by banks
to a dummy financial industry and as imputed service charges received by
banks from the dummy industry. Value added by banks increases by the
amount of the imputation, and value added by the dummy industry is
negative in the same amount. As a result, GDP is not affected by the
imputation.
Both the NIPA and the SNA imputations are open to criticism. Both
are complex and difficult to explain and both assign a value to a
service that is not clearly defined. In addition, the NIPA imputation
may be criticized both for assuming that services are rendered only to
depositors and for assuming that deposit balances (irrespective of the
turnover rates) are an appropriate indicator for allocating those
services. The SNA imputation may be criticized for adopting the
artificial device of a dummy industry.
Federal Government pensions.--In the NIPA's, the pension
component of compensation of Federal Government employees is measured by
the Federal Government's contributions to pension funds. In the
SNA, this component is measured by the benefits paid by the pension
fund.
To determine how to measure the pension component of employee
compensation, the SNA asks two questions. First, is the pension plan
funded--that is, does it maintain its assets separate from the
employer's? Second, are the assets of the pension fund invested
only in securities other than those of the employer? If the answer to
either of these questions is "no"--and the answer to the
second question is "no" for Federal Government pension funds,
which invest primarily in U.S. Government securities--then the SNA does
not regard the fund as separate from the employer. To portray the
outlays actually made, the SNA measures the pension component of
compensation by benefits paid.
In recent years, as benefits paid have exceeded employer
contributions, the effect of Federal pensions has raised SNA-basis GDP
relative to NIPA-basis GDP.
Differences that do not affect GDP
Some aspects of government activity are treated differently in the
NIPA's and the SNA without, however, affecting GDP. Adjustments
that affect components of GDP without affecting the total are identified
as shifts from government to other sectors in table 6. (Table 6 also
includes the other adjustments discussed so far.)
State and local government pension funds.--In the NIPA's,
pension funds for State and local government employees are classified
with government, and their administrative expenses are counted as
government purchases of goods and services. In the SNA, however, these
funds are classified along with private funds in the enterprise sector,
and their administrative expenses are counted as private final
consumption instead of government final consumption.(8) (The adjustment
is labeled "Other" in the personal/private consumption
expenditure reconciliation.) Likewise, saving of these funds is
classified as household, instead of government, saving (see the section
on differences in saving).
Some services provided by government for payment.--Goods and
services provided by government to persons for payment fall into three
general classes. The first two are treated similarly in the NIPA's
and the SNA, but the third is treated differently.(9)
First, fees are charged for some services that are strictly
governmental in nature. Examples include fees charged for passports and
drivers licenses. Both the NIPA's and the SNA treat these
transactions similarly; the fees do not represent private consumption in
either framework--they are a form of nontax payment to government in the
NIPA's and government fee in the SNA.
Second, government enterprises provide goods and services that are
very similar to those that are provided by private firms, and they
charge prices that are designed to cover a substantial portion of the
costs of providing the good or service. Examples include State liquor stores and the Tennessee Valley Authority. Purchases by households (and
businesses) from such enterprises are treated no differently than
purchases from private suppliers. Purchases by households enter the
NIPA's and the SNA as private consumption purchases from the
business sector.
Third, governments provide some services that are similar to
services provided by nonprofit organizations. Examples include services
of State universities, government recreational facilities, and public
hospitals. In the NIPA's, charges for these services are treated as
nontax payments and are not included in personal consumption
expenditures. Instead, these services enter GDP as government purchases,
valued at the cost to the government of providing the services. In the
SNA, the charges paid are considered private consumption expenditure;
the portion of the cost of providing these services that is not covered by consumer payments remains in government consumption expenditure.
U.S. military grant programs.--In the NIPA's, goods and
services transferred by the U.S. Government to foreign countries are
counted as government purchases. In the SNA, these transfers are counted
as exports. One rationale for the NIPA treatment is that these transfers
are made primarily to promote the security or other interests of the
United States and are made at the discretion of the U.S. Government.
(The adjustment is labeled "Other" in the exports
reconciliation in table 6.)
Differences in types of income and in saving
Types of income.--The discussion of GNP and GDP so far has dealt
with the product (or expenditures) components; summing these components
is the approach to measuring GNP or GDP most used in the United States.
Alternatively, gross product may be measured by summing value added
across industries. For this approach, both the SNA and the NIPA's
show compensation of employees, the consumption of fixed capital, and
indirect taxes less subsidies as charges against gross product. However,
the two systems differ in their presentation of the return to capital.
In the SNA, the production account's remaining component of
value added, the operating surplus, is defined as the return to
providers of all forms of capital. The disbursement of the operating
surplus, along with other sources of income, is shown in the income and
outlay accounts for the sectors and for the Nation. These accounts show
both receipts and payments of property income (interest, dividends, and
rent), of entrepreneurial income, and of miscellaneous income and
transfers.
In the NIPA's, the production account for the Nation is
combined with the income and outlay account for the business sector. As
a result, instead of showing an aggregate return to capital, this
account distinguishes corporate profits, proprietors' income, net
interest, rental income of persons, operating surplus of government
enterprises, and business transfer payments. Moreover, both the dividend
component of corporate profits and interest are measured net of receipts
of similar income.
Saving.--In both the SNA and the NIPA's, saving is derived as
the difference between current receipts and outlays. Total saving,
whether gross or net of capital consumption, is larger in the SNA than
in the NIPA's, because, as previously discussed, the SNA treats
government expenditures on nonmilitary structures and equipment as
investment and includes the consumption of this capital in the current
account, where it is included in government final consumption
expenditure.
The allocation of saving among sectors also differs substantially
between the SNA and the NIPA's. Table 7 shows a reconciliation of
NIPA and SNA net saving by sector. The largest sectoral difference is in
the treatment of State and local government pension funds; as mentioned
earlier, in the NIPA's, the saving of these funds is included in
government saving, and in the SNA, it is included in household saving.
Because these funds are currently running a substantial surplus, the
surplus in State and local government social insurance funds (and thus
government saving) is lower, and personal saving is higher, in the SNA
than in the NIPA's.
The table also shows two smaller differences. (1) In the
NIPA's, estate and gift taxes are included in personal outlays and
in government receipts and thus affect saving of the two sectors. In the
SNA, they are treated as capital transfers and, therefore, do not affect
saving. (2) In the NIPA's, government enterprises are given a mixed
treatment in which some types of transactions are recorded as if they
were part of the government sector and others as if they were part of
the business sector.(10) In the SNA, public enterprises are included in
the enterprise sector.
Differences in presentation
The extent of netting.--The SNA does not net offsetting
transactions to the same extent as the NIPA's. For example, the SNA
income and outlay account of the enterprise sector shows the receipt of
dividends on one side of the account and the payment of dividends on the
other. In contrast, the NIPA measure of corporate dividends is net
dividends paid (that is, dividends paid less dividends received). Thus,
enterprise income and total outlays in the SNA are larger than
comparable NIPA measures (although this difference in treatment does not
change sectoral saving).
Base year for constant-dollar estimates.--The base year for
calculation of constant-dollar estimates in the international
organizations' publications usually differs from that in BEA's
publications. Currently, the U.N. publications show 1980 as the base
year; the BEA publications shows 1982 as the base year. When BEA
converts NIPA 1982-dollar estimates to SNA 1980-dollar estimates, the
NIPA estimates are rebased at detailed expenditure levels. The year used
for the base period affects the levels of constant-price GDP (and
components) and the rates of growth calculated from them. Levels of
constant-price GDP usually are higher with a later base period because
inflation reduces the purchasing power of the unit of account--the
dollar, for example--in which it is measured. The later base period also
tends to result in lower rates of growth, reflecting the inverse
relationship between price and quantity changes that generally prevails
over long timespans.
Part 3. The Revision of the SNA
The revision of the SNA currently underway is based on a worldwide
review of progress in economic accounting over the last 20 years and of
the needs for domestic and cross-country analysis and policy
formulation. This part first describes the revision process. Next, it
describes some of the recommendations for revision. It illustrates the
definitional and classificational revisions with those that relate to
the issues discussed in part 2, and it summarizes some of the revisions
to the accounting structure that highlight the comprehensiveness of the
SNA and its flexibility. Finally, this part discusses the unresolved issues relating to the definition of investment and environmental
accounting.
Goals and organization of the revision
Early in the process, it was decided that the revision would not
make major conceptual changes or extensions. Instead, the revision would
update the SNA, clarify and simplify its presentation, and harmonize the
SNA with other international guidelines. The goal of updating the SNA
was to reflect new economic institutions, statistical developments, and
new analytical applications. For example, the SNA does not deal with the
value added tax, which is now widely used in Europe and which poses
difficulties for economic accounting. The goal of clarifying reflects a
widely felt need for a publication describing the system that is easier
to understand, and simplifying has come to be interpreted as the need
for a series of handbooks to explain how the system could be put into
practice. The harmonizing is to be with the guidelines for the System of
Balances of the National Economy, other international statistical
systems (such as the Balance of Payments Manual and A Manual on
Government Finance Statistics prepared by the International Monetary
Fund), and international classification systems (such as the
International Standard Industrial Classification of all Economic
Activities and the Classification of the Functions of Government).
The process has been planned and funded by the United Nations, the
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, the Statistical
Office of the European Communities, the International Monetary Fund, and
the World Bank. These organizations, operating through an
Inter-Secretariat Working Group, arranged a series of eight topical
"expert group" meetings beginning in 1986. These meetings
reviewed issues and made recommendations for revision. The participants
reflected the balancing of several perspectives--producers of economic
accounts and users, economic accounting generalists and specialists,
national statistical offices and international organizations. Five
"core" experts participated in all meetings to provide
continuity. Beginning in January 1989, the core experts were
supplemented by six other experts to become the "coordinating
group." This group will make recommendations on unresolved issues,
review drafts, and otherwise see the revision through to the end. U.N.
consultants--a primary author and several others doing selected
parts--are preparing a draft of the revised SNA manual. The drafting is
largely based on the recommendations made in the expert group meetings.
As of mid-1990, a provisional draft of the revised SNA manual and a
discussion paper prepared by the Inter-Secretariat Working Group are
being circulated to national statistical offices and will be discussed
in meetings of the U.N. regional commissions. A final draft of the
revised manual, reflecting comments on the provisional draft and
discussions in the coordination group, is to be submitted to the U.N.
Statistical Commission for approval in early 1993.
Recommendations for revision
The recommendations--which include several hundred individual
points--range from conceptual issues to specific treatments. Despite the
diversity, several themes have emerged; they include improving the
integration of flows and stocks, adapting the accounts to portray
economies experiencing inflation, improving the measurement of the
household sector, and updating the treatment of financial institutions
and transactions.
Several of these recommendations are related to issues discussed in
part 2, and they will serve to illustrate the kinds of definitional and
classificational revisions being considered.
* Reintroduce GNP as one of the family of aggregates.
However, because GNP is derived by adding net factor
income from the rest of the world to GDP, it would be
considered an income aggregate rather than a value
added aggregate (and it may be renamed gross national
income).
* Eliminate for government employee pension funds the
criterion of classification regarding the investment of
funds in the employer's own securities. (If the pension
fund invested only in the employer's securities, it was
classified in the sector of the employer.) Thus,
government employee pension funds that have been classified
in the government sector could be classified with other
pension funds in the enterprise sector.
* Broaden the definition of government capital
formation to include expenditure on goods purchased for the
military when the expenditure would be capital
formation if made by others. Continue to treat as current
expenditure only expenditure on goods used solely as
weapons and means of delivering weapons.
* Introduce the calculation of capital consumption
for government assets such as roads, dams, and
breakwaters.
* Retain the calculation of the imputed bank service
charge as property income received by financial
intermediaries less interest paid and, instead of using
the device of a dummy industry, allocate the service
charge--to be renamed the imputed service charge for
financial intermediation--among final consumption of
government and households, exports and imports, and
intermediate consumption of industry. The allocation
is to be based on the difference between (1) interest
flows actually paid on deposits and received on loans
and (2) corresponding interest flows calculated with
a central "reference" rate (such as interbank loan
rate or a prime rate). This approach to allocation
recognizes that different uses are accorded differing
amounts of service, reflecting the spread between the
actual interest rate paid or received and the reference
rate.
* Introduce imputed rent on buildings owned and
occupied by government. (As yet, however, the
recommendation has not been supplemented with an approach to
implementing it.)
The recommendations for the accounting structure are not
independent of the recommendations for the definitions and
classifications; by and large, the accounting structure can be viewed as
implementing the specific definitional and classificational
recommendations. Overall, the accounting structure is seen as having
four parts: (1) A central framework, which consists of a hierarchical
structure of classifications, sets of accounts, and sets of tables that
together, as a closed and articulated system, define the SNA; (2)
alternative matrix presentations, which are conversions of the accounts
in the central framework; (3) supplementary analyses, including
satellite accounts; and (4) links with other systems of statistics.
The recommendations for two parts of the structure will serve to
illustrate important characteristics of the revised system.
The sequence of accounts and the goods and services
accounts.--Within the central framework, the core of the system is the
"sequence of accounts" (table 8). This set of accounts is
pedagogical in intent, rather than for publication of estimates. It
demonstrates the comprehensive, integrated structure that is being
recommended: All transactions are recorded in it, and, in principle, the
sequence can be applied to all sectors (and subsectors) as well as to
the Nation.(11) A shortened sequence, accounts I and II.1.1, is to be
applied to industries.
The full sequence is an elaboration and refinement of the set of
accounts in the present SNA. (The production and the income and outlay
accounts shown in table 2 correspond to accounts I and II in table 8;
the capital accumulation, capital finance, and revaluation accounts in
table 2 correspond to accounts III.) The elaboration and refinement is
particularly noteworthy for the "distribution and use of income
accounts" and the "other changes in assets accounts."
The elaboration of the income accounts (accounts II) is designed to
improve the portrayal of the process of distributing and redistributing
income by separating it into steps. As the first step, the "primary
distribution of income accounts" show how value added, from the
production account, is distributed to labor and capital as factors of
production and to government. Second, the "secondary distribution
of income account" brings in cash income flows not related to
production; disposable income is the balancing item. Third, the
"redistribution of income in kind account" brings in social
benefits in kind and the value of services, such as education, provided
by government and nonprofit institutions to individual households; the
balancing item is adjusted disposable income. For the use of income, two
subaccounts correspond to the two measures of consumption--that is,
without and with the social benefits in kind--so that they show the same
measure of saving as their balancing items. (The introduction of
measures of income and consumption that include the value of services
provided by government and nonprofit institutions to individual
households is one of the major proposed revisions.)
The elaboration of the "other changes in assets accounts"
(accounts III.3) is central to the better integration of flows and
stocks and to the analysis of inflation. These accounts cover changes
other than those from saving and voluntary transfers of wealth; they
cover (1) discovery or depletion of subsoil assets, destruction by war,
natural disasters, etc., and (2) changes in the general price level and
in relative prices. The latter is in the revaluation account which shows
the changes in net worth from changes in the actual prices of assets and
liabilities. These nominal holding gains/losses are then separated into
two parts. Changes in net worth from changes in the general price
level--neutral revaluations--are obtained by applying an index of the
general price level to the opening value of all assets and liabilities.
Changes in net worth from changes in relative prices--that is, real
holding gains/losses--are obtained as the difference between nominal
holding gains/losses and neutral revaluations.
The central framework also includes a "goods and services
account," the key account in a set of accounts that are called
transactions accounts. This account records for the Nation the total
resources (output and imports) and total uses (intermediate consumption,
final consumption, changes in stocks, gross fixed capital formation, and
exports) of goods and services. It is balanced globally--that is, there
is a balance between all resources and all uses. (In contrast, the other
transactions accounts, which present total resources and total uses for
a particular kind of transaction, balance for each kind of transaction.)
Thus, the goods and services account summarizes the information in the
accounts for the sectors to yield a measure of national expenditure.
Satellite accounts.--One of the general recommendations is to
emphasize "flexibility" in the application of the SNA, thus
recognizing the diversity of the world's economies and statistical
systems. Satellite accounts are one of two major kinds of supplementary
analyses designed to implement this emphasis. (The other is the flexible
application of the central framework--for example, by using the
hierarchy of the central classification to provide more or less detail
or by using a complementary classification.)
A satellite account's basic element of flexibility is that it
can use definitions differing from those in the central framework as
long as they are consistent within the satellite account. Satellite
accounts can add information about a particular aspect of the economy to
that in the central framework; in particular, they can seek to integrate
monetary and physical data. They can arrange information
differently--for example, they can cut across sectors to assemble
information on both intermediate and final consumption. They can use a
classification other than the primary one used in the central
framework--for example, they can identify expenditure on "research
in education" as part of expenditure on research even if it is
included in expenditure on education in the central framework.
The recommendation to include satellite accounts builds on the
experiences of several countries that have constructed satellite
accounts, largely on an ad hoc basis, for such fields as health,
education, agriculture, research and development, and the environment.
The draft SNA manual includes a chapter that provides a general
framework and demonstrates how that framework might be used for some of
the fields in which satellite accounts would be most useful.
Outstanding issues
In several areas, final recommendations have not yet been made. One
of the areas deals with the extension of the concept of investment, now
essentially limited to outlays on structure and equipment, to include
outlays on research and development (R&D), mineral exploration,
computer software, and intellectual property such as films and sound
recordings.
The discussion about treating R&D as investment is
illustrative. The arguments for the change referred to R&D's
kinship with outlays on capital assets in that the purpose of both is to
generate income in future periods. Updating the definition of capital
formation was called for in light of studies that showed that R&D
outlays (and some other outlays on intangible assets) were important in
explaining economic growth. Several unofficial sets of accounts,
including those by Robert Eisner and John W. Kendrick for the United
States, have already included R&D as capital; a number of the
countries where R&D outlays are sizable have experience with data
collection using the guidelines drawn up by the Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development.
The arguments against the change centered on (1) the high degree of
uncertainty of return, which is one of the reasons given in the SNA to
explain the present convention; (2) the major break in continuity of
time series in the countries where most the world's R&D is
conducted (the change would raise GDP by 1 to 2 percent); (3) the
practical difficulties of calculating capital consumption and
constant-price estimates; and (4) the difficulty of identifying the
asset created by R&D outlays. Further, the conceptual basis for
including R&D outlays but not some other outlays--such as on
education and on literary and artistic work (for example, films and
sound recordings)--was questioned. Initially, the recommendation had
been to include R&D outlays as investment. Recently, an additional
difficulty has come to light: The guidelines for balance sheets include
patents (once purchased and sold), so including both what might be
called R&D assets and patents would lead to double-counting. Thus,
the earlier recommendation is being reviewed.
The treatment to be given natural resources and the environment in
the revised SNA is another area in which final recommendations have not
yet been made. The SNA is criticized because GDP, as now measured, is
seen as flawed in the way it treats environmental protection costs and
the degradation and depletion of natural resources. Adjustments for
"defensive expenditures" to restore and protect the
environment and for depletion and degradation of natural resources are
called for; only with the adjustments, it is argued, will a country know
the maximum amount that can be consumed without causing impoverishment
in the long run.
Especially since the early 1980's, international organizations
have made a substantial effort to develop environmental accounting. So
far, there has not been agreement on a recommendation to include any of
the suggested frameworks for environmental accounting in the new manual.
The argument that has prevailed is that too many questions of
identifying, defining, and measuring environmental issues are as yet
unresolved. Instead, the recommendation so far is that the new manual
should stress that GDP is not a measure of welfare and that care should
be taken in interpreting the accounts. More specifically, the new manual
is to discuss the interpretation of the main aggregates, such as GDP, in
relation to environmental degradation, depletion, and defensive
expenditures.
However, it is acknowledged that interest in environmental
accounting is growing. Concurrently, work in environmental accounting
continues, and the field may have progressed substantially by the time
the new manual is near completion. Two issues remain unresolved. What
balance should the new SNA manual strike in describing the strengths and
weaknesses of GDP? Can and should a framework for environmental
accounting, including an adjusted measure of GDP, be featured in
introducing and explaining satellite accounts? [Table 1 to 8 Omitted]
(1)The publication following that revision, often referred to as the
"Blue Book," can be taken as representing the present SNA; see
United Nations, A System of National Accounts, Studies in Methods,
Series F, No. 2, Rev. 3 (New York: United Nations, 1968). A subsequent
publication rounded out the guidelines on balance sheets; see United
Nations, Provisional International Guidelines on the National and
Sectoral Balance-Sheet and Reconciliation Accounts of the System of
National Accounts, Statistical Papers, Series M, No. 60 (New York:
United Nations, 1977). A useful overview of the present SNA is in
National Accounts Statistics: Main Aggregates and Detail Tables, 1986;
see the box "International Estimates of GNP and GDP." (2)For a
discussion of the principles of economic accounting with particular
reference to the United States, see "An Introduction to National
Economic Accounting" in the March 1985 SURVEY OF CURRENT BUSINESS.
This article, by Allan H. Young and Helen Stone Tice, is reprinted as
Methodology Paper Series MP-1 (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing
Office, 1985). (3)In fact, the integration is not yet complete, partly
because several unforeseen problems were encountered in developing
guidelines for balance sheets in the decade following the publication of
the guidelines for the flows. (4)The questionnaire for 1988, the most
recent year for which it is available, consisted of 66 tables. The
United States, like most countries, supplied considerably less than the
full set. The United States submitted 49 tables; 41 were derived from
the NIPA's, and 8 were derived from the Federal Reserve
Board's flow of funds accounts. (5)A standard package of computer
listings showing the conversion of annual NIPA estimates into 10 of the
major SNA tables is available from BEA. The cost is $25. New listings
are usually available in December, covering the same 4 years as the NIPA
estimates published the preceding July. Orders, accompanied by a check
or money order payable to Economic and Statistical Analysis/BEA, should
be addressed to the National Income and Wealth Division, BE-54, Bureau
of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce, Washington, DC 20230.
Custom computer listings, detailing other years (1960-88) or other SNA
tables, are available at cost. (6)Net factor income from abroad on the
SNA basis differs from that on the NIPA basis: (1) SNA-basis factor
incomes do not include reinvested earnings of direct investors and (2)
SNA-basis factor incomes do not include imputed interest (see the
section on the imputation for financial services). (7)Frank D. Martin,
J. Steven Landefeld, and Janice Peskin, "The Value of Services
Provided by the Stock of Government-Owned Fixed Capital in the United
States, 1948--79," The Review of Income and Wealth, Series 30
(September 1984): 346. (8)State and local government contributions to
pension funds are counted as part of government compensation in the SNA,
just as in the NIPA's. (9)For a discussion of the three classes in
the NIPA's, see U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis, Government Transactions, Methodology Paper Series MP-5
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1988): 5. (10)For a
discussion of the treatment of government enterprises in the
NIPA's, see U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis, Government Transactions, Methodology Paper Series MP-5
(Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1988): 6-8.
(11)However, not all transactions are relevant for all sectors, and,
similarly, not all accounts are relevant for all sectors. For example,
the use of income account, account II.4 in table 8, is relevant for the
sectors that engage in final consumption expenditure, but not for the
enterprise sectors, which do not engage in final consumption
expenditure.