Management theory: a fragmented and multifaceted field.
Aguero, Juan Omar
ABSTRACT
In this article there is exposed in very summarized way, the
epistemological problematic of the organizational studies and the
paradigms and main theories starting off from which a diversity of
authors have formulated during XX century a series of focuses, concepts,
categories and descriptive, explanatory and interpretive models of the
organizational phenomenon. This has generated a great fragmentation of
the field, but it has also enriched the debate with a multiplicity of
theoretical perspectives that, sometimes complementarily and other times
contradictorily, provide a complex and multifaceted look of the
organizations that cannot be reduced to a single paradigm and much less
still to a single theory.
KEY WORDS: Management, Organizational theory, Organizational
studies.
INTRODUCTION
Management was built up as a scientific discipline, starting off
from the pioneer works published during the second decade of the XX
century. Its study field is the organizations. In this historical
trajectory, there was a configuration of a corpus of paradigms,
theories, models and analytic categories, formulated by diverse authors,
from which it was tried to know, to understand, to describe, to explain
or to predict the behavior of the organizations. After the Kuhnian
revolution of the sixties, the epistemological debate on the
incommensurability of paradigms reached the management corpus, showing
its limitations and potentialities. The two queries that are tried to be
answered in this work are: a) which are the most outstanding theoretical
perspectives for the study of the organizations? And b) how does the
epistemological management establish itself as to paradigms
incommensurability? The purpose of this work consists, on one hand, in
carrying out a brief path of the most outstanding theoretical
trajectories in the management field, and, on the other hand, in
presenting an outline of the debate around the epistemological matter.
The structure of the work responds to these two parts.
I. THE MOST OUTSTANDING THEORETICAL PERSPECTIVES IN MANAGEMENT
The management theory is built during the XX century with different
focuses that try to know, to understand, to describe, to explain and to
predict the behavior of the organizations: 1) classic management theory,
2) humanist management theory, 3) rationalistic management theory, 4)
institutionalism management theory, 5) rational contingency theory, 6)
resources dependence theory, 7) ecological evolutionist theory, 8)
transaction costs theory, 9) agency theory and 10) management and
postmodernist critical theory.
1) Management Classic Theory
The management classic theory is formulated at the beginning of the
XX century. Taylor analyzes the workstations and the industrial
operations, seeking to improve efficiency and labor productivity. The
studies allow a) to know the times and required movements for each task,
b) to know the human aptitudes required for each task and c) to
establish wages in function of production. Fayol enlarges to the whole
organization Taylor's industrial analysis, formulating principles
for the direction and identifying the basic areas of the organization.
Although these principles are criticized and qualified as proverbs by
Simon (1947), they serve as base for the programming, coordination,
direction for objectives and the development of the consultancy for
companies (Perrow, 1991). The excessive rigidity and linearity of the
model and the omission of the human aspects of the organization, greatly
affect the validity of this theory, although Taylor and Fayol's
ideas maintain their influence intact in several aspects.
2) Humanist Management Theory
The focus of the human relations arises between 1924 and 1927 with
Hawthorne's experiences and Elton Mayo's studies on the
changes on physical working conditions and its effects on productivity.
In spite of the abundance of studies on leadership and productivity
between the 1930's and 1960's (Kornhauser and Sharp, 1932;
Lewin, 1935; Brayfield and Crockett, 1955; Vroom, 1964; Lawler and
Porter, 1967 and Hersberg, 1966, among other) there is no conclusion
that leadership necessarily improves labor yield. Other studies on the
organizational climate and the group relationships generate theoretical
formulations such as the hierarchy of the individual's necessities
(Maslow, 1968), the maturity theory (Argyris, 1962), the X and Y
theories (McGregor, 1960) and the organization systems (Lickert, 1961).
The human relations theoreticians are criticized as to the negative load
that they assign to the conflict, the forgetfulness of the widest
context that influences on the groups, the omission of the political
aspects, the suppositions of harmony and balance and the pretense of
understanding the organization as from the individuals and groups. The
great merit is the accumulation of empiric evidences that show the
complexity, irregularity and how unpredictable human behavior is.
(Perrow, 1991).
3) Management Rationalistic Theory
The organizational rationalism continues, it develops and it
deepens the ideas of the management classics, incorporating the human
relations contributions. It stresses on the technological matter of
programming of decisions, formalization of activities and control of the
behaviors of the members of the organization, but puts aside the
informal aspects, the power relationships, the conflict of interest and
the influence of the context. During the 1940's, 1950's and
1960's in the organizational field prevail: the institutionalism,
the decisions and human relations theory. Their seed is constituted by
Barnard (1938) and Weber's (1947) works, which influence in a very
different way (See Chart No 1).
For Barnard, the organizations are by nature cooperative systems
and cannot stop being so. It excludes the conflict, the obligatory
coordination and the financial incentives. For Weber people cooperate
forced by the hierarchy of authority and for the separation between post
and person. Both coincide in defining the organizations as an impersonal
system or supra individual of coordination of forces or activities, that
make the organizations more rational than the individuals.
Simon and March (Simon, 1947; Simon and March, 1958) develop and
reconcile Weber and Barnard's ideas, sustaining that an
organization is a group of people and what the organization does, is
carried out by people, but these possess limited rationality and
therefore their behavior can be controlled by the organization. These
controlled behaviors configure the organizational structure. The
authority, communication and formalization or programming of the
decisions and the activities (technology) are the means to control these
behaviors. The organization defines the objectives and goals. The
conflict is seen by these authors as an impersonal problem, as a
conflict of goals.
4) Management Institutionalism Theory
Institutionalism is the nearest focus to true organizations
sociology (Perrow, 1991). Its most important conceptual framework is
Parsons' structural functionalism. It analyzes in detail the real
and historical organizational processes, nesting them in an organic
whole that gives them sense. It is based on case studies, carefully
documented and analyzed (Selznick, 1949). It follows the revelation
tradition, demonstrating that things are not what they look like. It
analyzes the non political processes of the political behavior and the
non economic aspects of the economy behavior. The organizational
behavior is not based on the formal structure, neither in the objectives
and goals, neither in the production of assets and services, but in the
thousands of underground processes of the informal groups, power
relationships, conflicts, values and interests influenced by the
context. For Selznick (1957) a management process is guided by
efficiency, rationality and attainment of objectives, while an
institutionalization process is guided by values, it is adaptable and
sensitive. The organizations are in themselves, rational instruments and
not simply for the assets they produce or services they render. People
organize their lives around them; they identify themselves with them and
become dependent of them. The institutionalism process is a process of
organic growth for which the organization adapts itself to the internal
groups and to the values of the society that constitutes its context.
They are practices and procedures that continue (Pfeffer, 1982). It is
the crystallization of meanings in an objective way. (March and Olsen,
1976).
The economic institutionalism arises in Germany at the end of the
XIX century (Schmoller, 1900) inspired by romanticism and in Kant and
Hegel's ideas. It sustains that the economic process is operated
within a social framework crossed by culture and history. It is
developed in the United States with Veblen (1919), Commons (1924) and
Mitchell who criticize the suppositions of the classic economy by non
realists and for not considering the historical changes (Scott, 1995).
It rejects the supposition of rational individuals making decisions as
sustained by the classic economy and, on the other hand, it tries to
understand history. Veblen defines the institutions as established
"habits of common thought for the generality of men", while
Commons changes the emphasis in the individual behavior, suggesting
"transaction as an analysis unit". Williamson (1975) retakes
from Commons 1) that the institutions are conceived in dynamic form as
an answers to shortage and the interest conflicts, 2) that transaction
is the analysis unit that should be studied, 3) that the collective
action restricts, liberates and expands the individual action; the
individual can restate the collective action, the routines, the
transactions and the institutional context, and 4) the historical
precision. It criticizes those behavior presumptions of the economic
action sustained by the classic economists. Di Maggio and Powell (1983)
formulate the isomorphism concept to refer to values which continue or
are adjusted to certain rules of genuineness. Isomorphic processes are,
for example, "total quality" or "to study English and
computer science". The organizations exist in fields of other
similar organizations. An organizational field is those organizations
that on the whole constitute a recognized area of institutional life:
suppliers, clients, regulator organisms and others. The concept of
organizational field includes the entirety of relevant actors, not only
competitive organizations that form populations (Hamman and Freeman,
1977) or inter-organizational nets (Laumann, 1978).
For Di Maggio and Powell the organizations are more and more
isomorphic within their fields. This process of institutional
isomorphism is due to 1) the coercive forces of the context, such as
State regulations or cultural rules that impose or force to an
organizational standardization, 2) the mimicry or imitation among
organizations, by which some are modeled one to another and 3) the
normative pressures that come mainly from the professionalism of the
labor force. The organizational design does not come from a rational
process but from internal and external pressures that make the
organizations within their fields resemble some others through time.
Meyer and Scott (1983) and Zucker (1988) study the form in which
values are given to the practices and how the interaction patterns and
the structures are legitimated in the organizations, following Berger
and Luckman's (1967) point of view that reality is a social
construction. The actors are entities with feelings and meanings, they
are not technocrats. The organizations are not configured by
technological or environmental impersonal forces, as sustained by
organizational rationalism, the rational contingency theory, the
ecological theory, the resources dependence theory or that of costs
transaction. For Scott "the institutions are structures and
cognitive, normative and regulative activities that provide stability
and meaning to the social behavior" (Scott, 1995). They are
reproduced by culture, structures and routines. These three
institutional systems--cognitive, normative and regulative--operate in
six institutional levels studied by different authors (See Chart No 2).
Hall (1996) criticizes institutionalism 1) its potential
tautological reasoning1, 2) its lack of attention to what is and what is
not institutionalized; there is a tendency to apply institutionalism in
fact a posteriori, in an almost mystic way, where the ideas and the
practices go and come for any other reason that is not
institutionalization, 3) the explanation of the development of
organizational myths singular and collectively on the meaning of real
facts with the danger that reality, which is the base of the myth
becomes a myth itself, 4) its over-extension, when applying the
institutional theory to an enormous range of situations and
organizations. On the other hand Oliver (1992) criticizes
institutionalism which avoids the deinstitutionalization processes and
Abbott (1992) that avoids or subtracts its importance to topics such as
efficiency. For Perrow (1991) institutionalism contributes 1) to
emphasize on the organization as a whole, and in the variety of
organizational situations, 2) to consider the real possibility that at
least some organizations have their own life, in spite of the desires of
those who supposedly control them and 3) to put the emphasis in the
context as a whole.
5) Rational Contingency Theory
The rational contingency theory arises by mid 1950's in Europe
(Burns and Stockers, 1961 and Woodward, 1965) and is taken to the United
States--mainly to Harvard--by Lawrence and Lorsch (1967) and Thompson
(1967). It is the dominant theory in the 1950's, 1960's and
1970's and still maintains its validity. It exercises great
influence on marketing, in the design of organizations and in the texts
of enterprise consultants. This is very criticized academically. It
sustains as basic supposition that organizations act rationally and they
adapt themselves to the environment. It explains how the factors or
variables of the context determine the organizational structures. There
is not an ideal structure, but criteria to respond to those environment
factors. The environment influence is incorporated to the theory in the
1960's. Each organization has its own contingencies, its risks, its
uncertainty and its restrictions.
It is a functionalist structural theory that considers the
organizations as organisms (Burrell and Morgan, 1979) that adapt
themselves to their environment. The organizations are open systems that
interact with their environment to reproduce the social system (Scott,
1981). The logic of the technologies is of closed systems (Thompson,
1967). The environment generates uncertainty. The organizations look for
regularity, identity, balance (homeostasis) and they try to reduce
environment uncertainty (imbalance), adapting themselves to it
(balance). The closed systems degenerate (entropy). The organizations
are open systems that obtain their energy from the environment. The
organizational structures are differentiated in functions. There is
multiplicity in ways, possible to adapt to the environment (Lawrence and
Lorsch, 1967).
Thompson adopts from of Cyert and March (1963) the concept of
complex organizations to refer to factories, schools, hospitals and
others. From Simon (1947), the concept of limited rationality, to
sustain that the organizations face and solve problems, satisfying
objectives, not maximizing. From Barnard (1939), the idea that the
individuals have one foot inside and the other outside the organization
and from Parsons (1960) the different levels of responsibility and
control: technician, managerial and institutional.
Thompson denominates technical rationality or technology the
activities that, according to cause/effect relationships, produce the
desired results. A perfect technology produces the wanted result in an
unavoidable way in a closed system. Since the organizations search to
obtain wanted results and are open systems subject to rationality
criteria, they will search to protect their technical nucleus, reducing
the number of variables that operate on it, establishing a closed system
of logic. At institutional level, on the other hand, the organizations
are more open to the environment and they operate with more variables,
being therefore greater the uncertainty degree. The managerial role is
to intermediate between context--adapting and making the organization
flexible--and the technical nucleus protecting the key activities or
critics for the objectives of the organization.
The rational contingency theory is criticized for its tautological
outline, the non consideration of the political and historical aspects,
the obsession for efficiency and the omission of key actors for the
organization (Hall, 1996).
6) Resources Dependence Theory
The resources dependence theory arises by mid 1970's (Aldrich
and Pfeffer, 1976; Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978; Aldrich, 1979; Pfeffer,
1982) and it centers its analysis in the decisions taken inside the
organizations. It has links with the focus of political economy
organizations (Wamsley and Zald, 1973 and Benson, 1975) and with the
exchange-dependence focus (Haselfeld, 1972 and Jacobs, 1974).
The organizations have an internal political context within which
strategic decisions are taken, selecting alternatives in an active way,
trying to somehow manipulate the environment to obtain advantages in
terms of dependence of resources. All organizations depends on the
context to obtain the resources that they need: human, technological,
materials, financial and others, which are provided by other
organizations that in turn obtain their resources from other
organizations and so on and so forth, generating an inter-organizational
resources dependence chain.
The organizations try the diminish uncertainty and contingency that
generates this interdependence by means of coalitions, alliances and
other forms of inter-organizational relationship. These actions are
decided internally in the organizations by means of strategic options
that select the best alternative allowed by the context. The decisions
arise from the internal distribution of power, and keep in mind context
restrictions, uncertainty and contingencies.
The decisions can have important legal or economic barriers to
manipulate the environment. Big organizations can dominate the markets
leaving little or no margin or possibility to the small ones to modify
their environments or contexts. The ways in which the organizations can
operate successfully are reproduced by means of bureaucratization, the
specialization and the standardization of functions, the promotions
based on performance, the transmission of the organization culture and
the leadership structure.
7) Ecological Evolutionist Theory
In the ecological evolutionist theory, the context or environment
selects which organizations are adjusted or better adapted to it and
which are not (Hannan and Freeman, 1977, 1983 and 1989). It studies the
organizational forms and the organizations population. These concepts
are not sufficiently clarified in the theory and generate not few
methodological difficulties for their treatment. The organizations do
not adapt themselves to the environment, but rather they are selected by
this, in a natural process which has three stages (Campbell, 1969): 1)
Variation in the form or way of operating, planned or not, 2) selection
in the ways that are successful and 3) Retention in the selected ways,
conserving them and reproducing them. This conservation takes place
mainly through the managerial training and the professional training
based on the models that successfully function.
The organizational forms occupy niches within the context. For
Aldrich (1979) "the niches are combinations different from
resources and other restrictions that are enough to support an
organizational form". A niche is a group of organizations that
combine the same resources and have the same dependence of the
atmosphere. The narrow niches, for example the ethnic groups, the
neighborhood and the religious and professional groups, tend to maintain
specialized organizations, while the wider niches tend to maintain more
diversified organizations (Hannan and Freeman, 1983). For the study of
organization populations, Baum (1991) suggests several dimensions and
variables (See Chart No 3).
The main contribution of the ecological theory is to explain how a
population of organizations goes evolving and how a certain organization
will evolve. Nevertheless, there are several criticisms formulated on
this theory: its strong biological content and its scarce social
foundation (Perrow, 1979; Van de Ven, 1979); it does not take into
account the origin of the variations (Aldrich and Pfeffer, 1976; Van de
Ven, 1979); it does not consider the internal processes of the
organizations (Aldrich and Pfeffer, 1976); it does not explain the
adjustment processes between the organization and their environment (Van
de Ven, 1979); it is based on the same suppositions that the economy
sustains for the perfect competition markets and which are not verified
in any case (Aldrich and Pfeifer, 1976); it considers the selection
process as unavoidable (Van de Ven, 1979); it shows an environment empty
of human actors, with organizations like inert masses, eliminating power
variables, conflict, disorganization and other social processes (Perrow,
1979).
8) Transaction Costs Theory
The transaction costs theory arises from the economy field and
tries to why the organizations exist and act (Williamson, 1975, 1981 and
1985). The analysis unit is the transaction or exchange of assets and
services. It is based on the horno economicus that acts rationally
maximizing its benefit. When stressing on the transaction, it puts to
one side the production problem to center on the markets. The simple
transactions are carried out freely in the market, but when they are
complex they become uncertain and trust becomes problematic, being
justified in consequence the emergence of hierarchies or organizations
as an answer to uncertainty.
The transaction under the protection of an organization allows the
surveillance, supervision and control of the process. The organizations
search for more and more control by means of commitments formalization
processes of and construction of monopolies. But there is also the
inverse return process, to the free market transaction, for example in
the recruiting of temporary personnel and in services sub-contracts.
The costs transaction theory provides a limited vision of the
organization which should necessarily complement itself with other
focuses. This is recognized by Williamson (1985) himself. The
transactions, also, are carried out in contexts of social relationships
more than of economic relationships (Granovenen, 1985). Other phenomena
not sufficiently considered by this theory, are the vertical and
horizontal integrations of the organizations that give origin to true
domestic markets, isolated from competition and from open-markets
(Lazerson, 1988).
9) Agency Theory
The agency theory also tries to explain the existence and
performance of the organizations (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Fama, 1980
and Fama and Jensen, 1983). It supposes that social life is no other
thing than a series of contracts, where the buyer of assets and services
is the holder and the one that he provides them to is the agent. This
relationship holder-agent is governed by a contract, but subject to
fraud problems, scarce information and limited rationality. In the
formulation of agency theory one must keep in mind 1) the holder and the
agent's preferences, 2) the nature of uncertainty which generates
situations of grater or less insecurity and 3) the information available
to the holder regarding the agent's behavior. So, the agency
theory, like the costs transaction one, justify the existence of
organizations like framework actions to agree or to suit contracts that
regulate certain transactions that are necessary for the exchange of
assets and services in an economy system. This regulation diminishes the
uncertainty of the context and it allows certain degree of control on
the key variables.
10) Management and Postmodernist Critical Theory
For Alvesson and Deetz (1996), the critical theory emerges in the
organizational studies toward the ends of the 1970's and beginnings
of 1980's (Benson, 1977; Burrell and Morgan, 1979; Frost, 1980;
Deetz and Kersten, 1983; and Fisher and Sirianni, 1984), while the
postmodernist theory arises toward ends of the 1980's (Smircich and
Calas, 1987 and Cooper and Burreli, 1988). Both emerge in contexts
characterized by the increase of the size of the organizations, the
quick implementation of communication information technologies and, the
globalization processes, the changes in the labor relationships, the
decrease and professionalism of the labor work force, the
intensification of ecological problems and the markets turbulence.
So the critical theory as the postmodernist one, criticize the
illumination of modernity and its promise of autonomous subject,
progressively emancipated by the acquired knowledge through the
scientific method. In speech modernity, was attributed, emancipation of
the myth, authority and traditional values, through knowledge, reason
and opportunities based on training and individual development. Although
he partially recognizes the potentialities of illumination and modernity
(Habermas, 1984 and 1987), criticizes their great stories based on
abstract universal categories; the use of reason as a dominance and
hegemony instrument; the mystification of progress, science and
technology; the environment destruction; the unfulfilled promise of
human emancipation and the social exclusion generated systematically.
The inspiration sources of the critical and postmodernist theory
are a) Nietzsche's relationship between power and knowledge, b)
language constructivism and the experience of the inter-subjective
theory, c) Marx's social conflict theory and d) Freud's
complex human subject. In Deetz (1994) this author relations two
dimensions: on one hand, the origin of the social dominant speech, that
can be consent or disagreement and, and on the other, the concepts and
studied problems, that give place, a priori, to the domestic emergent
and elite categories. In function to these dimensions, the author
places, the critical theory in the disagreement, because the identity,
order and objects are built socially, and as elite a priori because it
is a previous privileged knowledge. On the other hand, the postmodernist
theory, although it is also located in the disagreement, it is domestic
emergent because it constitutes a knowledge built during the process.
The critical theory, in a wide sense, constitutes a radical critic
on contemporary society, pointing out exploitation, repression,
asymmetric power relationships, distorted communication and false
conscience. In a strict sense, it refers to the so called Frankfurt
School, whose maximum exponents are Adorno, Horkheimer, Marcuse and
Habermas. In the organizational studies, the pretense of the critical
theory is to aspire to societies and working places free of dominance.
Externally, it focalizes its attention in the relationship of the
organizations with the most ample society, emphasizing the social
consequences of colonization of other institutions and of the dominance
or destruction of the public sphere. Internally, it analyzes the
dominance generated by the instrumental reason, speech and the
"consensus". In a clear political agenda, it focalizes its
attention in the interests of specific groups such as women, workers and
negroes, studying the goals, values, conscientious forms and
communicative distortions within the organizations; the
institutionalization forms and ideologies and organizational practices
as expression of contemporary dominance forms (Alvesson and Deetz,
1996).
The organizational critical theory is composed of two large study
lines: 1) The ideological criticism and 2) The communicative action.
1) The early ideological criticism is carried out by Marx, who
described the way in which the exploitation relationship appeared as
legitimate. The economy conditions and class structure were central in
the analysis. Then, starting off from the 1970's, the dominance and
exploitation by the proprietors, and later on by the administrators,
were the ideological critic's central topics. Other studies refer
to the coercion processes (Gramsci, 1929 and 1935; Burawoy, 1979 and
Willmon, 1990), to the cultural-ideological control (Hodge, 1979;
Czarniawska-Joerges, 1988; Deetz and Mumby, 1990 and Kunda, 1992) and to
the organizations as expressions and producers of ideologies (Burrell
and Morgan, 1979; Alvesson, 1987; Alvesson and Willmott, 1996).
The ideological critic's 4 recurrent topics are the
naturalization of the social order, universalization of managerial
interests, instrumental reason and hegemony. a) The naturalization of
the social order: The social order is abstracted from its history and
its origin; the organizational processes appear as "natural"
and the organic and mechanical metaphors prevail. For the ideological
critic, organizations are socio-historical constructions (Lukacs, 1971;
Benson, 1977; Giddens, 1979; Frost, 1980 and 1987; Thompson, 1984 and
Deetz, 1985 and 1994).
b) The universalization of the managerial interests: The interests
particular to organizations are universalized and treated as if they
were of interests to all. The multiple demands of property to financial
estates decreases. Money fulfils a dominant role. For the ideological
critic, the managerial advantages can be seen as historically produced
and actively reproduced by the ideological practices in society and in
the organizations themselves (Tompkins and Cheney, 1985; Knights and
Willmott, 1985; Lazega, 1992; Deetz, 1992; Offe and Wiesenthal, 1980).
c) The instrumental reason: Habermas (1971, 1975, 1984 and 1987)
describe technical reasoning as instrumental and tending to be governed
by what is theoretical and hypothetical. Their opposite is the practical
interest. It is a constituent interest of the preservation and expansion
of inter-subjectivity from the possible action oriented towards mutual
understanding. The practical reasoning focalizes itself in the
understanding process and mutual determination of purposes.
d) Hegemony: is a concept analyzed and developed by Gramsci (1929
and 1935) as a complex net of conceptual agreements and materials which
occur in everyday life. The hegemony conception suggests the presence of
multiple dominant groups, with different interests and the presence of
power and activity even in the dominated groups.
Several objections have been formulated to the ideological critic:
a) that it is ad-hoc and reactive, explaining after the happening why
something does not happen instead of predicting the future; b) that is
elitist and c) that it is too simplistic. The greatest criticism is the
one formulated by the postmodernist theory, in connection with the
rational and reflexive agent's idea, able to act autonomously and
cohesively. The ideological critic has responded to these objections,
researching empirically dominance systems, insisting on the
interests' asymmetries and treating the ideologies as dominant
without seeing them as a simple instrument (Alvesson and Deetz, 1996).
2) Communicative action is part of the systematic philosophy
developed by Habermas (1984 and 1987). It distinguishes two processes of
historical learning and rationality forms: The
strategic-scientific-technological one, associated with the system
world, and the ethics-politics-communicative one, associated with the
world of life. The world of life is built creating and recreating the
meaning patterns. It can be considered as entirely rational, more than
instrumental or strategic, with interactions guided by the communicative
understanding rather than the world imperatives system or by the
non-reflexive traditional cultural values. Communicative understanding
depends on the non distorted communication, of the presence of the free
discussion based on agreement, argument and dialogue. The non distorted
communication provides the base for the highest rationality form.
In the communicative rationality there is no power, status,
prestige, ideology, manipulation, experts' role, fear, insecurity,
incomprehension or any other form of ideas repression. It is a method to
analyze--query; tested, accepting--the validity of different demands,
based on understanding, sincerity, truth and legitimacy. The
communicative action is an important aspect of the social interaction in
society, in the social institutions and in daily life (Alvesson and
Deetz, 1996).
Vattimo (1992) criticizes Habermas his "benign and benevolent
vision of the human species" that counts with the knowledge and the
argument to change thought and action, a position about which the
postmodernists are highly skeptical (Alvesson and Deetz, 1996).
The critical theory has carried out important contributions to the
organizational studies (Alvesson and Willmott, 1996; Alvesson, 1987;
Sieven, 1986; Fischer, 1990; Hollway, 1984; Mumby and Pumain, 1992;
Ferguson, 1984; Frost, 1987; Deetz and Kersten, 1983; Calas and
Smircich, 1992):
* The vision of organization as technocracy, mystification,
cultural drowsiness and colonization power.
* The analysis of the direction, favoring of the organization
members passivity, to be able to manipulate them.
* The ambiguity analysis, the contradictions and the codes in the
organizational communicative action.
* The narrow thought which generates the dominance of the
instrumental reason and the money code.
* The constrained working conditions, where creativity, change,
development and meanings are ignored or subordinated to instrumental
values.
* The asymmetric social relationships among experts (including the
administrator elites) and non experts.
* The extension of control on employees and concealment of their
social reality.
* The control on consumers and the social ethics-politics agenda,
prioritizing the money code.
* The environment destruction.
* The false appearance of objectivity and impartiality of the
management techniques used in the organizations.
* The dominance of groups, ideas and institutions.
* The conflicts between practical reason (communicative action) and
the instrumental reason (maximization of results).
On the other hand, postmodernism describes a historical period
marked by a deep social change. It has elaborated a group of
philosophical reflections on organizations (Featherstone, 1988; Kellner,
1988; Parker, 1992; Hassard and Parker, 1993), inspired by Derrida,
Foucault, Baudrillard, Lyotard, Deleuze, Guattari, Laclau and Moufle. It
is based on: a) speech centrality, b) fragmented identities, c) the
critic of presence philosophy, d) The loss of foundation of the great
narrations, e) The connection between knowledge and power, f) The
hyper-reality and g) Research as resistance and indetermination. a)
Speech centrality replaced the unconscious structure in postmodernism,
as the distorted communication replaced false conscience in the critical
theory. Language as a particular, domestic construction, from
life's experience, opposes itself certainty, to objective truth, to
prediction and control of nature and to the social world that sustains
objectivism. There are two versions regarding speech centrality: 1) the
one that emphasizes speech in a special linguistic sense, where the
language in use is intrinsically related to meaning and to perception
and 2) Foucault's vision of speech, as a thought system that
contains and informs material practices that produce peculiar forms of
subjectivity, not only linguistically, but also practically, by
particular power techniques.
b) With the fragmented identities, postmodernism rejects the sure
unitary identity as the center of the social universe, based on the
notion of autonomy and individual selfdetermination. On this position
there are two versions: 1) one that sustains that man's western
conception has always been a myth and 2) the one that sustains that the
individual vision as coherent, integrated and autonomous is false.
Organizations continually emerge, they are constituted and constituent
produced and consumed by the subjects.
c) The critic of the presence philosophy sustains that the material
of the world only becomes an object in a specific relationship. The
linguistic and non linguistic practices are central for the production
of the object (Mead, Wittgenstein, and Heidegger). For the normative
social science, the primary function of language is to represent
objects. For example, a "worker" is an object (also a subject)
in the world, but neither God nor nature made this "worker",
but rather--so that he exist--one requires: 1) a language and 2) a group
of practical social practices, that classify human beings in
"workers" and "non workers". Questions such as, what
is a worker really?, what constitutes a worker?, how does a human being
do to be a worker?, they are not answerable, looking at something in the
world that can be described as a "worker", but rather products
of the linguistic and non linguistic practices that make of this
something, an object.
d) The loss of foundation of the great narratives makes
reference--for example--to Marxism's fight of classes, to the
survival of social Darwinism or to the invisible hand of market economy.
There are two positions: 1) narrations are always a deceit that have
been used as support of a dominant vision of the world and of order and
2) narrations generate incredulity.
e) The connection between power and knowledge (Foucault, 1977 and
1980) is expressed in the formation of speech itself. Power resides in
the demarcation and the speech system.
f) Hyper-reality has to do with the world, understood not as a
reality but as a simulation.
g) Research as resistance and indetermination is a kind of
anti-positive knowledge, based on the deconstruction.
II. THE EPISTEMOLOGICAL MATTER IN MANAGEMENT
The organizational study field is fragmented and multifaceted. For
Burrel and Morgan (1979), all the organizational theories are based on a
certain conception on the nature of science and society, adopting as
foundation a subjective or objective dimension.
It is difficult to reconcile these positions outlined by Burell and
Morgan if we consider--as done by these authors--the objective and
subjective as rigidly antagonistic or as two completely different
realities. However, reality, or at least what we can know of it, is at
the same time objective and subjective, it goes building up with
objective elements (that exist independently of the subject) and
subjective (that belongs to the subject). This is for example is the
position that sustains the structuring theory (Giddens, 1984).
The same thing happens to the dichotomy between regulation and
radical change. Society is a combination of different regulation degrees
and change, in constant conflict which are solved in different ways.
Only in the case of the big revolutions, for example the French
revolution, the social change opposes itself as completely antagonistic
to regulation, the conflict being solved violently by imposition of the
radical change on the status quo. With these two dichotomies,
"objectivism / subjectivism" and "social
regulation/social change", Burell and Morgan build a matrix with
four big paradigms in which they place the different social theories
linked with the organizations:
Analyzing the results of several empiric researches on development
levels of paradigms of different disciplines, Pfeiffer (1993) concludes
that the organizational studies have low-level paradigm development due
to several factors: a) The reference to other social sciences; b) The
low remuneration of those who are devoted to said studies; c) The low
written production; d) The lack of interconnection regarding the written
production; e) The nonexistence of a research agenda and f) The
theoretical and methodological dispersion, sustaining the necessity to
achieve a consensus that favors the paradigmatic development of the
organizational studies, based on: a) A reduced number of outstanding
specialists of the discipline, b) The authority of this elite, c) A
standard methodology, d) A program of standard research and d) The
acceptance of certain central theories. At the present state of
development of the discipline, Pfeffe's proposal would be reached
around the functionalist paradigm, due to its hegemony, but with this
reduction one would have to discard an important quantity of scientific
production developed around the other paradigms pointed out by Burell
and Morgan, which would mean a setback and not an advance in the
discipline. Pfeffer's proposal has a strongly dogmatic bias.
Scherer and Steinmann (1999) discuss the problem of
incommensurability of the paradigms, understanding as the triple
relationship of orientation systems that include theories, rules,
structures, values, interests and cultures. A system is incommensurable with another regarding certain comparison rules, when three conditions
are given: 1) the radical difference between orientation systems, 2) the
competition or conflict between systems and 3) A certain action course.
There are no comparison standards that rationally solve a conflict
problem.
These two authors discuss the incommensurability problem in the
organizational studies from several theoretical conceptions: a) The
axiomatic-deductive reasoning concept; b) The paradigmatic relativism (isolationism), c) The paradigmatic dogmatism functionalist (hegemonic)
and d) The paradigmatic pluralism. From science, there does not arise a
perspective solution to the problem and we are at a break-even point because the level of the theories requires a goal-level of paradigms and
these, a goal-goal-level of understanding and thus they would go on
until the infinite.
Scherer and Steinmann intend then to adopt Geert-Lueke
Lueken's (1991) proposal, based on methodical constructivism
(Lorenzen, 1973, 1987) of the Erlangen School, a German city located
near Nurnberg, in Bavaria. To solve the incommensurability problem,
Lueken proposes the argumentation concept: "a symbolic action
dedicated to overcome a controversy and to reach consensus". He put
to one side the axiomatic-deductive concept of reasoning and sustains
that praxis precedes theory, that is to say action methodically precedes
knowledge. From the world of life or pre-theoretical praxis, the
theoretical praxis arises and then the praxis based on the theory that
in turn returns to refeed itself by the pretheoretical practice in
dialectical form. Scherer and Steinmann suggest to dissolve the rigid
structures of thought and action to begin a learning process, in a new
conception way and to carry out organizational studies (Morgan, 1983),
building a consensus from practice.
CONCLUSION
There is not a single way of looking at an organization. Even more,
the multiple looks from different theoretical angles are imposed as an
imperious necessity if one wants to build a vision which is the most
comprehensible possible on this phenomenon so complex as are the
organizations, with their multiple dimensions and transversal matters,
which cannot be explained satisfactorily from a single theoretical
perspective.
Each theoretical focus contributes its own. It contributes its own
look, certainly partial, of what they consider as organization.
The effective combination of these different theoretical focuses in
a research is not an easy task, but neither it is impossible, if we keep
in mind that the researched objects--as Bourdieu points out--are always
built, that is to say they are systems of conceptual relationships and
not physical demarcations of real objects.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
ALDRICH, H. y PFEFFER, J. Environments of organizations. Annual
Review of Sociology. (1976)
ALVESSON, M. Comunication, power and organization. New York. de
Gruyter.(1996)
ALVESSON, M. y DEETZ, S. Critical Theory and Postmodernism.
Approaches to organization studies. en Clegg S.(1996)
ALVESSON, M. y WILLMOTT, H. Critical Analysis. London, Sage.(1996)
ALVESSON, M. y WILLMOTT, H. Critical management studies. London,
Sage.(eds) (1992)
ALVESSON, M. y WILLMOTT, H.Making Sense of Management: A Critical
Analysis. London, Sage.(1996)
BARNARD, Ch. The function of the executive. Cambridge, Harvard
University Press.(1938)
BAUDRILLARD, J. Simulations. New York, Semiotexte.(1983)
BURAWOY, M. The politics of production: factory regimes under
capitalism and socialism. London, Verso.(1985)
BURRELL, G. y MORGAN, G. Sociological paradignis and organizational
analysis. London, Arena.(1979)
CLEGG, S. Frameworks of power. London, Sage.(1989)
CLEGG, S. Modern organization: organization studies in the
postmodem world. London, Sage. (1990)
CLEGG, S. y otros. Handbook of organization studies. London,
Sage.(1996)
DEETZ, S. The future of the discipline: The chalenges, the research
and the social contribution, en Deetz, S. (ed) Communication yearbook.
(1994)
DIMAGGIO, P. y POWELL, W. The newinstitutionalism in organizational
analysis. Chicago University Press.(1991)
DONALDSON, L. The normal science of contingency theory. en Clegg S.
y otros, obra citada.(1996)
FEATHERSTONE, M. Postmodernism. Newbury, Sage.(1988)
FORESTER, J. Critical theory, public policy and planning practice.
State University of New York Press.(1993)
FOUCAULT, M. Power / Knowledge. New York, Pantheon. (1980)
GIDDENS, A. The constitution of society. Outline of te theory of
structuration. CAMBRIDGE, Polity Press.(1984)
GRAMSCI, A. Selections from the prison notebook. New York,
International.(1929-1935)
HABERMAS, J. The theory of comunicative action. Reason and the
rationalization of society. Boston, Beacon Press.(1984)
HALL, R. Organizaciones: estructuras, procesos y resultados.
Mexico, Prentice Hall Hispanoamericana. (1996)
HANNAN, M. y FREEMAN. Organizational Ecology. Cambridge
University.(1989)
HASSARD, J. y PARKER, M. Postmodernism and organizations. London,
Sage.(eds) (1993)
PERROW, Ch. A framework for the comparative analysis of
organizations. American Sociological Review. (1967)
PERROW, Ch. Complex organizatioris: an critical essay. Scott,
Foreman and co.(1979)
PERROW, Ch. Sociologia de las organizaciones. Madrid, McGraw-Hill.
(1991)
PFEFFER, J. Organizations and organization theory. Boston,
Pitman.(1982)
PFEFFER, J. Barriers to the advance of organizational science:
paradigm development as a dependent variable. Academy of Management
Review, vol. 18, no 4.(1993)
SCHERER, A. y STEINMANN, H. Some remarks on the problem of
incommensurability in organization studies. Organization Studies.(1999)
SCOTT, W. R. Organizations: natural rational and open systems. New
York, Prenfice Hall. (1992)
SCOTT, W. R. Institutions and Organizations. Thousand Oaks,
Sage.(1995)
THOMPSON, J. Organizaciones en accion. Mexico, McGraw-Hill.(1991)
VATTIMO, G. The transparent society. John Hopkins University
Press.(1992)
WILLIAMSON, O. The economic institution of capitalism: firms,
markets, relational contracting. New York, Free Press. (1985)
(1) A tautology is a circular reasoning, where the variables are
defined, some in terms of the others, thus darkening and making
difficult the evaluation of the causes. (Turner and Maryanski, 1979)
Aguero, Juan Omar
Universidad Nacional de Misiones
Facultad de Ciencias Economicas
Ruta Nacional No 12, Km. 7 1/2--Campus
Universitario--C.P.(3304)--Miguel Lanus,
Misiones, Argentina
E-mail: juanaguero@arnet.com.ar
Chart No 1. Barnard and Weber's Influence on Management
Dimensions or
aspects Barnard's Influence Weber's Influence
Organizational System Organic Mechanic
Organization Axis The human beings The tasks
The tasks Adaptative and sensitive Rigid and inflexible
Organizational Model Democratic Authoritarian
Source: Own elaboration based on Perrow (1991)
Chart No 2. Institutionalism Levels Study
Levels Cognitive Normative
The World System Meyer (1994) Krasmer (1983)
Society Dobbin (1994) Parsons (1953)
The Organizational Di Maggio (1991) Mezias (1990)
Field
The Population of Carroll and Singh, Tucker and
Organizations Hannan (1989) House (1986)
The Organization Clark (1970) Selznick (1949
The Organizational Zimmermann (1969) Roy (1952) and
Subsystems Buroway (1979)
Levels Regulative
The World System North and Thomas (1973)
Society Skocpol (1979)
The Organizational Campbell and
Field Lindberg (1990)
The Population of Barnett and Carroll
Organizations (1993)
The Organization Williamson (1975)
The Organizational Shepsle and
Subsystems Weingast (1987)
Source: Own elaboration
Chart No 3. Dimensions and Variables for the Study of Organization
Populations
Dimension Variable Meaning
Demographic Age The old organizations have higher
mortality rate
Size The bigger ones have higher
survival rate
Ecological Density Number of organizations
Mass Size of organization population
Relationship Number of relationships between
organizations
Overlapping Overlapping of niches of
organizations
Localization Geographical environment
Specialization Competitiveness degree between
organizations
Environmental Institutional Norms that regulate populations
Political The organization population's
political framework
Technological Dominant designs
Economic Organizations Economic framework
Source: Own elaboration based on Baum (1991)
Chart No 4. Science Nature
Supposed Subjective Dimension Objective Dimension
Ontological Nominalism Realism
Epistemological Anti-positivism Positivism
Anthropological Voluntarism Determinism
Methodological Ideographical Nomothetic
Source: Own elaboration based on Burrel and Morgan (1979)
Chart No 5. Society's Nature
Regulation Social Change
Status quo Radical Change
Social Order Structural Conflict
Consensus Dominance
Integration Contradiction
Solidarity Emancipation
Satisfaction of necessities Deprivation
Present time Potentiality
Source: Own elaboration based on Burrel and Morgan (1979)
Chart No 6. Paradigms and Organizational Theories
SUBJETIVISM RADICAL CHANGE OBJECTIVISM
Humanist Radical Paradigm Radical Structurist Paradigm
Anarchist individualism Marxism
Critical theory Conflict Theory
French Existentialism Russian Social theory
Anti-organizational Theory Organization Radical theory
Interpretive paradigm Functionalist Paradigm
Phenomenology Integrative Theory
Hermeneutics Systems General theory
Ethno-methodology Objectivism / Pluralism
Symbolic Inter-action Bureaucratic Dysfunctions Theories
SUBJETIVISM REGULATION OBJECTIVISM
Source: Own elaboration based on Burrel and Morgan (1979)