Proactive measures of governmental debt guarantees to facilitate public-private partnerships project.
Tserng, Hui Ping ; Ho, Shih-Ping ; Chou, Jui-Sheng 等
Introduction
The role of Public-Private Partnerships (PPP) in providing public
services has become a common alternative for policy makers around the
world (Ock et al. 2005; Russell et al. 2006; Sungmin et al. 2009; Cheung
et al. 2010; Tang et al. 2010; Yuan et al. 2010). According to the
Private Participation in Infrastructure Database (WorldBank 2010),
investment commitments in PPP road projects grew from US$ 7 billion in
2005 to a new peak of US$ 16.7 billion in 2008. Solino and Vassallo
(2009) also observed that private participation in metropolitan
railroads through PPP method has gained the support of local government
due to the large and burdensome upfront investment costs.
Although the public sector is risk-averse and tries to transfer
most of risks to private in many PPP projects (Yuan et al. 2010),
government support for such projects is common in both developing and
developed countries, and is deemed as one of the critical success
factors (Chen, Doloi 2008; Chowdhury, Charoenngam 2009; Cheung et al.
2010). The literature proposes several explanations for this
governmental decision. However, past studies and practical cases
demonstrate that the good intentions of the government support may be
misused by the promoter due to moral hazard (Zhang 2005; Ho 2006; Chang,
Ive 2007; Irwin 2007). As noted by the OECD (2007), "The public
sector needs to realize that public guarantees of private commercial
behaviour can affect not only the degree of risk allocation and the
reporting of the investment as on or off budget, but, more importantly,
it can greatly affect the incentives of the private sector to accomplish
operational and administrative efficiencies."
Due to the highly diverse forms of government support, this study
focused on the Governmental Debt Guarantee (GDG). Because the GDG is the
key consideration of lenders when making loans to private promoters, it
significantly improves the bankability of PPP projects (PPIAF 2009).
However, implementing a GDG is a major challenge due to the increased
financial exposure of the government.
As Tang et al. (2010) argued when the government provides too much
guarantee, it would be easy for the concessionaire to get the benefit
from the contract at the expense of the public. This side effect of GDG
to the government is well known to the PPP experts, and a quick solution
according to their experience is to ask for a "sufficient"
equity investment from the promoter. Instead of this intuitional and
empirical answer, a literature review reveals the rationales have not
been systematically reviewed in a scientific manner. Subsequently, what
level of equity investment shall be considered as sufficient (i.e. 20%
or 30%) to mitigate opportunistic promoter behaviour in the case of GDG
has not been well examined. Few studies have proposed a practical and
quantitative method for the determination of this minimum equity
requirement from the government perspective. Moreover, what an
aggressive role the lenders can request from the government perspective
(as a debt guarantor) is also lack of discussion. Thus, more research
should be designed to find such an answer to facilitate the success of
PPP projects.
Therefore, this study is aimed at exploring the proactive measures
from the government perspective that could be embodied in the
contractual arrangements among the government, promoters and lenders in
a GDG to mediate counter party's opportunistic behaviour and to
enable a win-win-win situation. The scope of this GDG pilot study about
promoter opportunism is limited to the construction phase since lessons
learned from early projects suggest that the government can be taken
advantage of easily by profit-oriented promoter's behaviour in the
construction phase as presented in the next section.
This paper is divided into below sections. Following the
introduction, a literature survey is performed to identify the
rationale, potential benefits and problems of GDG in the scientific
context of Transaction Cost Economics (TCE) theory. Next, the research
design is briefly introduced. The Assistive Financing Mechanism adopted
by the Taipei City Government in twelve station PPP projects serves as a
case study in Section 3. Section 4 applies game theory to extract
valuable knowledge from the case study in a generic form and construct a
novel GDG model of quantitative conditions that encourage promoter
honesty. Based on the empirical case and developed model, Section 5
presents feasible measures toward the promoter and the lender for
harmonizing GDG provisions. Finally, conclusions are drawn, and
managerial implications and suggestions for future study are given.
1. Review of literature on Governmental Debt Guarantee
1.1. Why GDG
The importance of public support in promoting PPP projects
successfully is well acknowledged among policy makers, industrialists
and academics. For instance, public infrastructure mega-projects are
usually associated with huge capital investments and cannot be
financially freestanding from user charge while maintaining sustainable
fare policies (Devapriya 2006; Irwin 2007; Mandri-Perrott, Menzies
2010). Other current challenges to successful PPP project delivery
include limited access to project finance markets in developing
countries (Chen, Doloi 2008; Marin 2009), the bargaining outcome of best
risk allocation (Medda 2007; Chowdhury, Charoenngam 2009), and the
preference of lenders and the private sector for financing strategies
that mitigate political risk or financial risks (Devapriya 2006; Medda
2007). For example, Xu et al. (2010) concluded that the top two risk
groups of PPP highway projects in China were government intervention and
government maturity risk. Such public support may include equity
investment, tax and customs reduction, minimum revenue guarantees, loan
provision, capital subsidy and GDG (Zhang 2005; Wibowo 2006; Irwin 2007;
Chowdhury, Charoenngam 2009; Mandri-Perrott, Menzies 2010); and thus,
facilitate the progress of PPP projects.
Salman et al. (2007) observed that the common challenge for PPP
decision makers is to answer the question: "what are the conditions
needed and steps to be taken to improve project's viability?"
That is because many Build-Operate-Transfer (BOT) projects, one common
form of PPP, failed to be completed or were suspended because their
prior feasibility studies were insufficient to conclude the viability of
the entire undertaking. Furthermore, 21 significant factors which have a
certain impact on the feasibility of any BOT project were identified and
classified into three categories: legal and environment, financial and
commercial as well as technical aspects. Notably, expert opinions
collected by their research indicated that the financial and commercial
category of project viability factors is the most important (60.3%).
Two recent studies (Carrillo et al. 2008; Chan et al. 2010)
reported that the difficulty of finding financial partners due to their
limited interest is a key obstacle to PPP. Thus, the long and complex
procurement process, from preferred bidder stage to financial closing
stage, may cause substantial delays. Lenders with limited knowledge of
PPP prefer other investment alternatives (e.g. bond issues) than giving
loan to PPP projects unless their loan is well secured. Lenders clearly
consider GDG the second most important factor (after economic viability)
in their decision to lend because it reduces their risk in PPP financing
(Chiang, Cheng 2009). Even in the UK, which has a well-developed
financial market, direct government support for debt is the preferred
method for quickly implementing PPP in exceptional circumstances. After
the global financial market was seriously impacted by the 2008 Financial
Crisis, the UK government (HM Treasury 2009) temporarily intervened in
PPP projects for which sufficient debt financing could not be raised on
acceptable terms. Specifically, GDG strategy significantly reduces the
lender risk premiums associated with a loan and can increase the
financial viability of the project (Wibowo 2006; PPIAF 2008; Tang et al.
2010); therefore, GDG facilitates timely delivery of PPP projects from
the possible delay in loan acquisition.
1.2. Problems caused by GDG in the view of transaction cost
economics theory
1.2.1. Transaction cost economics
Transaction cost economics (TCE) was introduced by the publication
of "The Nature of the Firm" by Ronal Coase in 1937.
"Transaction cost" refers to the cost of using the price
mechanism or the cost of carrying out a transaction by means of an
exchange on the open market. North (1990) proposed that the key
transaction cost is the cost of acquiring information which consist of
the costs of measuring the valuable attributes of what is being
exchanged and the costs of protecting rights by policing and enforcing
agreements. Williamson (1996) then proposed that all transactions
between two parties involve hidden expenses called transaction costs
based on the assumption that human beings are bounded rationality and
sometimes display opportunistic behaviour.
Briefly, any exchange between two parties is a transaction.
Division of labour and specialization encourages transactions in society
(Dougma, Schreuder 2002). For example, completing the PPP project
required coordination among the government agency, promoter, designer,
contractor, lender, and operator. Each economic exchange between these
participants represents a transaction. From the TCE perspective,
transactions occur across markets or within organizations (defined as
hierarchies). Whether a transaction is allocated to the market or to a
hierarchy is a matter of cost minimization. Notably, transaction costs
should be considered because total cost is the sum of traditional
production costs and transaction costs (Grunegerg, Ive 2000). Comparing
the costs of managing transactions internally and externally may
indicate whether the goods or services should be produced in house
(defined as hierarchy) or purchased on the market. The TCE also enables
the design of an improved hybrid governance structure between market and
hierarchy (e.g. different contracts or organizations) that reduces
transaction costs. The TCE provides a conceptual framework for enhancing
economic performance by designing governance structures that reduce
transaction costs.
Dudkin et al. (2005) concluded that procurement-phase (including
bidding and contract negotiation) transaction costs comprise over 10
percent of the capital value of PPP projects. In post-contract stage,
the likelihood of incomplete contracts usually increases in long and
complex PPP projects. Therefore, anticipating all possible events during
the project lifetime is difficult. Some contractual agreements designed
to maximize ex-ante efficiency may result in ex-post inefficiency since
the value of the contract performance to the promise is lower than the
cost of performance incurred by the promisor (Solino, Vassallo 2009).
The opportunistic behaviours of individual parties trying to exploit a
situation for their own advantage increase the potential for high
transaction costs in the post contract stage of PPP projects, which is
known as the hold-up problem (Zhang 2005; Ho 2006; Chang, Ive 2007;
Irwin 2007; Ho, Tsui 2010).
When two contracting parties enter the post-contract stage, both
try to maximize their own profits by opportunistically exploiting
unforeseen events that are not governed by the original contract. The
party that tends to be disadvantaged is the one that has less bargaining
power and is susceptible to the hold-up problem. This occurs because
bargaining power is inversely related to the commitments/investments of
a party to that particular transaction (e.g. PPP project). In this
inverse relationship, the so-called asset specificity problem is that
the counter party can credibly threaten to terminate the transaction
(project), which can cause a huge loss, especially if the value of
alternative uses for the commitments/investments is relatively small.
Briefly, hold-up refers to action by the counter party to exploit the
situation and to appropriate the expected profit by threatening to walk
away from the relationship.
The model proposed by Chang and Ive (2007) captured the increased
vulnerability of project owners in the post-contract stage when the
initial requirements must be changed after signing the contract and when
transaction costs are high. Specifically, when the owner issues a change
order, the contractor tends to ask for a price higher than the general
market price because the contractor knows that the owner is held up. The
owner tends to accept the price demanded by the contractor unless the
cost of acceptance exceeds the cost of any one of the following: 1) the
loss incurred by abandoning the work in progress; 2) the cost of
switching to another contractor; or 3) the cost of using dispute
resolution mechanism plus the cost of settlement. To avoid delay and
further costs, the owner usually prefers not to abandon the
construction-in-progress, let alone switch contractors or use a dispute
resolution mechanism. Therefore, the party with less bargaining power
may take expensive measures to mitigate vulnerability to the hold-up
problem, which thus increases transaction costs.
In this discussion, governance structure refers to the GDG direct
agreement among the government, the Project Company funded by the
promoters, and the lender. It determines the relationship between
interested parties after a termination or threatened termination due to
Project Company Default. In this study, TCE is used to explore the
proper governance structure (the direct agreement) that harmonizes
government transaction costs in PPP projects with GDG.
1.2.2. Reduced cost borne by the promoter under GDG
A PPP project is typically financed by a combination of equity and
debt. Equity holders (Promoters) are entitled to share in profits but
may only do so after lenders receive their due interest. In a winding
up, they are entitled to the balance of the realized net assets after
lenders have been paid; thus, promoters may get nothing in return for
their investment in bad times. Therefore, the amount of their investment
determines the value of their assets specific to the success of the PPP
project in which they invested.
Despite the benefits of GDG, the promoter's long term
commitment to the performance of PPP project with GDG shall be
significantly reduced if the contractual arrangement (i.e. governance
structure) is poorly designed. Specifically, the construction
profit-oriented behaviour by promoters is encouraged. Figure 1 shows
that, when a PPP strategy is used in transportation construction
projects, contractors and rolling-stock providers are often the
promoters in the consortium. Because they are the major Project Company
shareholders, the sub-contracts for construction work and equipment are
normally awarded to them at prices above market prices due to the lack
of open competition (Ho, Tsui 2010). Such promoters are considered
short-term investors (Zhang 2005) because their equity contributions to
the Project Company are generally recovered from earnings on
construction activities.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The literature also indicates that such government-backed projects
often "deteriorate" because the promoter tends to exaggerate
the debt-carrying capacity of the project whereas the lender may not
examine the project rigorously. The lack of due diligence often results
in financing with a high debt-to-equity ratio, which enables short-term
promoters to undertake large construction activities with small equity
contributions.
Askar and Gab-Allah (2002) argued that a minimum (or reasonable)
level of equity is generally needed to convince the lender that the
project is creditworthy and therefore bankable and financeable. Bakatjan
et al. (2003) later developed a program for optimizing the capital
structure of BOT projects from the "promoter" perspective.
That is Debt Service Coverage Ratio (DSCR), i.e. the ratio of annual
cash available at hand to annual total debt service. Sungmin et al.
(2009) presented a model to optimize the developer's equity level
for privately financed infrastructure projects via Monte Carlo
simulation. Furthermore, an appropriate concession period can be deduced
basing on the fuzzy simulation model proposed by Ng et al. (2007) or the
simulation-based approach proposed by Zhang and AbouRizk (2006).
However, none of them has proposed a practical and quantitative method
to the government for the determination of minimum equity investment
from the promoter.
1.2.3. Increased transaction costs borne by the government agency
under GDG
Abandoning a PPP project is rarely feasible because of the huge
loss of socio-economic-political benefits. Moreover, to reap such
benefits, the public sector always strives to complete the project and
to provide the service on time. Thus, given the long duration and
complexity of a PPP, both the cost of switching promoters and the cost
of using dispute resolution mechanisms are higher than those in ordinary
construction projects because of time constraints.
Particularly, for a PPP project with GDG, the government
immediately bears the huge debt liability should it choose to terminate
the contract either after a promoter default or after an unforeseen
event that is advantageous to the promoter. Therefore, as asset
specificity increases, the transaction costs and the vulnerability of
the government also increase. In a GDG without a well-designed
governance structure, hold-up problem for the government agency is worse
than that in an ordinary construction or PPP project because the asset
specificity of promoters is reduced whereas that of the government is
increased.
1.3. Real cases facing problems caused by GDG
Indeed, whether to provide GDG in PPP projects is a major policy
dilemma. One representative case is the Taiwan High Speed Rail BOT
Project (THSRP). In the financial package proposed by the consortium
(MOTC 2010), total capital investment was US$ 13.54 billion financed
through equity (US$ 3.45 billion) and debt (US$ 10.09 billion). During
contract negotiations, the government authority agreed with the
consortium that no lender should lend money without a GDG. Thus, the
direct agreement signed by the government authority, Project Company,
and lenders set the bailout cap at US$ 10.83 billion (Li 1998). The
agreement for the US$ 10.74 billion loan to the Project Company was then
signed. According to the government authority, the GDG for the THSRP was
justified by the vast social and economic benefits expected from the
project. It avoided delays caused by switching to alternative
procurement approaches. The internal and external values of early
completion to the public clearly outweigh the contingent government
liability.
However, controversy happened during the building phase. An
official report by the Control Yuan, which is the highest auditing
organization in the Taiwan government, indicated that a THSRP promoter
undertook US$ 854 million in construction work whereas its equity
contributions to Project Company were only US$ 139.5 million. Because
the initial equity investment from the consortium members corresponded
to only about 6% of the loan the Project Company eventually took out, it
may give the members only a modest sum at risk, compared to construction
profits they earned. Subsequently, the promoters were reluctant to
inject any money when the government asked them to honour the
contractual requirement of one-quarter equity. Eventually, this equity
gap was invested by state-owned companies and government-controlled
banks. Another case is the railway guarantees in Russia (Irwin 2007),
which encouraged Project Company managers appointed by the controlling
shareholders to exploit the Project Company and the government agency by
paying inflated prices to suppliers and construction companies belonging
to controlling shareholders.
2. Research design
The research framework of this study included "case study
approach" and "game theory analysis". Firstly, a series
of Taipei Mass Rapid Transit (MRT) station PPP projects with a
particular GDG mechanism serve as the exploratory cases. These cases
provide valuable insights in dealing with the hold-up problem facing the
government in a GDG. However, where studies relied on case study only,
the further application of their findings are usually restricted because
contract arrangements are project specific and sensitive to the
different context of the host country.
In this sense, following the findings from case study, the research
process was continued by modelling the GDG on the basis of game theory.
The advantage of introducing a game-theoretic approach, as noted by Aoki
(2008), is the intuitively appealing and plausible notion that
institutional interdependencies, coherence and robustness are considered
analytically tractable rather than ad hoc presumptions. Notably, game
theory serves as a vehicle to extract the underlying principles from the
Taipei metro practitioners' experience; therefore, the constructed
model is generic and can broaden its application scope to other types of
PPP projects in other countries.
Game theory can be defined as the study of mathematical models of
conflict and cooperation between intelligent rational decision-makers
(McCain 2004). It provides a systematic and conceptual framework for
optimizing the strategy of a participant in response to the strategies
of all other participants (Ho 2006). All players are assumed to be
rational and self-interested in their pursuit of maximum payoff. There
are two basic types of games: static games and dynamic games, in terms
of the timing of decision making. In a static game, the players act
simultaneously, meaning that each player chooses his/her action without
knowing others'. On the contrary, the players act sequentially and
observe other players' actions in previous moves in a dynamic game.
Because the promoters make the decisions on the sharing of knowledge
after observing the GDG option taken by the government, the dynamic game
will be used for modelling and analysis in this study.
In order to answer what each participant will behave in this GDG
game, the concept of "Nash equilibrium", one of the most
important concepts in game theory is introduced. The Nash equilibrium is
a set of actions that will be chosen by each player. In other words, in
the Nash equilibrium, each player's strategy should be the best
response to the other player's strategy, and no player wants to
deviate from the equilibrium solution. Thus, the equilibrium or solution
is "strategically stable" or "self-enforcing"
(Gibbons 1992). In a dynamic game, the Nash equilibrium is a subgame
perfect Nash equilibrium, which satisfies the sequential rationality
required for the solution of a dynamic game. For more information about
the game theory analysis and its application, readers are suggested to
refer to Ho et al. (2011) and Tserng et al. (2012).
3. Case study
3.1. Background of Taipei MRT station PPP cases
After about 20 years development, the network of Taipei MRT lines
that have been completed for commercial service is 106.4 km, with over
1.3 million passenger trips per day on average (DORTS 2011). In order to
release the huge financial burden of the government during the
construction, property development around/above MRT stations was
considered as a feasible solution to internalize the external benefit
that results from investments in MRT system. Moreover, those stations
can also be built by the property developers without the money coming
from the government's pocket. A dedicated regulation was
established (e.g. Regulation for the Development of Land Adjacent to or
Contiguous with MRT System) at the beginning to form the legal basis
covering related issues of planning, application, evaluation, land
acquisition, land use, guarantee bonds, incentives, monitoring, etc.
From the perspective of the Taipei City Government, the ideal
scenario for enhanced cost-effectiveness and efficiency is for
landowners to offer land and for promoters to fund the integral
planning, design and construction of the MRT stations. This
joint-development approach which belongs to the PPPs concept reduces the
financial burden on the Government and applies the skills and knowledge
of promoters, which may not be available from the public sector.
Although this idea was implemented, the results were disappointing. One
major reason was that the promoters had difficulty obtaining loans
because banks were unfamiliar with the novel proposal and were reluctant
to make non-collateralized loans.
Thus, the Taipei City Government proposed an assistive financing
mechanism, a particular form of GDG, in 2003 after one year preparation
and communication with promoters and bankers. As of the end of 2010,
promoters in twelve station projects have used this mechanism to obtain
more than US$ 898.9 million in loans as summarized in Table 1. They are
Muzha Station, Yongchun Station (Zone 19), Yongchun Station (Zone 21),
Houshanpi Station (Zone 25), Taipei Main Station (T 9), Xindian City
Office (Zone 22), Qizhang Station (Zone 10, 11), Wanlong Station (Zone
10), Gongguan Station (Zone 11), Xingtian Depot (Zone 17, 18, 19),
Xingtian Temple Station (Zone 5) and Xingtian Temple Station (Zone 7).
The assistive financing mechanism used in these twelve station
projects was selected as an exploratory case for the following two
reasons: firstly, of these twelve projects, nine were successfully
delivered while three are currently nearing completion. Until now, none
has been terminated early, and, therefore, none has required a
government bailout. The successful use of this assistive financing
mechanism confirmed its validity.
Secondly, in order to insure that all participants fulfil their
contractual obligations without failure, a trust organization is used
which form a particular contractual complexity beyond what is considered
standard practice in PPP projects. As presented in Figure 2, the
contractual framework including "PPP Agreement", "Loan
Agreement", "Direct Agreement" and "Trust
Agreement" is more complex than that of common PPP projects as
presented in the upper part of the Figure 1 (without Trust Agreement).
The results of the case study, which included a detailed review of
official meeting minutes and terms of direct agreement and trust
agreement, in conjunction with face-to-face interviews with basic-level
and high-ranking officials responsible for establishing and implementing
the assistive financing mechanism, are given below.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
3.2. Introduction of assistive financing mechanism
Figure 3 shows the implementation procedures for the mechanism. The
Taipei City Government, the bank, and the promoter in the Project
Company contractually agree to how their relationship would be affected
by a termination or by a threatened termination after promoter default.
Essentially, the Taipei City Government guarantees the loan to the
Project Company whereas both the bank and the promoter commit to the
following complementary measures.
If a promoter default leads to early termination of the PPP
agreement in the construction phase (e.g. if the promoter cannot raise
the required equity investment), the City Government "may"
terminate the PPP agreement. In this case, the City Government must
purchase the work-under-construction at a "compensation
payable" purchase price. After deducting a penalty for promoter
breach of contract (30% of the agreed "compensation payable",
which is equal to total equity investment), the priority of the City
Government is to repay the loan to the bank.
Instead of terminating the PPP, the City Government "may"
choose to fill the gap in promoter equity. The direct agreement requires
the bank to continue disbursing the loan. Upon completing the
construction work, the market value of the project should far exceed
that at the time of promoter default due to lack of a liquid market for
incomplete construction projects. This ensures the completion of the
development project, which is the objective of the Government.
The following clauses are added to the PPP agreement to comply with
the principles of the above direct agreement: 1) Project Company should
entrust all sources of funds (equity from the promoter and loans from
the bank) and rights to a trust organization; 2) the bank must be
included as a beneficiary of the All Risk Insurance held by the
Contractor. The insurance claim must be managed in an individual account
and can be used to pay for necessary repairs or reconstruction of target
projects. The above trust system has three advantages: 1) The promoter
equity and the bank loan are managed in an individual account, which
ensures that the Project Company uses the funds appropriately; 2) The
actually cumulative expenditures on the construction work are clearly
identified, so compensation payable in the event of early termination is
easily determined; 3) It prevents lender foreclosures or provisional
seizures of the work under construction when the promoter has financial
difficulties. Therefore, it limits interruptions of project progress.
Limitations of this mechanism are as follows: 1) The City
Government provides GDG in the construction phase only (no revenue
guarantee in the operation phase). This mechanism can be considered a
government assurance of completion. Fortunately, since the financial
pressure on PPP projects is highest in the construction phase before
revenue is generated, the limited scope of the application is
appropriate in most cases. 2) Although GDG can reduce funding costs,
complementary measures such as employment of the trust organization
increase administration and monitoring costs. Therefore, the trade-off
between capital costs and administration and monitoring costs should be
carefully considered. From the perspective of promoters who can secure
their own bank financing, GDG is inappropriate because it increases
their costs. In the case of the Taipei MRT stations, promoters in about
one-third (12 of 39) projects have requested GDGs. 3) The government
agency should consider this mechanism a last resort for project
financing because the government agency must assume the debt in the
worst-case scenario. A thorough evaluation is needed in the planning
phase to confirm the financial feasibility and construction costs of the
project and to minimize government risk.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
3.3. Analysing the underlying principles of assistive financing
mechanism
The authors view this governance structure as a
"conditional" GDG. These complementary measures enable the
government to balance hold-up and bargaining power when managing the
construction profit-oriented behaviour of the promoter and to avoid
inheriting the debt left by the promoter.
3.3.1. Increasing the cost of the promoter
The transaction cost of the promoter can be increased because the
asset specificity of the promoter can be increased in this governance
structure. Several approaches are possible:
Appropriately require minimum promoter equity: Promoter equity
should be at least 30%. Additionally, the bank should only be allowed to
disburse the loan after the promoter commits at least half of the agreed
funding. Additionally, the disbursement of loans should be proportional
to the amount committed. The rationale is that promoters should kick-off
the construction work with their own money. Unless the promoter provides
15% of total project capital, the bank loan can be used to inject funds
proportionally. Regarding why a 30% equity level is required for Taipei
cases, no concrete reason can be found in the documents. Is it too
conservative or too risky? A scientific model will be introduced to
bridge the empirical findings based on game theory in Section 4, and
thus, the "appropriate" minimum equity requirement can be
determined not only in Taipei cases but also in other PPP projects.
Meaningfully penalize promoter default: The agreed penalty for
early termination caused by promoter default is 30% of payable
compensation. The penalty ratio is set intentionally the same as the
required equity ratio. If the City Government must take over the
project, the invested funds by the promoter become a sunk cost; this
increases the asset specificity of a promoter who is considering walking
away from a project that is currently underway.
Carefully determine the amount of compensation: If the promoter
inflates the construction fee, the City Government overpays for the
project. Thus, the amount of compensation payable upon early termination
is determined by whichever of the following is lower: 1) Planned
expenditures on construction: this amount is based on the investment
execution plan approved by the City Government and is the cumulative
construction cost as of the time of early termination. 2) Actual
expenditures on construction: the trust organization must present
receipts from all manufactures and contractors on behalf of the Project
Company. A professional and independent third party should be
commissioned for due diligence. Finally, these expenditures must be
approved by the bank and the City Government.
3.3.2. Reducing the transaction cost of the government agency
The switching cost is usually the upper limit of the amount that
the promoter can take advantage of the government in the event of
ungovernable contingencies (Chang, Ive 2007). The government hold-up
problem is reduced because the switching cost is better managed by:
Against the promoter: The penalty for early termination due to
promoter default is 30% of payable compensation. This amount should be
sufficient for the government agency to find an alternative promoter.
Against the banker: The direct agreement provides that the City
Government can fill the funding gap when the promoter encounters
financial difficulties and that the bank must disburse the loan
continuously. Thus, the government avoids the immediate budgetary burden
of paying out the promoter debt. Moreover, the direct agreement should
ensure that the interest rate from this point should be lower than that
for the promoter.
4. The GDG game
4.1. Model setup
The two participants in this game are the Government (GOV) and the
Promoter, and the GDG is the security package required by the lender.
Accordingly, GOV must first determine whether to provide the GDG. The
strategic choices of the Promoter are either honour (by performing the
PPP agreement in good faith) or exploit (by hold-up or other
opportunistic behaviours). When analysing holdup coupled with
construction profit-oriented intention, the associated business of the
Promoter is assumed to be relevant to that PPP project (e.g. the
contractor or equipment provider). Meanwhile, the sub-contracts are
awarded to the business associates of the Promoter.
In this sequential game, the GOV moves first, and Promoter observes
the GOV action before choosing a strategy. Figure 4 shows the extensive
form. Suppose that early termination after Promoter default occurs in
the construction phase. The GOV then takes over the project after
providing compensation (denoted by EV) to the Promoter, and the Promoter
is liable for the agreed penalty, which is equal to the equity level
([alpha]). Eqn (1) formulates the relationship, where AC = the actual
cost of construction work performed, i.e. total costs incurred by the
contractor to complete work during a given time period; EV = the earned
value, also called the budgeted cost of construction work performed,
i.e. total expenditures paid by the Project Company to the contractor
during a given time period; RCP = reasonable construction profit margin
when an open tendering procedure is used; k = inflated construction
profit margin resulting from limited tendering procedure in which only
one contractor is invited to tender an offer for the construction work.
Basically, AC and EV used above are drawn from (PMI 2004):
EV = AC (1 + RCP + [kappa]). (1)
Other abbreviations are used in the model: a = equity level, equity
= [alpha] x EV, and debt finance = (1 - [alpha]) x EV; NPV = the
expected net present value of the PPP project; [beta] = the ratio of
project value shared by GOV to NPV, which is decided through open
competition of that PPP project; r = interest rate of the debt (since
the debt is guaranteed by GOV, where r should approximate the nominal
yield of bond depending on the GOV's creditworthiness); G = the
smallest GOV subsidy needed to persuade the lending bank to continue
supporting a project after Promoter default; [tau] = opportunity cost
for the GOV to replace the promoter, which may include the retendering
cost and the cost of interruption due to the bankruptcy and retendering
process; [lambda] = cost of administering GDG.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
4.2. Propositions and discussions
Proposition 1: Where p[alpha] > 1 - 1/(1 - r)(1 + RCP + [kappa])
the dominant strategy for the Promoter is to honour the contract when
GOV chooses to provide GDG.
Proof: A dominant strategy is the strategy that is the best
response to all possible strategy choices of all the other players
(Carmichael 2005). By direct verification, Promoter chooses the
"honour" strategy only if it yields a higher payoff compared
to "exploit". That is:
AC(RCP + [kappa]) - [alpha]EV - r(1 - [alpha])EV< (1 -
[beta])NPV. (2)
Since GOV and Promoter never promote a project with negative NPV,
replace NPV = 0 (the worst case for
GOV) in Eqn (2):
then AC(RCP + [kappa]) - [alpha]EV - r(1 - [alpha])EV < 0; (3)
AC(RCP + [kappa]) - [alpha]EV - rEV + r [alpha] EV < 0; (4)
AC(RCP + [kappa]) - rEV - [alpha] (1 - r)EV < 0, (5)
then [alpha](1 - r) EV > AC(RCP + [kappa]) - rEV, (6)
substitute Eqn (1) into Eqn (6):
then [alpha] > 1 - 1/(1 - r)(1 + RCP + [kappa]) (Q.E.D.). (7)
Discussion: Since the contingency is that GDG is provided, the
rational Promoter maximizes the payoff. The preferred Promoter response,
honour or exploit, depends on which yields the higher payoff. The GOV is
suggested to think strategically and to anticipate how a Promoter would
respond to the offer of a GDG. In short, Eqn (7) indicates the best
protective measure for the government even when NPV equals 0. The
government should request an equity level appropriate for the given
values of r, RCP and k. The outcome (Eqn (7)) of the game proposed in
this study can supplement the theoretical gap in the case study, which
is based on expert rules of thumb. The simplified formulation applied to
the Taipei MRT station experience can be expanded to other PPP projects
across different infrastructure sectors.
Proposition 2: Suppose that Proposition 1 holds and that G, [tau],
[lambda], and r = 0 for GOV The subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium for GOV
and Promoter is (Provide, Honour). Proof: A Nash equilibrium is
subgame-perfect if the player strategies constitute a Nash equilibrium
in every subgame (Gibbons 1992). The authors solve this game by
backwards induction as follows. Because Proposition 1 holds, the unique
solution for the Promoter optimization problem in the second stage of
the game is honour. Since GOV can anticipate the Promoter reaction to
each GOV action at the first stage, the GOV must decide how to maximize
its payoff. Briefly, the "provide" strategy shall be a
dominant strategy if it yields a higher GOV payoff compared to the
"not provide" strategy. Since PNPV [the corresponding payoff
for GOV for (provide, honour)] exceeds 0 [the payoff for GOV at not
provide], provide must be the dominant strategy for GOV if AC - (1 -
[alpha]) EV - G - [tau] - [lambda] [the payoff for GOV at (provide,
exploit)] is no less than 0 [the payoff for GOV at not provide]. Because
Proposition 1 holds, Eqns (1) and (7) above are substituted into Eqn AC
- (1 - [alpha])EV - G - [tau] - [lambda]; moreover, if G, [tau], and
[lambda] = 0, then:
Payoff GOV = 1 - 1/(1 - r). (8)
If r = 0, then Payoff GOV = 0 (i.e. provide is the dominant
strategy for GOV).
Therefore, the backwards-induction outcome of this game is
(provide, honour) with the corresponding payoffs [PNPV, (1 -
[beta])NPV]. Further, in this two-stage game of complete and perfect
information, the backwards-induction outcome is the subgame-perfect Nash
equilibrium defined by Gibbons (1992) (Q.E.D.).
Discussion: The assumptions in Proposition 1 and Proposition 2
protect the GOV from the pitfalls of a GDG. The exploratory cases
demonstrate a practical application of these theoretical assumptions.
The direct agreement commits the lending bank to disbursing the loan
only if the City Government chooses to step in (G = 0). Additionally,
the Promoter penalty is equal to the project equity (30%), which should
adequately compensate the City Government for the total costs of
replacing the promoter, administering the government guarantee, and
paying the interest on the debt ([tau], [lambda], and r = 0,
respectively). If the lender or promoter declines to commit, GOV has no
dominant strategy because its payoff from "provide" may be
smaller than that from "not provide". Thus, the game may be
terminated, meaning both the participants and the lender leave with
"zero" payoff. To obtain a win-win-win outcome (i.e. [PNPV, (1
- [beta])NPV, r(1 - [alpha])EV]) among GOV, Promoter and the lender, the
best response by the three participants is agreeing to the above
complementary measures because the payoff matrix of this cooperative
solution outweighs that of non-cooperation.
5. Suggested proactive measures and applications
According to the literature, case study and theoretical model, the
transaction cost resulting from asset specificity for the government,
the promoter and the lender can be balanced concurrently in GDG by a
properly designed governance structure. The government should request
all participants to commit to the project unanimously. The payoff matrix
(i.e. [[beta]NPV, (1 - [beta])NPV, r(1 - [alpha])EV] among GOV, Promoter
and the lender) for this cooperative solution shows that the bonding
arrangement under the proposed scheme benefits all participants.
1. Requesting sufficient promoter equity
In accordance with proven proposition 1 and innovative Eqn (7), the
sufficient equity level of the promoter should be required by the
government can be calculated based on r, RCP and [kappa]. The value of r
(the interest rate of the debt) can be set to the nominal yield of
government bonds. That is because they are guaranteed by the government
as well. In this case, the default risk of the debt perceived by the
lenders should be similar to that of the government bond. Therefore, a
similar risk premium is required. The value of RCP can be set to the
average profit margin of listed companies whose main business is
relevant to the construction work, such as building contractors, civil
engineering contractors, design-build firms, etc. The value of k can set
to the average ratio of tender awarding value to budget value in
previous government procurement projects. The GOV can also apply the
cost estimation tools and techniques proposed in the PMBOK Guide (PMI
2004), including analogous estimating, parametric modelling, bottom-up
estimating, and computerized tools, in order to estimate k accurately.
Table 2 is a minimum equity level matrix for r = 2%. For example, if RCP
and k equal 10% and 30%, respectively, the government should require
minimum promoter equity of 27%. The proposed equation is not only
practicable for policy makers but also scientifically proven as a
self-enforcing Nash equilibrium which can avoid the subjective or
intuitional determination based on rules of thumb.
The detailed contract arrangements drawn from the exploratory cases
can then be considered in line with the characteristics of each PPP
project application. For example, the penalty for breach of contract can
be based on the required minimum equity level; the payable compensation
can be set to planned or actual expenditure, whichever figure is lower.
The Project Company should also entrust its funds and rights to a trust
organization through the trust agreement.
2. Preventing lender withdrawal
Proposition 2 which has been proven suggests that measures
complementary to a GDG should manage the government's cost of
persuading the lender to continue supporting a project after promoter
default (G). Since it must pay out the secured debt immediately, the
government is vulnerable to a lender exercising its power to withdraw
funds. The detailed contractual structure in the case study shows that,
if the government chooses to take over a project, the lender should be
obligated to continue providing the loan. The interest rate should also
be determined in advance.
Conclusions
The public sectors should refine their strategies for delivering
better Public-Private Partnerships (PPP) projects by reviewing empirical
cases and theoretical foundations given the fact that PPP is now used to
finance infrastructure projects worldwide. In order to prevent the
financial bailout of the government from the promoters'
opportunistic behaviour in a Governmental Debt Guarantee (GDG) PPP
project, this study used case study and game theory for developing
generic and proactive measures for the government that complement GDG in
the construction phase. This generic GDG model and suggested proactive
measures have been proven based on game theory as a self-enforcing Nash
equilibrium. This model can bridge the theoretical gaps in the case
study and broaden its application.
Contractual arrangements for two proactive measures against to the
promoter and the lender respectively are proposed to enable policy
makers to mitigate their financial exposure risk in GDG. The authors
propose an innovative and practicable equation for quantitatively
calculating the minimum equity level of the promoter should be requested
by the government in response to r (interest rate of the debt), RCP
(reasonable construction profit margin through open tendering procedure)
and k (inflated construction profit margin resulting from limited
tendering procedure). The government should require the promoter to meet
this minimum equity level. Instead of requiring the government to pay
out the secured debt immediately, the contract should also require the
lender to continue providing the loan if a government takeover occurs
after promoter default.
According to transaction cost economy (TCE), the suggested measures
complementary to GDG can harmonize the transaction costs of the
government agency. However, both the transaction costs of the promoter
and the lenders resulting from asset specificity increase concurrently.
Briefly, the proposed governance structure is a mutual hold-up
structure. Since all parties involved increase their commitments, the
proposed contractual arrangements give all parties an incentive to make
the project work by placing their investment at risk. Notably, GDG is
one out of many types of government supports for PPP. All participants
should recognize the pros and cons of each type of government support;
and furthermore, choose the proper type of government support according
to the attributes of each project.
The findings of this study are valuable for both PPP experts and
researchers. In practice, the conceptual idea that a minimum equity
investment is essential to the success of a PPP project based on rules
of thumb has been enhanced with scientific rigorousness. Experts can
determine a specific ratio about what quantitative level is sufficient
to protect the government from the opportunistic behaviour of the
promoter. Moreover, the role of the lenders can be also taken into
consideration in a GDG case. Properly bridging the theoretical gap would
provide them with comprehensive knowledge and the capability to apply
the findings and suggestions in the case study to specific contexts in
their own countries.
Academically, the valuable experience distilled from the case study
approach is interpreted in light of the TCE. Subsequently, the game
theory methodology is adopted. Unlike superficial reasoning based on
intuition, the game equilibrium view of GDG as well as case study
evidence convincingly support the conclusions of this study. The
proposed methodologies and research flow for combining case study, TCE
and game theory provide researchers in construction field a useful tool
for analysing similar contractual issues. Future studies may apply the
proposed methodologies and research flow for indepth analysis of
opportunistic promoter behaviour in the operation phase of PPPs with
GDG. Such studies could reveal measures complementary to GDG in
different stages of a PPP life cycle.
References
Aoki, M. 2008. Analysing institutional change: integrating
endogenous and exogenous views, in Kornai, J.; Matyas, L.; Roland, G.
(Eds.). Institutional change and economic behaviour. New York: Palgrave
Macmillan, 113-133.
Askar, M. M.; Gab-Allah, A. A. 2002. Problems facing parties
involved in build, operate, and transport projects in Egypt, Journal of
Management in Engineering 18(4): 173-178.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)0742597X(2002)18:4(173)
Bakatjan, S.; Arikan, M.; Tiong, R. L. K. 2003. Optimal capital
structure model for BOT Power projects in Turkey, Journal of
Construction Engineering and Management 129(1): 89-97.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)0733-9364(2003)129:1(89)
Carmichael, F. 2005. A guide to game theory. Harlow: Financial
Times Prentice Hall. 286 p.
Carrillo, P.; Robinson, H.; Foale, P.; Anumba, C.; Bouchlaghem, D.
2008. Participation, barriers, and opportunities in PFI: the United
Kingdom experience, Journal of Management in Engineering 24(3): 138-145.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)0742597X(2008)24:3(138)
Chan, A. P. C.; Lam, P. T. I.; Chan, D. W. M.; Cheung, E.; Ke, Y.
2010. Potential obstacles to successful implementation of public-private
partnerships in Beijing and the Hong Kong special administrative region,
Journal of Management in Engineering 26(1): 30-40.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)0742597X(2010)26:1(30)
Chang, C.-Y.; Ive, G. 2007. The hold-up problem in the management
of construction projects: a case study of the Channel Tunnel,
International Journal of Project Management 25(4): 394-404.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2007.01.001
Chen, C.; Doloi, H. 2008. BOT application in China: driving and
impeding factors, International Journal of Project Management 26(4):
388-398. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2007.07.002
Cheung, E.; Chan, A. P. C.; Kajewski, S. 2010. The public
sector's perspective on procuring public works projects--comparing
the views of practitioners in Hong Kong and Australia, Journal of Civil
Engineering and Management 16(1): 19-32.
http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/jcem.2010.02
Chiang, Y.-H.; Cheng, E. W. L. 2009. Perception of financial
institutions toward financing PFI projects in Hong Kong, Journal of
Construction Engineering and Management 135(9): 833-840.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)07339364(2009)135:9(833)
Chowdhury, A. N.; Charoenngam, C. 2009. Factors influencing finance
on IPP projects in Asia: a legal framework to reach the goal,
International Journal of Project Management 27(1): 51-58.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2008.01.011
Devapriya, K. A. K. 2006. Governance issues in financing of
public-private partnership organisations in network infrastructure
industries, International Journal of Project Management 24(7): 557-565.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2006.07.003
DORTS (Department of Rapid Transit Systems). 2011. Network
[online], [cited 18 November 2011]. Available from Internet:
http://english.dorts.taipei.gov.tw/ct.asp?xItem=205656&ct
Node=19582&mp=115002
Dougma, S.; Schreuder, H. 2002. Economic approaches to
organizations. Harlow: Pearson Education Limited. 282 p.
Dudkin, G.; Valila, T. 2005. Transaction costs in public-private
partnerships: a first look at the evidence. Economic and Financial
Report 2005/03, European Investment Bank.
Gibbons, R. 1992. A primer in game theory. Harlow: Pearson
Education Limited. 288 p.
Grunegerg, S. L.; Ive, G. J. 2000. The economics of the modern
construction
firm. Macmillan Press Ltd. 307 p.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/9780230510432
HM TREASURY. 2009. Treasury lending to PFIprojects and the
Treasury's Infrastructure Finance Unit [Online], [cited 10 June
2011]. Available from Internet:
http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/201004070108
52/http:/www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/ppp_tifu_index.htm
Ho, S. P.; Hsu, Y.; Lin, E. 2011. Model for knowledge-sharing
strategies: a game theory analysis, Engineering Project Organization
Journal 1(1): 53-65. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/21573727.2010.549610
Ho, S. P.; Tsui, C. 2010. When are public-private partnerships not
an appropriate governance structure? Case study evidence, in Proceedings
of Construction Research Congress 2010, 8--10 May, 2010, Banff, Canada,
817-826. http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/41109(373)82
Ho, S. P. 2006. Model for financial renegotiation in Public-Private
Partnership Projects and its policy implications: game theoretic view,
Journal of Construction Engineering and Management 132(7): 678-688.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)07339364(2006)132:7(678)
Ho, S. P.; Liu, L. Y. 2002. An option pricing-based model for
evaluating the financial viability of privatized infrastructure
projects, Construction Management and Economics 20(2): 143-156.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/01446190110110533
Irwin, T. C. 2007. Government guarantees--allocating and valuing
risk in privately financed infrastructure projects. Washington, DC:
World Bank. 230 p. http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-6858-9
Li, N. N. T. 1998. Keeping Taiwan connected--the new high speed
rail [online], [cited 5 May 2011]. Available from Internet:
http://www.prac.org/materials/1998_Taipei/ TaiwanHSR.html
Mandri-Perrott, C.; Menzies, I. 2010. Private sector participation
in light rail-light metro transit initiatives. Washington, D.C.: The
World Bank. 324 p. http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-8085-7
Marin, P. 2009. Public-Private Partnerships for urban water
utilities--a review of experience in developing countries. Washington,
D.C.: The World Bank. 208 p. http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/978-0-8213-7956-1
McCain, R. A. 2004. Game theory: a non-technical introduction to
the analysis of strategy. Mason, Ohio: Thomson/South-Western. 391 p.
Medda, F. 2007. A game theory approach for the allocation of risks
in transport public private partnerships, International Journal of
Project Management 25(3): 213-218.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2006.06.003
MOTC (Ministry of Transportation and Communication). 2010. Taiwan
High Speed Rail (HSR) projects [Online], [cited 5 May 2011]. Available
from Internet: www.hsr.gov.tw/homepage.nsf/2274ba1db71bcceb48256
921002b7f08/824eef7a368d87264825729800391614?OpenDocument
Ng, S. T.; Xie, J.; Skitmore, M.; Cheung, Y. K. 2007. A fuzzy
simulation model for evaluating the concession items of public-private
partnership schemes, Automation in Construction 17(1): 22-29.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.autcon.2007.02.010
North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, institutional change and economic
performance. New York: Cambridge University Press. 159 p.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511808678
Ock, J. H.; Han, S. H.; Park, H. K.; Diekmann, J. E. 2005.
Improving decision quality: a risk-based go/no-go decision for
build--operate--transfer (BOT) projects, Canadian Journal of Civil
Engineering 32(3): 517-532. http://dx.doi.org/10.1139/l05-002
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development).
2007. OECD Principles for Private Sector Participation in
Infrastructure. Paris: OECD Publications. 32 p.
PMI (Project Management Institute) 2004. A guild to the project
management body of knowledge (PMBOK Guide). Pennsylvania: Project
Management Institute. 459 p.
PPIAF (Public-Private Infrastructure Advisory Facility) 2009.
Toolkit for Public-Private Partnerships in roads and highways (updated
in 2009) [online], [cited 15 November 2011]. Available from Internet:
http://www.ppiaf.org/ppiaf/sites/ppiaf.org/files/documents
/toolkits/highwaystoolkit/3/3-34-3.html
Russell, A. D.; Tawiah, P.; De Zoysa, S. 2006. Project innovation
--a function of procurement mode?, Canadian Journal of Civil Engineering
33(12): 1519-1537. http://dx.doi.org/10.1139/l06-077
Salman, A. F. M.; Skibniewski, M. J.; Basha, I. 2007. BOT viability
model for large-scale infrastructure projects, Journal of Construction
Engineering and Management 133(1): 50-63.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)07339364(2007)133:1(50)
Solino, A. S.; Vassallo, J. M. 2009. Using Public-Private
Partnerships to expand subways: Madrid-Barajas international airport
case study, Journal of Management in Engineering 25(1): 21-28.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)0742597X(2009)25:1(21)
Tang, L.; Shen, Q.; Cheng, E. W. L. 2010. A review of studies on
Public-Private Partnership projects in the construction industry,
International Journal of Project Management 28(7): 683-694.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijproman.2009.11.009
Tserng, H. P.; Russell, J. S.; Hsu, C. W.; Lin, C. 2012. Analyzing
the Role of National PPP unit in promoting PPP using new institutional
economics and case study, Journal of Construction Engineering and
Management 138(2): 242-249.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)CO.1943-7862.0000398
Wibowo, A. 2006. CAPM-based valuation of financial government
supports to infeasible and risky private infrastructure projects,
Journal of Construction Engineering and Management 132(3): 239-248.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)07339364(2006)132:3(239)
Williamson, O. E. 1996. The mechanisms of governance. Oxford:
Oxford University Press. 429 p.
WORLDBANK. 2010. Did you know? Note 12: Investment in road projects
with private participation more than doubled between 2005 and 2008, but
was concentrated in a few countries. Public-private infrastructure
advisory facility. 4 p.
Xu, Y.; Yeung, J. F. Y.; Chan, A. P. C.; Chan, D. W. M.; Wang, S.
Q.; Ke, Y. 2010. Developing a risk assessment model for PPP projects in
China--a fuzzy synthetic evaluation approach, Automation in Construction
19(7): 929-943. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.autcon.2010.06.006
Yuan, J.-F.; Skibniewski, M. J.; Li, Q.; Shan, J. 2010. The driving
factors of China's Public-Private Partnership projects in
metropolitian transportation systems: public sector's viewpoint,
Journal of Civil Engineering and Management 16(1): 5-18.
http://dx.doi.org/10.3846/jcem.2010.01
Yun, S.; Han, S. H.; Kim, H.; Ock, J. H. 2009. Capital structure
optimization for build-operate-transfer (BOT) projects using a
stochastic and multi-objective approach, Canadian Journal of Civil
Engineering 36(5): 777-790. http://dx.doi.org/10.1139/L08-134
Zhang, X.; Abourizk, S. M. 2006. Determining a reasonable
concession period for private sector provision of public works and
service, Canadian Journal of Civil Engineering 33(5): 622-631.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1139/106-010
Zhang, X. 2005. Financial viability analysis and capital structure
optimization in privatized public infrastructure projects, Journal of
Construction Engineering and Management 131(6): 656-668.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)0733-9364(2005)131:6(656)
Hui Ping TSERNG (a), Shih-Ping HO (a), Jui-Sheng CHOU (b), Chieh
LIN (a, c)
(a) Department of Civil Engineering, National Taiwan University,
Taipei, Taiwan
(b) Department of Civil and Construction Engineering, National
Taiwan University of Science and Technology, Taipei, Taiwan
(c) Department of Technology, Public Construction Commission,
Executive Yuan, Taiwan
Received 26 Jul 2011; accepted 20 Jan 2012
Corresponding author: Hui Ping Tserng
E-mail: hptserng@ntu.edu.tw
Hui Ping TSERNG. He is a Full Professor at the Department of Civil
Engineering of National Taiwan University. He is also a Corresponding
Member of Russian Academy of Engineering. He has a PhD degree in
Construction Engineering and Management from University of
Wisconsin-Madison and he is an Official Reviewer or Editorial Board
Member of several international journals. His research interests include
advanced techniques for project management, construction finance,
knowledge management, management information system, GPS/wireless Sensor
Network, and automation in construction.
Shih-Ping HO. He is an Associate Professor of Construction
Management at National Taiwan University. He taught at Stanford
University in 2010 as endowed Shimizu Visiting Associate Professor. He
is on the Editorial Board of Engineering Project Organization Journal.
His research focuses on game theory modelling and analysis, the
internationalization of A/E/C firms, the governance of Public-Private
Partnerships (PPPs), strategic management, and knowledge sharing.
Jui-Sheng CHOU. He is a Full Professor at the Department of Civil
and Construction Engineering of National Taiwan University of Science
and Technology. He has over a decade of experience in project management
and consulting services for the private and public sectors. He also
serves as a Committee Member in several international and domestic
professional organizations. His teaching and research interests are
primarily involved in Project Management related to knowledge discovery
in databases, quantitative methods, decision, risk & reliability,
cost management, hazard mitigation in spatial planning practice, and
sustainable development.
Chieh LIN. As a Deputy Director for the Department of Technology of
the Taiwan Government (R.O.C.), he was responsible not only for
enacting, regulating, and promoting Public-Private Partnerships
(PPP)/Government Procurement (GP) policy, but also for planning,
reviewing, coordinating, and supervising PPP/GP projects. He received
his MS in Construction Economics and Management from the London College.
He has over a decade of experience in promoting PPP for the public
sector. He has professional licenses in both civil and geotechnical
engineering. He was a part-time PhD student in the Department of Civil
Engineering at National Taiwan University during 2009--2013. Because of
his unique work experience, his primary research interests are PPP and
GP, including financial assessment, contractual design and project
management.
Table 1. List of Taipei MRT station joint-development
projects with assistive financing mechanism
(until the end of 2010)
# Line Joint-development StatBase Area Floor Area
([m.sup.2]) ([m.sup.2]2)
1 Wenshan-Neihu Muzha Station 14,251 39,733
2 Nangang Yongchun Station 2,448 23,627
(Zone 19)
3 Nangang Yongchun Station 4,512 37,633
(Zone 21)
4 Nangang Houshanpi Station 1,533 9,341
(Zone 25)
5 Danshui Taipei Main Station 21,374 244,717
(T 9)
6 Xindian Xindian City Office 1,721 13,896
(Zone 22)
7 Xindian Qizhang Station 7,900 89,735
(Zone 10,11)
8 Xindian Wanlong Station 1,248 7,680
(Zone 10)
9 Xindian Gongguan Station 1,868 15,921
(Zone 11)
10 Xindian Xingtian Depot 92,561 405,695
(Zone 17,18,19)
11 Luzhou Xingtian Temple 2,223 17,966
Station
(Zone 5)
12 Luzhou Xingtian Temple 629 4,958
Station
(Zone 7)
Total 1 152,267 910,903
# Line Total Debt with Actual
Investment GDG Completion
(US$ million) (US$ million) Date
1 Wenshan-Neihu 58.4 34.6 Under Construction
2 Nangang 18.6 16.9 31 May 2005
3 Nangang 35.9 29.6 6 Oct 2005
4 Nangang 9.4 4.9 12 May 2006
5 Danshui 395.0 292.4 24 Jul 2009
6 Xindian 21.5 8.6 29 Oct 2004
7 Xindian 140.1 73.1 9 Jan 2008
8 Xindian 10.3 5.0 Under Construction
9 Xindian 28.0 15.0 29 Dec 2005
10 Xindian 652.7 394.5 Under Construction
11 Luzhou 31.1 18.9 12 May 2009
12 Luzhou 9.3 5.7 5 Jan 2010
1410.4 898.9
Table 2. Matrix of equity levels (a) by reasonable construction profit
margin (RCP) and inflated construction profit margin (k) with fixed
interest rate
[alpha] [kappa] (%)
(%)
(r = 2%) 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
RCP10 7 15 22 27 32 36 40 43 46 49 51
20 15 22 27 32 36 40 43 46 49 51 54
([degrees]% 30 22 27 32 36 40 43 46 49 51 54 56