The Economics of Good and Evil: The Quest for Economic Meaning from Gilgamesh to Wall Street.
Welker, Michael
The Economics of Good and Evil: The Quest for Economic Meaning from
Gilgamesh to Wall Street
Tomas Sedlacek
New York: Oxford University Press, 2011 (368 pages)
Here I am in my finest tweed, with a fine cigar in hand, a brandy
snifter on the table next to me, and a book cracked open to examine the
meaning of good and evil from the perspective that part of real human
life involves economics. Let us be clear, though. This book is not about
good and evil in themselves, but rather peers at them through a lens
that hints at notions often front and center in modern discussion--I
refer primarily to the post-Enlightenment discussion concerned with
pleasure, pain, and the like. Rather, we must sit down and consider a
wider range of sources on this question. The purpose is simply to help
us become more cognizant that economics--material reality and our
wellbeing--has always been only a minor factor in the human conquest of
happiness.
One might say that this book encouraged me to sit back and survey
historical expressions from the most ancient of civilizations to the
present day concerning the general meaning of economics. This book,
strictly speaking, does not really go head to head with the long
philosophical and theological intellectual tradition concerned with the
meaning of good and evil (along with how economics fits into this
discussion). However, by implication, and perhaps by way of a broader
impression of this book, one would say it aids us in discovering that
there may be good reason that the field of economics was not so
prominent in the past. Naturally, we tend to think, as economists, that
crucial economic questions only begin historically when the bourgeois
class arises, so that questions of preference satisfaction and the
valuation of a produced surplus are inexorably linked with historical
conditions.
What Sedlacek seems to want us to admit, however, is that questions
of economic value are very much present throughout the writings and epic
vision of past civilizations and religious traditions. Fundamentally, he
brings to life the particularly cogent references in such writings as
the Epic of Gilgamesh and certain features of the Jewish and Christian
scriptures, along with the contributions on happiness from Aristotle,
Plato, Augustine, Aquinas, Kant, Mandeville, Smith, Bentham, and so
forth. The trick to all this is showing how the central question of
economics, the core idea common to all accounts of our material
well-being, is the question of happiness--and by way of an intellectual
connecting of ideas, the question of what we value as good and what we
value as evil. Likewise, the lesson, though possibly lost to us if we
are not attentive to the broader effect of the text, is that our
happiness depends only partially on acquisition. This is a broadside
against policy and governance grounded in the vision that property is
sacrosanct and ultimate. As such, the book is a contribution that
perhaps wakes up leaders, making them much wiser. This is, after all, a
good thing, considering that it seems, of late, that we are blundering
our way through the twenty-first century (witness the European financial
debacle, the US real estate crisis, and a seemingly knee-jerk Keynesian
response to every economic downturn).
This is a neat trick indeed (making us wiser), and one that is
tough to pull off, considering all the varying views of happiness and
the varying attempts to connect a particular view of happiness to the
issue of valuation of production, or of valuation, in the primary sense,
of the goods of the earth. Sedlacek sticks with a basic core idea--to
examine the range of poetical, philosophical, and theological approaches
to human existence--to show us that economics has its roots in much else
beyond the traditional view that it was a field born in the
Enlightenment. The author does a fairly good job of avoiding possible
pitfalls along this historical journey, sticking closely to his aims--to
convince us that economic ideas abounded in any place human beings
discovered the wonders and the problems of exchange economies and
division of labor (thus, Xenephon, particularly, makes a showing).
However, any well-trained economist would already be quite familiar with
the history of economic thought: Any text worth its weight in greenbacks
on this topic stretches back to Aristotle, and adventurous tomes would
possibly include the Code of Hammurabi (wherein one will find strict
rules on the allocation of inheritances--allocations that surprisingly
align with optimal outcomes of multiplayer noncooperative game theory).
The stark improvement that Sedlacek offers here, over and against close
cousins in the field of economic and intellectual history, is the
inclusion of a modified angle of viewing historical contributions. This
modification is an admittedly simple adjustment; it is admitting up
front that the subject matter of economics is inherently of moral
importance.
The author proves to be fairly generous with respect to multiple
interpretations, perhaps not the least of which would have been a
temptation to rely on modern default views of the Old Testament and the
attractive yet usually (at least in economics-speak) irrelevant vision
of the Gilgamesh epic--a curious object of an ancient world, so to
speak, but perhaps no more than that. By addressing the contributions of
the many historical voices he wants to bring to this conversation, the
general effect is to remind readers, particularly policy makers and
analysts, that past thinkers tended to place economics in a particular
sphere: the sphere of ethics. Economics was often specified as a
conceptually less relevant sphere indexed to human skills, activities,
and competences regarded at a lower level in the hierarchy of knowledge.
It was perhaps not at the lowest end of the scale, but nearly there, as
opposed to the realms of warfare or of rhetoric--both regarded as
high-level intellectual endeavors in support of the greatest aspirations
of humans as political animals. In a way, Sedlacek is trying to
re-present a tradition that can aid us in the current debate about
whether humans are (also, or only?) economic animals. I like the way he
allows for a discovery of the historically relevant to reach a sort of
critical mass, as the evidence marshals for an argument.
However, this is where the book fails. In a sense, the evidence
raised suggests that we ought to broaden our vision of good and evil, so
that we come to better understand and evaluate economic policy. The
problem is that the book leaps to conclusions that need intermediate
arguments to make any headway against current political momentum. Let us
face it. The Keynesian vision of countercyclical short-run policy has a
great deal of historical evidence in its favor, despite troubles with
financial bubbles and the dangers of overregulation. Likewise,
macroeconomists have strong empirical support for the view that stable
prices can spur economic growth. Others will read Sedlacek and find
little to convince them that the bourgeois emphasis on unleashing the
natural commercial impulse is a false vision (at least on the basis of
practical effects for society--consider that economic growth and the
spread of capitalism produces much good, including reductions in
poverty, hunger, illiteracy, oppression, and so forth).
In a way, the book is a good history test for its audience. I would
regard it as a helpful start in expanding one's intellectual
journey with the aim of integrating every bit of helpful knowledge into
a broad vision of human life--a vision that includes this adventure into
epic literature, sacred scripture, and any contribution that may assist
us, acting as a sort of trump card, in fashioning economic policy that
is humane and, ultimately, good (rather than evil). Indeed, the text
cannot be the last word on such a grand and complex issue, but it
achieves a basic (perhaps unintended) purpose: The writing on the
historical facts fascinates, it is never tiresome, and it helps us
recover some sense of tradition (meant in the neutral sense, not the
political sense). Thus one could think of the topics that Sedlacek
presents to us as a sort of Dark Continent for modern thinkers. In a
way, we start our reading of this book with a somewhat informed sense of
the sources, insofar as we can distinguish that Aristotle was a truly
important Greek philosopher and the Old Testament is not a univocal
treatise on human nature. Rather, we are encouraged to really engage
those texts that organically arose from a sense of wonder and the
supernatural--texts that seem irrelevant and distant from our very real
problems. The systematic disclosure here offers details and
interpretations that show the richness and diversity of the Great
Conversation, along with a laudable attempt to integrate such into
present-day discourse.
--Michael Welker
Franciscan University, Steubenville, Ohio