Corporate welfare.
Delery, Jeanette ; Block, Walter
Welfare bums and welfare queens are by no means limited to the
public housing projects. They are also to be found in the corporate
boardrooms of some of the most prestigious business firms in the nation,
but wherever found, this system is corrupting and inefficient.
Government efforts to direct capital to its most productive uses have
been a dismal failure, compared to private money managers and
entrepreneurs. This is because the latter, but not the former, face a
"cruel" market test every day, which weeds out inefficiency.
The phrase corporate welfare has been coined to portray the idea
that government involvement in the economy is innately corrupting; it
also imparts the information that there are welfare bums and welfare
queens to be found in the boardroom and not just in the public-housing
projects. This particular intervention comes in every conceivable shape
and size: grants, sweetheart business deals arranged by the commerce
department, cut-rate insurance, low-interest loans, a protective wall
against foreign competition, exclusive contracts, and a mind-boggling
maze of other special interest privileges (Moore 1997, 3). (1) The
phrase conveys the debilitating effects that government subsidies impose
on corporations, which parallel the dependent and self-destructive
behavior bred by social programs for the poor. Instead of being
subsidized with millions of taxpayers' dollars, the fate of ailing
corporations should be left up to the cruel market test wherein only the
efficient survive the competition.
For most Americans, the term welfare is associated with any number
of negative images: laziness, illegitimacy, family breakup,
irresponsibility, and wasted tax dollars. As welfare brings to mind the
image of a "young unwed mother of two or three infants, huddled in
front of a TV set in a public housing tenement and living at taxpayer
expense on monthly Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) checks
and food stamps" (Moore 1997, 3), it is striking that
America's most costly welfare recipients today are actually Fortune
500 companies--recording best-ever earnings of $24 billion dollars in
1997--costing taxpayers $87 billion per year (Moore 1997, 3). (2)
Upholding his promise to "end welfare as we know it," and
urged by the American people to do so, President Clinton signed the
Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Act (PRWOA) in August of
1996. The Temporary Assistance of Needy Families (TANF) program, which
arose from this welfare reform, established a time limit on welfare
benefits as well as work, training, or education requirements in
exchange for benefits (policyalmanac.org). (3) The result is that the
number of people on welfare has declined roughly 50 percent from a 1994
peak, with "record levels of former recipients now working and
paying taxes, not collecting them" (Moore 1997).
Unfortunately, none of this reform ethic has taken root in the
realm of corporate welfare. (4) In fact, the business community has come
to regard subsidy payments as "de facto entitlements." There
is no five-years-and-off time limit when it comes to corporate handouts.
With the exception of a few "anticorporate welfare
warriors"--Republicans, Senator John McCain (5) and Representative
John Kasich; (6) Democrats, Senator Russ Feingold and Representative Tom
Andrews; and of course Libertarians across the board--almost no one
wants to make an enemy of big business. Even though there is bipartisan
support for eliminating many major corporate welfare programs, little
has been done to reduce the funding for them. While "Congress
typically rails indignantly against corporate handouts," it
"flinches when it comes time to make the cuts" (Moore 1999,
1). Congress will not even cut the most egregious corporate welfare
programs, such as the Department of Commerce's high-tech grants to
Silicon Valley, the advertising subsidies for Ralston Purina cat food,
and California's dancing raisins (Moore 1999, 4). The Bush
Administration has, however, hinted at its "intent to reappraise the federal government's role in subsidizing private
businesses" (Slivinski 2001, 2) and included a recommendation of
$12 billion in total corporate welfare cuts in its first proposed
budget. (7) Though meager, these are the largest proposed cuts in many
of these programs' budgets since Ronald Reagan was in the Oval
Office (Slivinski 2001, 8).
If corporate welfare is an unproductive end game, why does it keep
growing, even in a period of ostensible intensive government cost
cutting? For starters, it has good public relations and an army of
bureaucrats are working to expand it. A corporate-welfare bureaucracy of
an estimated eleven thousand organizers and agencies has grown up with
access to city halls, state houses, the Capitol, and the White House.
They offer attractive and well-financed seminars, conferences, and
training sessions. They have their own trade associations. They publish
their own journals and newsletters. They create attractive Web sites on
the Internet; they never call it welfare. Instead they characterize it
as "economic incentives," or "empowerment zones," or
"enterprise zones" ("Corporate Welfare" 1998, 38).
(8)
Whatever the name, the results are the same; corporate welfare is
intrinsically unfair. Some companies receive public services at reduced
rates, while others pay the full cost. Some companies are excused from
paying all or a portion of their taxes due, (9) while others pay the
full amount imposed by law. Some companies receive grants, low-interest
loans, and other subsidies, while others must fend for themselves
("Corporate Welfare" 1998, 38).
One supposed role of government is to help ensure a level playing
field for people and businesses. This so-called level playing field
intrinsically calls for minimal interference in the marketplace and
substantially reduced tax rates and regulatory burdens. Business
subsidies, which are often said to be justified because they correct
distortions in the marketplace, actually create huge distortions of
their own. Business subsidies divert credit and capital to politically
well-connected firms (which are not necessarily the most efficient
producers) at the expense of their less politically influential rivals,
tilting the playing field in favor of the largest, most politically
influential, or most aggressive businesses (Slivinski 2001, 10).
Bureaucrats have a disappointing record of picking winners and
losers. The basic premise of federal business subsidies is that the
government can direct the limited pool of capital funds just as
effectively as, if not better than, venture capitalists and money
managers. The core function of private capital markets is to direct
investment to industries and firms that offer the highest potential rate
of return (Hazlitt 1979, 90). Natural selection occurs independent of
any intervention into the free-market system. The truth is that capital
markets rely on more sophisticated knowledge, and in much larger
quantities, than a government could ever collect, use effectively, or
even fathom (Hayek 1948). This fact dooms most capital allocation
decisions by bureaucrats to failure (Slivinski 2001, 9). Capital markets
require that the President and Congress cut those programs and tax
provisions that artificially raise the rate of return for particular
corporations, (10) which interfere with market signals for no overriding
social or economic purpose (Hazlitt 1979, 90).
Corporate welfare fosters an incestuous relationship between
businesses and government. In Washington today, industry trade
associations and lobbying firms continually pressure lawmakers to give
out new business subsidies or to protect longstanding handouts. This is
a natural byproduct of an administration that uses its power to give
taxpayer money to favored interests. If there were no possibility that
subsidies might be offered, demands for them would naturally diminish if
not disappear altogether. The reality, however, is that the federal
government has been redistributing wealth virtually since its inception
(Slivinski 2001, 10).
This system is sustained by a budget process that stacks the deck
in favor of new spending. It is also nurtured by the problem of diffuse
costs and concentrated benefits, as seen when subsidies are given to a
few at the expense of many (Moore 1999, 12; Friedman 1962). Because
there is such a large number of taxpayers--any given corporate welfare
subsidy may cost each taxpayer only a few cents--most individual
citizens do not have an interest in lobbying against subsidies; the cost
of doing so far outweighs simply paying the taxes. However, the
recipients of those subsidies have a substantial interest in making sure
they maintain this flow of money. Thus, there is a great deal of
lobbying by special interests with very little counteraction on behalf
of the longsuffering taxpayer. In addition, subsidies create a perverse
incentive for businesses; if their competitors are receiving help from
the government, it is in their best interest to try to avail themselves
of it too. That incentive serves only to turn many businesspeople into
lobbyists, not entrepreneurs (Slivinski 2001, 10).
Some argue that condemning corporate welfare eliminates public
policy's influence on the direction of private investment and other
resource allocation --thereby hobbling government (Laird and Reich 1998,
74). However, corporate subsidy programs lie outside Congress'
strictly limited and enumerated spending authority under the
Constitution and thus should be eliminated if only for that reason.
Nowhere in the Constitution is Congress granted the authority to spend
funds to subsidize the computer industry or to enter into joint ventures
with automobile companies or to guarantee loans to favored business
owners. The main effects of such corporate welfare programs are to
undermine free enterprise and corrupt the political system as well
(Moore 1999, 15). Yet, particularly since the New Deal, by applying very
expansive readings of the "general welfare" clause, the
Supreme Court has allowed Congress to redistribute wealth from taxpayers
to favored business interests (Slivinski 2001, 11).
Advocates of corporate welfare often maintain that federal support
of business is in the national interest--"Can't afford to
subsidize? ... can't afford not to subsidize!" (Wipond 1996,
47). However, the arguments in support of corporate welfare do not stand
up under scrutiny.
Corporate welfare is said to preserve high-paying American jobs.
Subsidies have grown in recent years, without any indication that the
benefits they confer on the public exceed the costs. The justification
for much of the welfare is that the U.S. government is creating jobs.
While James A. Harmon, president and chairman of the Export-Import Bank
of the United States (which has received billions in subsidies) (11)
contends that "American workers ... have higher-quality,
better-paying jobs, thanks to Eximbank's financing"
("Corporate Welfare" 1998, 37) at the companies that have
accounted for about forty of all Eximbank's loans, grants, and
long-term guarantees in the 1990s, overall employment has fallen, as
more than a third of a million jobs have disappeared ("Corporate
Welfare" 1998, 37).
In 1991, prohibitive duties were placed on low-cost Japanese
computer parts. The motivation was to save jobs in the U.S. factories
that made computer circuit boards. The decision to keep out foreign
parts inflated (by almost $1,100) the cost of a personal computer
manufactured by U.S. companies, such as IBM, Apple, Microsoft, and
Compaq. That gave a huge advantage to Japanese computer companies; it
significantly reduced sales of the domestic computer firms; and, worst
of all, thousands of Americans were thrown into unemployment (Moore
1999, 8).
Corporate welfare is said to subsidize research activities that
private industries would not finance themselves. Many Fortune 500
companies have received millions of dollars of funding to undertake
research they could easily finance on their own. Government funding of
research often ends up simply underwriting other aspects of corporate
operations. Created in 1982, the Small Business Innovation Research
(SBIR) program's goal is to "stimulate technological
innovation" (Wallsten 2000, 13). Rather than stimulate
technological progress, SBIR subsidies effectively crowd out private
research and development. Subsidies are apparently going to
"better" firms whose projects would likely be funded even
without federal support. The SBIR program provides an incentive for
companies to cut their research budgets and pass research and
development costs on to the government (Wallsten 2000, 15).
Arguably, let us ignore this crowding-out effect and assume that
government subsidies to research and development actually succeed in
increasing funds devoted to this purpose. Would that imply a benefit to
the economy? Not at all. There is, contrary to the advocates of
subsidies for this purpose, such a thing as overinvestment in research
(Kinsella 2001). In the absence of any reason to believe that the market
does not optimally allocate resources between innovation and all other
purposes, the presumption must be that government support for these
expenditures, to the extent they succeed, have the effect of promoting
malinvestments in the economy.
Corporate welfare is said to counteract the business subsidies of
foreign governments to ensure a level playing field. In fact, when it
comes to subsidies and trade barriers, often instituted to maintain
competitiveness, they actually hinder proper economic development. There
are currently thousands of tariffs levied on thousands of goods and
import quotas imposed on numerous others. All of these barriers have the
effect of protecting domestic industries from foreign competition in
goods and services. They also restrict the free flow of goods in the
economy, leading to decreased supply, foregone economic production, and
higher prices for consumers (Slivinski 2001, 25). No one knows precisely
the total cost to American consumers of barriers to free trade, but
several authoritative sources place the figure at $80 billion a year.
"There is virtually no specific U.S. trade restriction the economy
wide costs of which do not exceed the industry-specific benefits"
(Moore 1999, 8). Therefore, Congress should immediately lift all
barriers to free trade.
Lower prices of products for consumers would be one immediate and
tangible benefit of abolishing trade barriers that support and protect
favored domestic industries. If subsidy cuts were accompanied by tax
cuts, the lowering of the tax burden would be another clear benefit to
consumers, workers, and the U.S. economy. (12) That factor alone would
make the United States even more competitive with the high-tax,
high-subsidy nations of the European community and Japan.
Protectionism produces no substantial gains. Industrial policies
and the politics of "crony capitalism," for instance, have
begun to collapse and cause economic problems in Japan13 and elsewhere
in Asia. Japan is beginning to abandon the very policies that proponents
of U.S. corporate welfare support (Slivinski 2001, 9).
Domestic subsidies cost the United States jobs, business formation,
and overall growth. Not only do they reduce normal competitive pressures
to innovate, they also place industries not receiving favored treatment
at a disadvantage by effectively raising their costs of capital and
labor relative to subsidized sectors (Moore 1999, 13).
There is a second argument against U.S. government subsidies to
U.S. businesses as a response to similar practices abroad: There is
nothing wrong, from our perspective, with the latter practice. That is,
suppose that Japan subsidizes its automobile manufacturers to the extent
that Honda, Toyota, and so forth can afford to sell their products to
the U.S. consumer for half price. This, naturally, would tend to drive
out of business all U.S. auto producers. (14)
If this program is expected to last indefinitely, it is in effect a
subsidy from the Japanese government to U.S. consumers. Why should we
look such a gift horse in the mouth? In the face of such Japanese
largesse, we no more need U.S. car production than we now need horse and
buggy manufacture, thanks to the largesse of improved technology that
has long ago vitiated a previous need for the products of that industry.
Similarly, if the French were to give us free or heavily subsidized
wine, it would no longer be rational for us to invest resources in this
product. Under these stipulations, the reasonable course of action is
for people in the U.S. automobile and wine industries to shift to the
production of goods and services that are not being given to us for
free, or at artificially low prices. What is the point of doing those
things for ourselves, at great cost, if others will do them for us for
free?
However, suppose these gifts are really Trojan horses. They are not
really gifts made to us out of the goodness of the hearts of the
Japanese and French governments. Instead, posit that this beneficence is
only a ruse, an attempt to get us to transfer factors of production out
of the wine and auto industries, and when this nefarious predatory
pricing scheme has unfolded, they will jack up prices to astronomical
levels, after having made us dupes, dependent upon their only temporary
largesse.
If true, then we can foil their evil machinations by leaving
skeleton crews in the wine and auto industries (McGee 1958), ready to
spring immediately back into action when and if these wicked plans are
put into action. Further, there will be every incentive for U.S. firms
to do precisely this if they suspect that the foreign subsidies are
merely a gambit in an attempt to ruin our domestic industries. In the
meantime, while the getting is still good, it would be folly for the
U.S. government to subsidize the manufacture of these products so that
they may be fully operational, during the phase of the diabolical
foreign plan to hook us on their wares.
Perhaps for different reasons, both the Left and the Right in
America should recognize the damaging effects of the expansion of the
modern corporate welfare state. Democrats should understand that
corporate welfare is the essence of corrupt government (Bartlett 1997).
We have basically put Uncle Sam up for sale to the highest
bidder--"that is seldom the poor, the disabled, or the
working-class family with two wage earners struggling to pay the
electric bills each month" (Moore 1999, 4). Meanwhile, Republicans
on the Right should see that business handouts make big business a mere
ward of the state--an advocate of government expansionism and a
well-financed enemy of Adam Smith's invisible-hand capitalism.
Corporate welfare, in sum, is "the antithesis of good government
and the antithesis of a free-market economic system" (Moore 1999,
4).
On the one hand, there is an insidious effect of special privileges
(15) for corporations that ought to be keenly appreciated by those with
an interest in markets and morality: Such goings-on undermine the
morality of the business community. Suppose you are the CEO of a
corporation. As a moral businessman, the last thing you would do would
be to seek a special subsidy from the government. However, you know that
your competitors are likely, more than likely, to tread down this
morally dangerous path. If you do not, you will to that extent risk the
economic viability of your firm. On the other hand, you have an
obligation to the stockholders of your company to maximize their return
by all legal methods. Unhappily, the law is such that you will not be
imprisoned for seeking just such unfair advantages. The result is a
moral quandary.
Nor is this difficulty by any means limited to the business
community. It affects all of us, in our role as consumers, citizens,
members of society, and so forth. For example, is it not to take
advantage of government subsidies to use such government institutions as
the Post Office, public roads, and Bureau of Motor Vehicles. Virtually
all of us will accept Social Security, police and fire protection, and
so forth. Are we all not, therefore, welfare bums of a sort?
One defense of this practice is that we are all "just getting
our own money back," and, it cannot be denied that this is true in
at least many cases, but not all. The scope of the present article does
not allow for a solution to this predicament (Block 2004; Block,
forthcoming). Here, we must content ourselves with pointing out that
government subsidies create highly complex moral quandaries.
Notes
(1.) Note, we do not mention tax loopholes. Strictly speaking, to
say that a failure to tax is a subsidy is to imply that government is
the legitimate owner of the entire gross domestic product (GDP): What
the state fails to take from the citizen it is really "giving"
to him. This notion, of course, must be rejected as irrational and out
of keeping with the doctrine of private property rights.
(2.) Similarly, welfare bum and corporate welfare bum depict the
pejorative manner in which both groups are helped by many segments of
the populace.
(3.) To address long-term welfare dependency, TANF placed a
five-year lifetime limit on assistance, and also stipulated that by
2002, 50 percent of families on assistance in every state must be
engaged in work-related activities (policyalmanac.org).
(4.) President Clinton also proclaimed his intent to reinvent
government and end irresponsible business subsidies; however, he
proposed aggregate increases of 10 percent for major corporate welfare
programs almost every year he was in office (Slivinski 2001, 2).
(5.) In 1997, Senator John McCain (R-AZ) and a bipartisan group of
senators and outside interest groups announced their support for
legislation to curb business subsidies (Bartlett 1997).
(6.) In the House, Budget Committee Chairman John Kasich formed a
one-man crusade against welfare for the well off. In 1997, he formed the
Stop Corporate Welfare Coalition, an eclectic group that runs across the
political spectrum, from Grover Norquist on the Right to Ralph Nader on
the Left (Moore 1997, 28).
(7.) These proposed bills still have to go through conference
committee to have their differences worked out, but the original bills
can give a preliminary indication of where the budgets of individual
programs might end up (Slivinski 2001, 8). Spending bills working their
way through the House and Senate Appropriations Committees have,
however, reversed or diluted most of Bush's proposed cuts
(Slivinski 2001, 1).
(8.) To the extent that enterprise zones are limited to tax
reductions, they do not constitute corporate welfare. Typically,
however, they include much more, such as explicit government subsidies
to business.
(9.) See endnote 1, supra, for a critique of the concept of tax
subsidies.
(10.) By these restrictive policies, wages and capital returns
might indeed be kept higher than otherwise for the particular company,
but wages and capital returns for other corporations would be forced
down, lower than otherwise. That company would benefit only at the
expense of the other corporations (Hazlitt 1979, 101).
(11.) The House bill advocates a cut of $125 million, or 15
percent, as opposed to Bush's proposed cut of 25 percent (Slivinski
2001, 8).
(12.) If corporate welfare were eliminated tomorrow, the federal
government could provide taxpayers with an annual tax cut more than
twice as large as the tax rebate checks mailed out in 2001 (Slivinski
2001, 2).
(13.) In Japan, the myth of industrial policy as a competitiveness
strategy has led to a 60 percent reduction in the value of the Japanese
stock market since 1990 (Moore 1999).
(14.) Nowadays, it is not so easy to distinguish between U.S. and
foreign producers of road vehicles, as many of the latter have opened up
plants in this country.
(15.) Some writers use the word privilege as a synonym for wealth.
He is privileged means he is rich. We abjure such word usage. Instead,
in our view, privilege in this context means an unwarranted advantage
given to some companies but not others.
References
Almanac of Policy Issues. 2001. Policy News Publishing. 18
November. http://www.policyalmanac.org.
Bartlett, Bruce. 1997. "Corporate Welfare's Country
Cousins." Washington Times. 6 February.
Block, Walter. 2004. "Radical Libertarianism: Applying
Libertarian Principles to Dealing with the Unjust Government, Part
I." Reason Papers 27 (Fall): 117-33.
Block, Walter. Forthcoming. "Radical Libertarianism: Applying
Libertarian Principles to Dealing with the Unjust Government, Part
II." Reason Papers 28.
"Corporate Welfare." 1998. Time. 9 November, 36.
Friedman, Milton. 1962. Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Hazlitt, Henry. 1979. Economics in One Lesson. New York: Crown
Publishers.
Hayek, Friedrich A. 1948. "The Use of Knowledge in
Society," Individualism and Economic Order. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Kinsella, N. Stephan. 2001. "Against Intellectual
Property," The Journal of Libertarian Studies 13, no. 2 (Spring):
1-53.
Laird, Frank, and Robert Reich. 1998. "The Rhetoric of
'Corporate Welfare.'" The American Prospect 40
(September-October): 74-77.
McGee, John S. 1958. "Predatory Price Cutting: The Standard
Oil (New Jersey) Case," The Journal of Law and Economics (October),
137-69.
Moore, Stephen. 1997. "Corporate welfare queens."
National Review 49, no. 9 (May 19): 27, 28;
http://www.findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m1282/is_n9_v49/ai_19421987.
--. 1999. "Welfare for the Well-Off: How Business Subsidies
Fleece Taxpayers." Hoover Institution Essays in Public Policy
(May).
Slivinski, Stephen. 2001. "The Corporate Welfare Budget:
Bigger Than Ever." Cato Institute Policy Analysis 415 (October 10).
Wallsten, Scott J. 2000. "The R&D Boondoggle."
Regulation 23, no. 4: 12-16.
http://www.cato.org/pubs/regulation/regv23n4/wallsten.pdf.
Wipond, Rob. 1996. "No, You're Living off My Back; the
Other Point of View on Subsidies." The Humanist 56, no. 4
(July-August): 46, 47.
Jeanette Delery
Christian Brothers University
Walter Block
Harold E. Wirth Eminent Scholar
Endowed Chair and Professor of Economics
Loyola University New Orleans