Review essay: not quite on the level.
Schansberg, D. Eric
The Spirit Level is a favorite book of one of my university
colleagues. It is also on a topic of immense interest to me: income
inequality. Yet I probably would not have taken notice of Wilkinson and
Pickett's book (WP) without my colleague's repeated reference
to their work. (1)
Wilkinson and Pickett are quite helpful in laying out certain
income inequality data--as well as data on a wide and impressive array
of correlated social problems and issues. They rely on comparisons
within two samples: the twenty-three richest countries and the fifty
states in America. They discuss some of the relevant theories and at
least some of the relevant literature. (2) Then, they combine the data,
theory, and literature review with some just-so stories that result in
inferences somewhere between solid ground and an awkward narrative that
fits various aspects of their worldview. (3)
At the end of the day, their data do not imply much about how to
achieve their ends. Most of the time, WP are appropriately reluctant to
make policy prescriptions. (4) Nevertheless, sometimes, they deviate a
bit and get themselves into contradictory positions. Unfortunately, they
are not forceful enough in insisting on humility among their
readers--and therefore careless proponents of their work could easily
end up being less cautious than would be wise.
In a review in Faith and Economics, A. M. C. Waterman summarizes
the WP project well, though he is more generous than I concerning the
statistical basis: Despite its flaws, "the overall effect of all
the evidence is persuasive... [so let us] take it that the correlations
do indeed tell us something true and important, and go on to consider
some of the questions they raise." (5)
Income Inequality Measured
"There are lots of ways of measuring income inequality,"
WP write, "and they are all so closely related to each other that
it doesn't usually make much difference which you use" (17).
They then refer to the choice of quintiles and deciles for income
measurement and the calculation of Gini coefficients.
Among those choices, they are correct; it does not make much
difference. However there are other key data questions that are not even
raised here: Are we looking at individual or household or family
measures of income? Is income pre- or post-tax? Is income pre- or
post-transfer (payments from government welfare programs)? Wilkinson and
Pickett touch on these three questions only briefly (243)--and largely
to dismiss them.
More broadly, what constitutes "income" in these
measures? What about measures of compensation rather than wages? What
was the impact of 1980s changes in tax laws that encouraged
higher-income workers to receive more wages and less stock? What about
much-more-equal measures of consumption (rather than income)? (6) To
what extent is variance in income a function of differences in hours
worked? (7) The immense failure to discuss all of these and WP's
reliance solely on a narrow approach that favors their chosen narrative
is, by itself, sufficient to reject WP's work out-of-hand as naive
or biased. But let us assume the best and move along.
Wilkinson and Pickett focus on averages and aggregate measures. It
would be interesting to know how much the numbers (and WP's
inferences) would change with significant changes in the
"super-rich"--for example, if one were to triple or halve the
number and/or the incomes of those in the top .1 percent. (My guess is
that the numbers would barely move, but the implications would be
relevant either way.) Related to this, they criticize CEO pay (249-64),
and they assume that CEO pay is a significant contributor to the
underlying problem (such as it is). (8) This seems fanciful. In any
case, it would be nice to see them address this somewhat--at least with
static simulations.
Wilkinson and Pickett discuss social mobility as their final
applied topic (chap. 12). In part, this is reasonable: It is arguably
the most important consideration, so why not save it for last? On the
other hand, it is curious to wait so long because the dynamics are so
important--and so important to the foundational topic of true versus
measured income inequality. More troubling, they only discuss a narrow
slice of a complex and mixed literature on income and class mobility--a
slice that favors their worldview. Again, this is a lack of scholarship
or an unfortunate bias. (9)
Income Inequality versus Poverty
Wilkinson and Pickett are usually careful to avoid the common error
of conflating income inequality with poverty. (10) But their passing
references to the problems of poverty underline another point--poverty
is at least as pressing as income inequality. That said, they rarely
seem to recognize this--even implying that material poverty should be
considered in strictly relative terms (15), rather than strictly
absolute terms, or taking the more moderate position that material
poverty is both relative and absolute.
This raises another question: In recent years, why has there been a
greater focus on income inequality than poverty per se? One answer is
that many "inequality warriors" are more concerned about
income inequality, whether from a sense of morality; out of envy; or
here, as with WP, from pragmatic concerns about its practical impact on
society.
Yet many proponents of "equality" care about poverty too.
This leads to another answer: In public debate, it is common (and easy)
to use static analysis of simple statistics. (11) This approach works
reasonably well for income inequality. However it works very poorly for
the poverty rate--the favorite but simplistic metric in that realm. In
short, a reliance on the poverty rate would indicate a massive failure
for the War on Poverty because it remains roughly unchanged since the
so-called war began. Although the poverty rate is deeply flawed
(12)--and masks many of the problems of the poor--the public debate has
become wedded to simple statistics and the flawed analysis that follows.
Given that the poverty rate "doesn't help" the preferred
narrative of advocates, it makes more sense for them to focus on
inequality than poverty.
Social Implications of Income Inequality
This is the most impressive and useful section of the book:
chapters 4-12 on community life; (13) mental health and drug use;
health, obesity, and life expectancy; educational performance; babies
born to teenagers; crime and punishment; and social mobility. Wilkinson
and Pickett present a series of simple correlations--with aggregate
statistics, mostly point-in-time. The approach is limited but becomes
more persuasive as they apply it so broadly.
Arguably, the most powerful point in the book is that income
inequality correlates with a number of troubling social indicators--for
both the poor and the rich. It is one thing to say that inequality (or
poverty) hurts the poor. It is much more provocative to say that it
impacts the wealthy. In economic terms, WP are trying to make the case
that income equality has positive externalities and thus should be
fostered by some set of government policies. (14)
Even so WP either ignore or too easily dismiss the potential
influence of many other contributing variables: religious belief and
practice, family structure and stability, and globalization and other
economic factors. They discuss Robert Putnam's concept of
"social capital" at length (54-56, 79, 140) as another
positive externality. Oddly, they give it little weight as a causal
factor or a potential solution (208-9).
There are clearly other variables in play as well--limits in the
data and other causal factors--given the significant dispersion along
WP's set of univariate trend lines. In all of this it is strange to
see WP be so sociologically selective, focusing almost exclusively on
income inequality. They seem oddly passionate about looking for "a
common underlying cause" (186), and for casting income inequality
in that role--as if a single cause were likely to explain something so
complex. (15)
Likewise WP implicitly hold genetics and culture constant--an odd
and incoherent position. (16) They try to dismiss the former with a
quick sentence (185): "This must be rejected because it is simply
an expression of racial prejudice." If you do not reject scientific
investigation of the topic, then you are a bigot? They extend the
discussion briefly, to acknowledge that race correlates strongly for the
results within the United States but walk away after that. In the rest
of the book, correlation is king. Here it is dismissed as a joker.
Given this attempt to describe complex realities in simple terms,
the authors are compelled to marshal many just-so stories to make the
data fit the analysis. This narrow approach should be troubling to
sociologists, economists, or anyone doing policy analysis.
In Coming Apart, Charles Murray provides a useful expansion on
WP's discussion. (17) As with WP (44), but in far-greater depth,
Murray discusses the impact on measured income inequality of
"sorting" by class and education in marriage. As with WP
(164), but in far-greater detail, Murray describes the cultural barriers
increasingly implied by class differences. As with WP (chap. 9 and pp.
137-38), Murray talks about family structure and stability, but in a
more comprehensive and coherent manner. For example, WP argue at some
length that fathers and family structure matter--that there is more to
life than material goods. Then, apparently conflicted, they argue that
it seems "possible to safeguard children against most of the
adverse effects of being brought up by lone parents"
(187)--possible, but unlikely, given the bulk of the available research.
Policy Prescriptions
Even assuming away the above concerns, now what? In most cases, WP
are noticeably and appropriately hesitant to make policy prescriptions.
Other times they are mysteriously optimistic: "There are good
reasons to feel confident that we can create a society in which the real
quality of life... is far higher" (241). At the end of the day,
their data do not have much to say about how to achieve the implied and
desired ends. Hence, caution is the wise approach.
Wilkinson and Pickett are correct in pointing to the limits of
economic growth--at least on average, in developed countries (5). This
is a point made nicely in Charles Murray's indispensable book on
public policy in broad terms, In Pursuit of Happiness and Good
Government (Simon & Schuster, 1988). Murray uses Maslow's
hierarchy to note that material needs are the first goal but not the
only policy goal. In developed countries, the thresholds on material
needs can easily be (and have been) met--while using policy to move
beyond thresholds has relatively little value and creates a range of
other problems.
At times WP deviate a bit from policy humility and get themselves
into contradictory positions. Early on they trot out items from a common
laundry list of policy prescriptions: (18) housing, health care,
work/life balance, child support payments, and the "provision of
high-quality early childhood education" (112). (19) Later, they
argue that "attempts to deal with health and social problems
through the provision of specialized services have proven expensive and,
at best, only partially effective" (238). Then, as examples, they
cite a wide range of such efforts--police, medical care, social work,
drug rehab, and obesity--concluding that they are often "a form of
window-dressing, a display of good intentions" (238). They leave
unanswered or even unasked the question of how government actions could
be better motivated, informed, and executed. (20)
Wilkinson and Pickett also ignore the challenges of large-scale
federal policies in the United States, especially given the complexities
of poverty and all sorts of diversity in a population. To sum up, one
would expect federal policy to be more beneficial with smaller and more
homogeneous populations and more damaging as population and diversity
increase.
Exploring the many reasons cited by economists for middle class
struggles and growing income inequality over the last forty years, WP
unfortunately focus on Paul Krugman. (21) He argues that inequality has
been driven by reduced unions, a lower real minimum wage, and changes in
taxes and benefits (22)--a carefully chosen subset of the causes laid
out by economists. Wilkinson and Pickett conclude by citing a straw man:
"changes in income distribution are almost never attributable
simply to market forces influencing wage rates"--so as to move to
the claim that the key is "something much more like the changes in
institutions, norms and the use of political power which Krugman
describes in the U.S." (243).
Conclusion
Ultimately, income inequality and poverty raise ethical and
practical questions, both in terms of current outcomes and potential
(policy and nonpolicy) remedies. (23) Wilkinson and Pickett are helpful
on the practical side of wrestling with the potential impact of income
inequality. Nonetheless, one should recognize the limits and flaws in
their analysis and should not forget about poverty or the practical and
ethical limits of public policy.
At the end of the day, WP is worth a read for those who have
invested heavily in this realm. For novices who want to jump into the
topic, I would start with two more-helpful, less-statistical, and
easier-to-read books: Tyler Cowen's Average Is Over (Dutton Books,
2013) and especially, Charles Murray's Coming Apart (Crown Books,
2013).
Notes
(1.) One problem exists: the subtitle is good, but the title of the
book does not prompt its potential audience to think of its primary
topic--income inequality.
(2.) I certainly do not know all of the amazingly broad literature
well. However from the areas I do know, I would infer that they are
selective in a biased sense.
(3.) For example, WP have an odd focus on "anthropogenic
global warming" (AGW) throughout the book (but especially in
chapter 15)--at least in terms of their efforts to connect it to their
book's thesis. When authors go so far afield, it raises red flags
about objectivity and worldview. That said, they have an innovative
reference to "tradeable carbon quotas" (222)--the sort of
approach that would be bothersome to most people concerned with AGW.
(4.) This contrasts with Thomas Piketty's more famous (or
infamous) book, Capital in the Twenty-First Century (Cambridge: Belknap
Press, 2014).
(5.) A. M. C. Waterman, "Inequality and Social Evil: Wilkinson
and Pickett on the Spirit Level," Faith and Economics (Spring
2014): 38-49.
(6.) See David Cutler and Lawrence Katz, "Rising Inequality?
Changes in the Distribution of Income and Consumption in the
1980s," AEA Papers and Proceedings (May 1992): 546-51; David S.
Johnson, Timothy M. Smeeding, and Barbara Boyle Torrey "Economic
Inequality Through the Prisms of Income and Consumption," Monthly
Labor Review 128, no. 4 (April 2005): 11-24; and Bruce Meyer and James
Sullivan, "Five Decades of Consumption and Income Poverty,"
NBER Working Paper #14827, March 2009.
(7.) Wilkinson and Pickett offer a brief mention of the aggregates
(228) but do not discuss work differences between income classes.
(8.) Robert Reich provides the foreword for the book and provides a
useful corrective here (xi). "CEO pay" turns out to be a
complicated theoretical issue with a very mixed bag of empirical
results. "The market for CEO's" is not the most
competitive, but its flaws are often exaggerated. It is also really
difficult to measure well. Not surprisingly, one can find empirical
results all over the board.
(9.) For a useful set of essays on the related topics, see
"Income Inequality in America: Fact and Fiction," Manhattan
Institute, e21 Policy Brief, May 2014.
(10.) Even so, WP still occasionally stumble. See, for example,
"most deprived neighborhoods" (195) and "denying adequate
incomes" (264).
(11.) It is not clear whether this stems from its rhetorical
usefulness or its lack of empirical knowledge and theoretical rigor.
(12.) See chapter 1, D. Eric Schansberg, Poor Policy (Boulder, CO:
Westview Press, 1996).
(13.) Among many variables on "community life" in chapter
4, WP discuss "trust" and find significant differences between
countries. This is not an area of expertise for me, but I have read one
scholar who says that the international differences on this metric are
not significant: Dan Ariely, The Honest Truth About Dishonesty: How We
Lie to Everyone--Especially Ourselves (New York: Harper Perennial,
2013).
(14.) See Robert H. Frank, Falling Behind: How Rising Inequality
Harms the Middle Class (Oakland: University of California Press, 2007).
(15.) Without any apparent sense of irony, WP (246) cite New
Hampshire and Vermont as examples of respectively low and high tax
burdens. The two states have similar cultures, populations, and results,
so the differential tax burden seems unrelated to the outcomes.
(16.) See Thomas Sowell, Race and Culture (New York: Basic Books,
1995).
(17.) Charles Murray, Coming Apart: The State of White America,
1960-2010 (New York: Crown Forum, 2013).
(18.) Likewise, trade unions get a positive but passing
reference--without any explanation of how private-sector unions could
rebound in an increasingly competitive and globalized economy (245).
(19.) Wilkinson and Pickett are apparently unaware of the US
government's expensive and largely failed attempts to do the latter
through Head Start. See Health and Human Services, "Third Grade
Follow-up to the Head Start Impact Study: Final Report," OPRE
Report 2012-45, October 2012.
(20.) Wilkinson and Pickett want to avoid "concentrating power
in the hands of the State" (255), but they say nothing about doing
so with health care--or more importantly here, with K-12 education. One
might reasonably hope to improve the K-12 education system by reducing
the concentrated (monopoly) power "in the hands of the State"
and empowering those in lower classes through enhanced school choice
(tax credits, educational vouchers, charter schools, and so on). They do
include an odd claim about public school spending--public spending as a
percentage of total spending (not overall spending or spending
inequality) is the key variable (161). On what theoretical basis would
one choose that variable? This seems like the sort of variable choice
that springs from data-mining or ideology.
(21.) Because WP are not Americans, they might reasonably rely on
the popular and prolific Krugman as their primary guide to all things
American. Giving the benefit of the doubt, we can excuse them for this
instance of fallacy-of-authority.
(22.) Ironically, proponents of these changes typically focus on
pre-tax/transfer measures of income inequality.
(23.) Waterman, "Inequality and Social Evil," 48-49,
applies the "seven deadly sins" to this discussion. See also
D. Eric Schansberg, Turn Neither to the Right nor to the Left: A
Thinking Christian's Guide to Politics and Public Policy
(Greenville, SC: Alertness Press, 2003) for a broad and thorough
discussion of ethical and practical angles to social and economic
policies.
D. Eric Schansberg
Professor of Economics Indiana University Southeast
(*) Kate Pickett and Richard Wilkinson, The Spirit Level: Why More
Equal Societies Always Do Better (London: Allen Lane, 2009; New York:
Bloomsbury, 2010).