首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月28日 星期四
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:How do predatory lending laws impact bank performance?
  • 作者:Hendrickson, Jill M. ; Nichols, Mark W.
  • 期刊名称:Academy of Banking Studies Journal
  • 印刷版ISSN:1939-2230
  • 出版年度:2011
  • 期号:January
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:The DreamCatchers Group, LLC
  • 摘要:The past decade has witnessed a significant expansion of credit for many in the United States. This is particularly true for minority borrowers, those with limited or poor credit histories and those with low-incomes. Banks and other financial institutions have increasingly offered credit to this segment of the market and have frequently benefited from higher earnings on these loans. As evidence of the growth in this market, consider that in 1995, loan originations in the sub-prime market were $65 billion and by 2003 originations increased to $332 billion (Chomsisengphat and Pennington-Cross, 2006). However, as the subprime market expanded, so did concerns regarding who was receiving these high-priced loans. Awareness became particularly acute in the fall of 2007 and the expansion of the financial crisis. Each year, Housing and Urban Development (HUD) compiles a list of subprime lenders and has used this information to make the case that much of the subprime lending in the United States has been in low-income and minority neighborhoods. Others, for example, Immergluck (1999) and Marsico (2001) also find evidence that subprime lending growth is greater in low-income and minority areas. There is also concern regarding the outcome of these lending relationships; specifically, the increasing number of foreclosures and loan delinquencies. Taken together, the concern over subprime lenders targeting a certain segment of the population and the undesirable outcome of many of these loans, these developments prompted consumer advocacy groups and regulatory bodies to take a look at this growing market.
  • 关键词:Banking industry;Financial crises;Loans;Predatory lending

How do predatory lending laws impact bank performance?


Hendrickson, Jill M. ; Nichols, Mark W.


INTRODUCTION

The past decade has witnessed a significant expansion of credit for many in the United States. This is particularly true for minority borrowers, those with limited or poor credit histories and those with low-incomes. Banks and other financial institutions have increasingly offered credit to this segment of the market and have frequently benefited from higher earnings on these loans. As evidence of the growth in this market, consider that in 1995, loan originations in the sub-prime market were $65 billion and by 2003 originations increased to $332 billion (Chomsisengphat and Pennington-Cross, 2006). However, as the subprime market expanded, so did concerns regarding who was receiving these high-priced loans. Awareness became particularly acute in the fall of 2007 and the expansion of the financial crisis. Each year, Housing and Urban Development (HUD) compiles a list of subprime lenders and has used this information to make the case that much of the subprime lending in the United States has been in low-income and minority neighborhoods. Others, for example, Immergluck (1999) and Marsico (2001) also find evidence that subprime lending growth is greater in low-income and minority areas. There is also concern regarding the outcome of these lending relationships; specifically, the increasing number of foreclosures and loan delinquencies. Taken together, the concern over subprime lenders targeting a certain segment of the population and the undesirable outcome of many of these loans, these developments prompted consumer advocacy groups and regulatory bodies to take a look at this growing market.

The initial regulatory response was federal regulation followed shortly by state regulation, in many states. In general, these laws restrict high cost loans, their fees and rates. The state level regulation varies tremendously from one state to another. Perhaps one reason for the variation is that there is no consensus on a definition of predatory lending. Engel and McCoy (2001) provide a set of loan criteria that define predatory lending to include at least one of the following: loans that provide no benefit to the borrower; loans with misleading nondisclosures; loans with fraud or deception; loans that require the borrower to forego redress; or loans that earn 'supranormal' profits. Pennington-Cross and Ho (2008) defined predatory lending to be whenever the borrower is unable to understand the terms and obligations of the loan. Morgan (2007) argues that any welfare-reducing form of credit can be labeled predatory lending. Similarly, the U.S. Government Accountability Office (GAO) defines a predatory loan to be one which contains terms that will ultimately harm the borrower (2004). Stressing the asymmetric information problem between the borrower and lender, Morgan (2007) defines a predatory loan to be one which the borrower would certainly decline if she shared the same information as the lender. Clearly there is no universal definition. However, it is accepted that predatory lending occurs within the subprime market. Not all subprime loans are predatory but most predatory loans are considered subprime.

Generally speaking, the predatory credit market is a subset of the subprime market. Because of a lack of data, it is not known how large this market actually is. There have been some micro estimates of the size of predatory lending. For example, Goldstein (2006) estimates that over 22 percent of all property loans in Philadelphia are predatory. Stock (2001) investigated whether predatory lending was instrumental in mortgage foreclosures in Montgomery County, Ohio. His sample of 1,198 mortgages indicated that 255 of these were predatory; this suggests that approximately 21 percent of the mortgages were predatory in this region. This limited research suggests that predatory lending is significant but certainly more evidence is required to draw conclusions about systemic practices.

With the first financial crisis of the twenty-first century, most Americans became aware of the subprime market and perhaps even of predatory lending. It seems likely that one response to the financial crisis will be increased regulation. More specifically, it is likely that regulators and policy makers will turn to predatory lending laws to keep the subprime mortgage market in check. If so, it is important to understand not only how these regulations impact the loan market but also the institutions that are extending the loans. That is, the predatory lending laws are, on the one hand, designed to protect borrowers from abusive lending practices. On the other hand, however, regulators and policy makers need to be careful that their regulatory decisions do not end up costing the lender so much that they retreat from this segment of the market. This paper attempts to inform regulatory and policy discussions by empirically testing whether predatory lending policies hurt the performance of the commercial bankers who are extending mortgage credit.

The second section of this paper provides a concise overview of the evolution of predatory lending laws and is followed in section three with a review of the salient literature. This is a relatively new field of literature as abusive lending practices have become more prevalent with the recent national policy emphasis to increase homeownership. The fourth section of the paper outlines the empirical specifications, data, and methods. Section five contains the empirical results and section six concludes. Briefly, the results indicate that national bank performance improved relative to state bank performance following a decision by the Office of the Comptroller to reduce the predatory lending regulatory burden on national banks.

BRIEF BACKGROUND OF FEDERAL AND STATE PREDATORY LENDING LAWS

As credit expanded to low-income and higher-risk individuals and as higher delinquencies and foreclosures became evident, community and consumer advocacy groups became more vocal about their concerns that lending abuse was taking place. The initial response to these concerns was the passage of a 1994 federal law known as the Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act (HOEPA) under Regulation Z at the Federal Reserve. The purpose of HOEPA was consumer protection from potentially abusive outcomes such as high interest rates and fees. HOEPA defined loans that were closed-ended home equity loans that met APR and finance fee triggers. A closed-ended loan is one in which the borrower received a fixed sum that must be repaid over time. Protection from HOEPA was triggered if either the loan's APR exceeded a comparable Treasury bond by 8 percentage points on the first lien or if finance charges on the loan exceeded 8 percent of the loan amount or a fixed $480 amount adjusted for inflation using the consumer price index (Ho and Pennington-Cross, 2006). Further, for HOEPA-covered loans, there were lending restrictions which included no no-document loans, no balloon loans, no pre-payment penalties greater than 5 years, among others. It was anticipated that HOEPA would reduce the predatory lending that came to light in the mid 1990s.

Nonetheless, a few years later, several government agencies (Housing and Urban Development, the Federal Reserve Board, and the U.S. Department of the Treasury) once again investigated the possibility of continued abuse in this segment of the credit market. At the end of 2000, the Federal Reserve called for more stringent restrictions on loans and an expanded definition of loans covered under HOEPA (Elliehausen and Staten, 2004). However, regulators were also aware that there was a fine line between protecting against lending abuses and also servicing the credit needs of these low-income and minority credit seekers. In the end, the changes to HOEPA recommended by the Federal Reserve were made in 2002. Hoping to strike a balance between cutting off credit to this segment of the market and protecting borrowers from abusive lending practices, this further defined HOEPA-covered loans to be those more likely to have predatory characteristics. Despite these changes in federal law, the ongoing growth in the subprime market led many to believe that the HOEPA changes were not sufficient. Indeed, a 2001 study found that HOEPA covers, at a maximum, only 5 percent of all subprime mortgages (Board of Governors, 2001).

In 1999 states responded by passing their own predatory lending laws which were more restrictive and prohibitive than the federal law. While state coverage is much broader than HOEPA, there is significant variance from state to state on the specifics of their predatory lending laws. Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006) capture the extent to which state laws extend HOEPA and also the variance between states by constructing empirical indexes for each state with predatory lending laws. More recently, Bostic et al. (2008) construct predatory lending law indexes as well. However, the Bostic work attempts to refine the work of Ho-Pennington-Cross (2006) by including four coverage measures and four restriction measures and also considers the enforcement of the state laws. In this way, the indexes more precisely indicate the legal environment in each state with respect to predatory lending laws. Like the Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006) indexes, those in Bostic et al. (2008) provide insight to the variation of the laws themselves and the enforcement of the laws.

The discussion above indicates that the regulatory environment for predatory lending began with federal regulation in 1994 and was enhanced beginning in 1999 as states began implementing even more stringent laws. Consequently, for ten years, between 1994 and 2004, there was a mix of both federal and state (in some states) predatory lending laws in the United States. During this time frame, all banks operating in a state with state predatory lending laws were required to follow these laws. This changed in 2004 when the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) issued a ruling that state predatory lending laws were preempted by federal statute (see Hawke, 2004). This meant that nationally chartered banks, whose primary regulator is the OCC, were exempt from state predatory lending laws. The OOC's position was that national banks were already subject to federal anti-predatory lending laws and also not significantly engaged in predatory lending to warrant the burden of additional state law (Office of the Comptroller, 2004).

Thus, following the final ruling by the OCC in 2004, nationally chartered banks were no longer legally required to meet state predatory lending laws. This means that state chartered banks are subject to more regulation in the post 2004 era than nationally chartered banks when it comes to issues of abusive lending practices. Since regulation is not without significant costs, it is reasonable to expect that nationally chartered banks should perform better than state chartered banks in those states with state predatory lending laws. Whalen (2008, 775) argues that these regulations may reduce revenue if banks make fewer mortgage loans in response to higher regulatory costs. This would, ceteris paribus, decrease bank profits and put state chartered banks at a competitive disadvantage to nationally chartered banks. The primary purpose of this paper is to determine if differences in these regulatory regimes hurts one classification of bank relative to another.

LITERATURE REVIEW

There are two salient bodies of literature that are relevant to the purpose of this paper. First is the literature that considers the impact of predatory lending laws on credit markets, the borrower, or the lender. This section of the paper begins with a review of this literature. Second, since an important assumption of this paper is that bank regulation will increase costs, ceteris paribus, this must be established. Consequently, the effect of bank regulation on costs is also considered in this literature review.

It is useful to classify existing predatory literature into four categories; that which considers the impact of predatory regulation on the flow of credit; that which considers how the regulation impacts the cost of credit; that which considers the likelihood of increased foreclosures from predatory credit; and, finally, that literature that considers the impact of the predatory regulation on the institutions extending credit. All four are discussed separately in this section of the paper. The first concerns the flow of subprime credit as a result of federal and state predatory lending laws. That is, this literature asks if the laws influenced the applications and originations for subprime mortgages. Much of this research finds a reduction in the flow of subprime credit (see, for example, Harvey and Nigro, 2003 and 2004, and Elliehausen and Staten, 2004), particularly the earliest research which focused on the North Carolina experience. Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006) extend the initial research beyond North Carolina to include ten states with predatory lending laws and they find that, generally speaking, there is little to no impact on the flow of credit from this regulation. However, their micro-analysis of the specific type of lending laws indicates a more mixed result: some laws reduce predatory lending, others increase it, and still others have no impact. The same authors also find mixed results in their follow-up work on predatory lending; Ho and Pennington-Cross (2007) find that in some states subprime originations decrease and in others, it increases. They hypothesize that this increase in lending may be because borrowers have fewer fears of predation and are more willing to try and obtain a loan. Bostic et al. (2008) also study the impact of predatory lending laws on the flow of credit. They find that when aggregated, the laws seem to have little to no impact of the flow of credit. However, Bostic et al. (2008) find that particular aspects of the law may impact credit flows. More specifically, they find that more restrictive laws reduce subprime originations and increase the likelihood the loan will be rejected. At the same time, they find that laws with broader coverage tend to reduce subprime applications but also have lower rejection rates. Like Bostic et al. (2008) and Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006), Li and Ernst (2007) find, in the aggregate, no change in the flow of credit as a result of predatory lending laws. Since the findings in the literature on the flow of subprime credit are mixed, there is ongoing inquiry.

The second type of subprime literature considers the impact of the predatory lending laws on the cost of credit. Pennington-Cross and Ho (2008) indicate that this is more challenging than the flow literature from the perspective that pricing in the subprime market is more complex than in the prime market. That is, determining interest rates on subprime loans is a function of multiple variables, for example, the borrowers' credit score, down payment amount, specific loan characteristics, etc. Further, increasingly, subprime loans carry adjustable rates which, themselves, are the result of a myriad of loan characteristics. According to Harvey and Nigro (2004), these subprime loans often carry higher interest rates because there is a lack of standardization in underwriting these loans which increases the cost to both originate and service the loans. That said, Pennington-Cross and Ho (2008) hypothesize that states with predatory lending laws have higher, systematic, interest rates on subprime mortgage loans as a result of higher regulatory compliance costs. To test their hypothesis, the authors perform two estimations with two different data sets. In the first, they use Home Mortgage Disclosure Data (HMDA) to examine the impact of lending laws on the annual percentage rates (APRs) of a subprime loan. The find no empirical evidence that predatory lending laws lead to higher APRs. In the second estimation, they rely on interest rate data from LoanPerformance Inc. on securitized subprime loans which is a data set largely confined to the top segment of the subprime population, known as the A- segment. They find a small increase in interest rate costs for fixed rate loans and a small decrease in interest rate costs for adjustable rate loans.

Many states that adopted predatory lending laws did so to reduce the number of foreclosures that are said to be the result, in part, from predatory loans. The third classification of predatory regulation literature investigates how these laws impact foreclosures. For example, Rose (2008) investigates the Chicago metropolitan area and determines that lending laws may or may not be effective in influencing foreclosure rates. His empirical analysis suggests that the relationship between foreclosure rates and loan characteristics is complicated; not all limitations on lending found in predatory lending laws reduce foreclosures. Quercia et al. (2007) ask if loans with predatory characteristics are associated with an increased likelihood of foreclosure. These authors find significant evidence to suggest that refinanced loans with specific predatory loan characteristics are more likely to foreclose than other types of non-predatory loans. Generally, these findings have implications for the regulation of predatory, and other, type of lending.

A fourth subset of the predatory lending literature concerns the impact that predatory lending laws have on bank performance as a result of regulatory compliance. For example, Whalen (2008) uses an event study approach to determine if the OCC's preemption decisions in Georgia that allow national banks to circumvent state predatory lending laws give an advantage to one charter type over another. Using stock values to measure wealth, Whalen (2008) finds that the preemption did not create an advantage for national banks; only small, geographically diverse national banks witnessed increased performance. He offers the possibility that preemption reduced these small bank costs attributable to regulatory compliance and scale. Whalen (2008) is the only work that considers the impact of predatory regulation on the lending institutions. Consequently, there is room for further analysis on the issue of the impact of predatory regulation on the institutions affected by the laws.

A comprehensive review of the regulatory costs in banking is found in Elliehausen (1998). In this work, Elliehausen carefully documents the research related to methods of measuring regulatory costs including case studies, surveys, and econometric analysis, among others. Across all methodologies, the findings are consistent: regulation increases the cost of delivering banking products and services. Further, compliance costs are significantly greater for smaller banks. That is, there are scale economies for regulatory costs in banking.

Given the overwhelming evidence found in Elliehausen (1998), it seems safe to assume that regulation increases bank costs. Consequently, it is reasonable to ask if predatory lending regulation laws put state bank performance at a disadvantage relative to national banks. In doing so, this paper makes several important contributions to the literature. First, to the author's knowledge, there is no existing work, outside of Whalen (2008), that investigate how predatory lending laws impact bank performance. If banks pursue lending strategies to maximize their profits and if laws are created to change the nature of lending, it seems this would negatively impact bank profitability and stability. Whalen (2008) admits that there is no empirical evidence related to these issues so that the debate about both predatory lending and the preemption's effects on banks is ongoing. Where Whalen (2008) considered the impact at bank holding companies on their wealth (stock value), this paper considers several measures of bank performance using balance sheet and income statement data.

Second, this paper relies on some unique data that has not been utilized in the literature to date. The three most common sources of data in the predatory lending literature are the HMDA data used by Pennington-Cross and Ho (2008), Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006 and 2008), Bostic et al. (2008) and Whalen (2008), the HUD data used in Harvey and Nigro (2004), Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006) and Bostic et al. (2008) and the LoanPerformance Inc. data (a private data vendor) in Pennington-Cross and Ho (2008), Li and Ernst (2007), Quercia et al. (2007), Demyanyk and Hermert (2008), and Rose (2008). A less utilized data source in the literature is the American Financial Services Association data in Elliehausen and Nigro (2004). This paper follows existing literature by utilizing the HMDA Aggregate Reports data to identify the banks in our sample and then relies on the FDIC for firm level data. However, this paper also utilizes survey data from the Conference of State Bank Supervisors to identify the legal bank environment in each state.

IDENTIFICATION AND ESTIMATION

The hypothesis tested in this paper is that the OCC's preemption of state predatory lending laws improves the performance and stability of nationally chartered banks relative to state charted banks in those states with predatory lending laws. To empirically test this hypothesis, a difference-in-difference-in-differences (DDD) model is estimated. Before presenting this, however, the sample of states with and without predatory lending laws is described.

Identifying which states have predatory lending laws is not as straightforward as one may expect because there are different definitions of predatory lending laws. There are two primary existing works that attempt to quantify state predatory lending laws; these are Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006) and Bostic et al. (2008). Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006) construct three indexes for each state; one captures the extent to which the state law broadens HOEPA; a second captures how restrictive each state is relative to others; and the third combines the first two for an overall measure of regulatory rigor. The difference in these indexes highlights the variation across states and also provides evidence for identifying which states have a greater regulatory burden. In their work, Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006) focus on states with laws that use triggers similar to HOEPA to define an abusive loan. Consequently, some states with predatory lending laws, but without triggers, are not in their sample.

Bostic et al. (2008) also construct predatory lending indexes for each state. However, these authors differentiate between anti-predatory lending laws and what they call "mini-HOEPA" laws. Mini-HOEPA laws are typically triggered below the national HOEPA triggers, but state differences remain in terms of enforcement and restrictions. Predatory lending laws are, to these authors, statutes or regulation of prepayment penalties, balloon clauses or other loan characteristics that are often considered predatory. Using their definition of both predatory lending laws and mini-HOEPA laws, Bostic et al. (2008) determine that by January 1, 2007, only six states (Arizona, Delaware, Montana, North Dakota, Oregon, and South Dakota) had no predatory lending laws or mini-HOEPA laws in place. Because Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006) use a sample of banks and because Bostic et al. (2008) use a broader definition of predatory lending laws, these two works do not identify the same states in the creation of their indexes.

To complicate matters, the "Profile of State Chartered Banking" (2008) at the Conference of State Bank Supervisors (CSBS), surveys state banking authorities on a wide range of budget, cost, and regulatory issues. The survey in the most recent profile (2008), asks the state authorities if there are predatory lending laws in their state during the 2006-2007 period. Alabama, Alaska, Arizona, Delaware, Hawaii, Indiana, Iowa, Louisiana, Michigan, Missouri, Montana, Nebraska, New Hampshire, North Dakota, Oregon, South Dakota, Texas, Utah, Virginia, Washington, and Wyoming all indicate that there are no predatory lending laws in place. Because of inconsistencies in these three data sources, the authors contacted directly the state bank authorities for clarification. These conversations relieved that Texas, Michigan, Indiana, and Utah do have predatory lending laws. Consequently, we identify seventeen states without predatory lending laws using the survey data.

Since this list of seventeen is generally consistent with Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006), we use this as our sample of states without predatory lending laws. Table 1 lists all states; those with shading are identified by the "Profile of State Chartered Banking" (2008) and confirmed by author interviews as not having predatory lending laws and those listings without shading do have predatory lending laws. The effective date of the law is identified in the second column. The final two columns indicate the index calculated by Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006) and by Bostic et al. (2008). In both cases, a higher number indicates more restrictive lending laws.

Since we are interested in learning how the preemption by the OCC of state predatory lending impacts national bank performance relative to state bank performance, our sample requires banks operating under state predatory lending laws and a control sample of banks not operating under state predatory lending laws. While one option is to simply compare bank performance at the state level between the different legal environments, it may be more instructive to consider bank performance at a more micro level. To that end, this paper uses metropolitan statistical area (MSA) level data to compare bank performance, by charter type, in MSAs with and without predatory lending laws. The process of selecting MSAs relies on first identifying the largest six MSAs in each legal environment: those states with and those without predatory lending laws. The U.S. Census Bureau identifies the MSAs by population rank and, as of July 1, 2008, table 2 identifies the largest six MSAs for those states with and without predatory lending laws.

Recall that Bostic et al. (2008) claim that only six states, at the beginning of 2007, do not have predatory lending laws. This is because Bostic et al. use a different definition of predatory lending than do some state authorities. To test the robustness of our sample and results, we also collect data on the largest MSA in each of the six states identified in Bostic et al. (2008) and we will apply the same estimation techniques to this sample as to the sample identified under the Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006) and "Profile of State Chartered Banking" (2008) procedure explained above. Table 2 also identifies the Bostic et al. (2008) sample.

Once the MSAs are identified, the institutional directory at the FDIC identifies all commercial banks headquartered in each MSA. Several of the MSAs in our sample include more than one state with conflicting predatory lending laws. In these cases, for example, the Fargo MSA includes parts of Minnesota, the banks headquartered in states with inconsistent predatory lending laws are removed from the sample (e.g. Minnesota banks who operate under predatory lending laws are removed from this MSA). Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) Aggregate Reports identify all banks and financial institutions headquartered in each MSA. Using this list, all banks are cross-listed with the FDIC's Institutional Directory to determine if the bank is a commercial bank and to determine its charter type. We end up with three samples that will be used to test the hypothesis that predatory lending laws impact bank performance. The sample extends from 1999 through 2008.

To capture bank performance, we use three variables identified by Nippani and Green (2002): 1) real return on equity (ROE); 2) real return on assets (ROA); and 3) real net interest margin (NIM). These are represented as PERFORMANCE in equation (1) below. Data definitions and sources are found in the Data Appendix. The DDD model estimated in our analysis is as follows:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (1)

[PLL.sub.i,j,t] is a dummy variable equal to one if bank i in MSA j, at time t, is subject to predatory lending laws, zero otherwise. [OCC.sub.t] is a dummy equal to one for years 2004 through 2009, and captures the decision by the Office of the Comptroller to preempt state predatory lending laws for all nationally chartered banks, effective January 7, 2004 (Whalen, 2008). [NAT.sub.i,j,t] is a dummy variable equal to one if bank i in MSA j at time t is a nationally chartered bank, zero otherwise.

The various interaction terms relate to the DDD model. Intuitively, a difference-indifference (DD) model compares two different groups over different time periods. Frequently one group is subject to an intervention or treatment in one period(s), but not the other period(s). Another group is not subject to the intervention in either period(s). Rather than simply comparing the treatment group before and after the intervention, the DD model nets out, or controls for, changes in the non-treatment group that also occurred over the different periods. In our case, the intervention is the decision by the Comptroller to exempt national banks for state predatory lending laws. However, what is the appropriate control group? One DD model could compare national bank performance with state bank performance in states with predatory lending laws. Alternatively, another DD model could compare national bank performance in states with predatory lending laws to national bank performance in states without predatory lending laws. The DDD model above is a more robust model that uses both state banks in predatory lending law states and national banks in non-predatory lending law states as controls. The coefficient, [[beta].sub.7], on the interaction term NAT*OCC*PLL, provides the additional return to national banks after the Office of Comptroller's decision in predatory lending law states (for other examples of the difference-in-difference-indifferences estimator see Wooldridge, 2007, Currie et al., 2009, and Acs and Nelson, 2004).

Other variables in equation (1) are included as various controls. [STATE.sub.j] is a dummy variable for the state that MSA j is located in. [YEAR.sub.t] is a set of year dummy variables. [ACTIVITY.sub.i,j,t] represents bank activity that can impact bank performance. Specific variables included in ACTIVITY are: the real total amount of 1-4 family home loans extended by the bank (ML) in hundreds of thousands of dollars. During healthy times, it is expected that ML contributes positively to bank performance. However, during times of falling home values, it is expected that ML hurts bank performance. The ratio of 1-4 family mortgage loans made to low-income applicants to total 1-4 family mortgage loans extended (LIM) is also included. If low-income loan recipients are at a higher risk of default, these loans may hurt bank performance. The bank's real security investments (SEC), in hundreds of thousands of dollars, are also included and since banks are limited to government securities, these investments are low risk and should enhance, or at least not hurt, bank performance. Finally, banks' most important source of fund is deposits. Consequently, this is an important cost on their balance sheets. To control for these costs, this paper relies on the real interest deposit expenses, IDE, at each bank in the sample, also measured in hundreds of thousands of dollars. It is expected to negatively impact bank performance since it represents a cost to the bank.

Finally, equation (1) also contains several controls for the local market that each bank operates within since the market structure certainly impacts bank performance: the number of financial institutions (NUM) either headquartered in the MSA or with branches in the MSA captures the competitive nature of the MSA. Real per capita personal income, PCPI, in thousands of dollars, describes the borrowing population facing the banks. Finally, the percentage change in home values (HV) within the MSA is included. Certainly, a declining house market will hurt bank performance since the potential for loan defaults increases. The regression specifications in equation (1) also control for general movements in interest rates by including the prime rate, PRIME.

RESULTS

Results from estimating equation (1) on our three samples are presented in Tables 3-5. Table 3 provides estimates using the Return on Assets (ROA) as the performance measure. The full sample, reported in the first column of results, consists of banks located in all the MSAs identified in Table 2. Thus the full sample includes states identified by both Ho Pennington-Cross (2006) and Bostic (2008) as not having predatory lending laws and, of course, banks located in MSAs in states with predatory lending laws. The second column of results is based on the sample where states without predatory lending laws are those identified by Ho Pennington-Cross (2006) and the Profile of State Chartered Banking. Finally, the third column is based on the sample where states without predatory lending laws are limited to those identified by Bostic (2008). Tables 4 and 5 present results for the return on equity and net interest margin.

Our main estimated coefficient of interest, [[beta].sub.7], is on the interaction term NAT*OCC*PLL. As shown in Table 3, national banks in states with predatory lending laws had a significant increase in their return on assets after the Office of the Comptroller's ruling exempting them from a state's predatory lending laws. This is true regardless of the sample that is examined, i.e., regardless of the definition used to identify states without predatory lending laws. The average return on assets for the whole sample is 0.678, with a standard deviation of 5.24, so the increase to national banks of 1.793 is economically meaningful as well.

It is important to place this increase in the return on assets in context and recognize that it is the marginal change in the return on assets for those banks in predatory lending states after the OCC decision. For example, Table 3 demonstrates that national banks had higher returns, ceteris paribus, than state banks irrespective of location or time, demonstrated by the coefficient, [[beta].sub.3], on NAT. Similarly, Table 3 also demonstrates that all banks performed more poorly after the Office of the Comptroller's ruling (2004), regardless of charter type, as seen by [[beta].sub.2], the coefficient on OCC. This is not surprising since this covers the 2004-2008 period and bank profits were compromised as a part of the wider financial crises during this period.

The other interactions also show marginal effects for various place-time-charter type groupings. For example, the coefficient, [[beta].sub.4], on NAT*PLL indicates that national banks in those states with predatory lending laws had a decrease in their profitability relative to their national bank counterparts that were not subject to predatory lending laws. Combined with the coefficient on NAT*OCC*PLL, this suggests that the predatory lending laws compromised profitability for national banks in general, but that this reduction was offset after the Office of the Comptroller's exemption. This is consistent with the findings in Elliehausen (1998), who finds regulation increases bank costs and hence reduces profit. This finding is also consistent with the Comptroller's concern that state predatory lending laws unnecessarily burden national banks. Similarly, the coefficient, [[beta].sub.5], on NAT*OCC indicates that national bank profit was declining after 2004 relative to earlier years, regardless of location.

The above is best demonstrated with a few examples. Consider the marginal impact on the return on assets for national banks in predatory lending law states after the Comptroller's decision. In this case, NAT=1, PLL=1, and OCC=1. Ceteris paribus, the marginal impact on the return on assets is 0.207, calculated by summing the corresponding coefficients (0.655-0.803 + 0.980-1.162-1.373 + 0.117 + 1.793). Comparing this for state banks in predatory lending law states during the same period (NAT=0, PLL=1, OCC=1) yields a marginal impact of -0.03 (0.655-0.803 + 0.117). Similarly, the marginal impact on the return on assets for national banks in non-predatory lending law states after the Comptroller's decision (NAT=1, PLL=0, OCC=1) is -1.19 (-0.803 + 0.980-1.373). Even if one excludes the coefficient on OCC*PLL (0.117) due to it being statistically insignificant the qualitative conclusions do not change: the national bank's exemption from state predatory lending laws reduced the negative impact of the financial crisis and improved their profitability compared to their state-chartered counterparts and national bank counterparts in non-predatory lending law states.

Other variables in the DDD regression are also statistically significant. The results in Table 3 reveal, for example, higher real security holdings increase a bank's ROA as does an increase in home values. Most of the other bank activity control variables are not statistically significant.

Tables 4 and 5 present similar conclusions when examining the bank's real return on equity (ROE) and net interest margin (NIM). While not as statistically strong, Table 4 shows a significant increase in a national bank's ROE in predatory lending law states after the Office of Comptroller's decision. The only exception is when Bostic's (2008) sample of non-predatory lending law states is used for comparison. The increase, of 7.975 and 9.409 for the full and Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006) samples respectively, is notable given the average ROE of 8.00 with a standard deviation of 57.02. When examining NIM, a similar conclusion is reached, only this time it is the Bostic et al. (2008) sample that is statistically significant. The average NIM is 3.76 with a standard deviation of 1.957.

Recall that both Ho and Pennington Cross (2006) and Bostic et al. (2008) construct predatory lending law indices that differentiate states by the severity of their predatory lending laws. Including these indices in the above regressions yielded a negative and statistically significant impact on ROA, further suggesting that predatory lending laws harm bank performance. However, the indices were not statistically significant in the regressions on ROE and NIM.

In summary, the above results suggest the national banks in states with predatory lending laws benefited from the decision to exempt them from those laws, both relative to national banks in states without predatory lending laws and compared to state banks in states with predatory lending laws.

CONCLUSION

The only existing research that investigates the impact of predatory lending laws on bank performance is Whalen (2008) who finds that the Office of the Comptroller's preemption decision did not significantly increase stock prices of national banks. This study, which uses a much broader sample of banks and different measures of bank worth, finds national bank performance improved after the Comptroller's ruling when controlling for charter type and legal environment. While not directly comparable to Whalen due to the different measures of bank worth, these results do support his argument that regulation may reduce revenue as well as the hypothesis in Ho and Pennington-Cross (2007) that there may be a regulatory cost burden associated with predatory lending laws. While we are unable to distinguish whether it is reduced revenue or increased costs that harm performance, it is clear that nationally chartered banks in predatory lending law states outperform their state bank counterparts and their national bank counterparts in non predatory lending states after the Comptroller's ruling.

Going back to the early 1990s, the federal government has been pursuing a set of policies to increase access to homeownership. An unintended consequence of these policies has been the increased incidence of predatory lending practices. The results of this paper suggest that policymakers should be careful when trying to address predatory lending issues. Costly regulation is likely to hurt bank performance and poor performing banks will not be able to extend credit, mortgage or otherwise, to that portion of the population targeted through federal policy. If regulation is too burdensome and too costly, it is possible that banks will respond by either increasing costs to borrowers or restricting credit to higher risk borrowers. Neither response by banks will help achieve the wider homeownership goals that have characterized federal policy for the past twenty years.
Data Appendix: Data Definitions and Sources

Variable                   Description               Source

Dependent Variables

Real Return on         Ratio of undivided     FDIC.gov
Equity (ROE)           profits to total
                       assets at commercial
                       banks in the sample.

Real Return on         Ratio of undivided     FDIC.gov
Assets (ROA)           profits to equity
                       capital at
                       commercial banks in
                       the sample.

Real Net Interest      Ratio of difference    FDIC.gov
Margin (NIM)           in interest income
                       and interest expense
                       to earning assets at
                       commercial banks in
                       the sample.

Control for Local
Market Conditions

Number of Financial    otal number of         FDIC.gov
Institutions (NUM)     commercial banks
                       headquartered in the
                       MSA.

Per Capita Personal    Per capita personal    BEA/gov/regional/
Income (PCPI)          income in the MSA.     reis/

House Values (HV)      Index of house         FHFA.gov
                       prices in the MSA.

Control for Legal
Environment

Binary Control (PLL)   simple control for     o and Cross-
                       states with and        Pennington (2006),
                       without predatory      Bostic et al.
                       lending laws = 0 if    (2008), and the
                       no laws and = 1 if     rofile of State
                       the states does have   Chartered Banking
                       laws according to      (2008).
                       the date the law was
                       implemented.

OCC Decision (OCC)     A control for the      N.A.
                       OCCs decision to
                       preempt state
                       predatory lending
                       laws= 0 for 1999-
                       2003 and = 1 for
                       2004-2009.

Bank and Borrower
Characteristics

Home Mortgages to      Ratio of mortgage      HMDA Disclosure
Low-Income (LIM)       loans to low-income    Reports
                       applicants to total
                       mortgages loans by
                       the commercial banks
                       in the sample.

Home Mortgage Loans    Dollar value of 1-4    FDIC.gov
(ML)                   family home loans
                       extended by the
                       commercial banks in
                       the sample.

Securities             Dollar value of        FDIC.gov
Investments (SEC)      securities
                       investments by the
                       commercial banks in
                       the sample.

Interest Deposit       Dollar value of        FDIC.gov
Expense (IDE)          interest expense on
                       deposits by the
                       commercial banks in
                       the sample.

Other

CPI                    Consumer price index   BLS.gov
                       used to convert
                       nominal to real
                       values.

Prime Rate (PRIME)     A general control      stlouisfed.org
                       for interest rate      .fred2.data.PRI
                       movements.             ME.txt


REFERENCES

Acs, Gregory and Nelson, Sandi (2004). Changes in Living Arrangements During the Late 1990s: Do Welfare Policies Matter. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 23(2), 273-290.

Board of Governors (2001). Truth in Lending. 66 Fed. Reg. 65,604.

Bostic, Raphael W., Kathleen C. Engel, Patricia A. McCoy, Anthony Pennington-Cross, and Susan M. Wachter (2008).

State and Local Anti-Predatory Lending Laws: The Effect of Legal Enforcement Mechanisms. Journal of Economics and Business, 60, 47-66.

Conference of State Bank Supervisors (2008). Profile of State Chartered Banking.

Chomsisengphat, S., and Anthony Pennington-Cross (2006). The Evolution of the Subprime Mortgage Market. Federal Reserve of St. Louis Economic Review, 88, 31-56.

Currie, Janet; Hanushek, Eric; Khan, Megan; Neidell, Matthew; and Rivkin, Steven (2009). Does Pollution Increase School Absences. The Review of Economics and Statistics, November 2009, 91(4), 682-694.

Demtanyk, Yuliya, and Otto Van Hemert (2008). Understanding the Subprime Mortgage Crisis. Retrieved October 14, 2009 from http://ssrn.com/abstract=1020396

Elliehausen, Gregory (1998). The Cost of Banking Regulation: A Review of the Evidence. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Staff Study, 171.

Elliehausen, Gregory and Michael E. Staten (2004). Regulation of Subprime Mortgage Products: An Analysis of North Carolina's Predatory Lending Laws. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 30, 167-196.

Engle, Kathleen, and Patricia McCoy (2001). The Law and Economics of Remedies of Predatory Lending. Proceedings of a Federal Reserve System Community Affairs Research Conference: Changing Financial Markets and Community Development, April 5-6.

General Accountability Office (2004). Consumer Protection: Federal and State Agencies Face Challenges in Combating Predatory Lending, GAO-04-280.

Goldstein, Ira (2006). Predatory Lending and Mortgage Foreclosures in Philadelphia. Retrieved September 24, 2009 from http:www.trfund.com/resource/downloads/staffwritings/ABA_NLADA_2006.pdf

Harvey, Keith D. and Peter J. Nigro (2003). How Do Predatory Lending Laws Influence Mortgage Lending in Urban Areas? A Tale of Two Cities. Journal of Real Estate Research, 25, 479-508.

Harvey, Keith D. and Peter J. Nigro (2003). Do Predatory Lending Laws Influence Mortgage Lending? An Analysis of the North Carolina Predatory Lending Law. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 29(4), 435-456.

Hawke, John D. (2004). Statement of Comptroller of the Currency John D. Hawke, Jr. Regarding the Issuance of Regulations Concerning Preemption and Visitorial Powers. Retrieved September 21, 2009 from http://www.occ.treas.gov/2004-3aComptrollersstatement.pdf

Ho, Giang and Anthony Pennington-Cross (2006). The Impact of Local Predatory Lending Laws on the Flow of Subprime Credit. Journal of Urban Economics, 60(2), 210-228.

Ho, Giang, and Anthony Pennington-Cross (2007). The Varying Effects of Predatory Lending Laws on High-Cost Mortgage Applications. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, January/February, 39-59.

Immergluck, Daniel (1991). Two Steps Back: The Dual Mortgage Market, Predatory Lending, and the Undoing of Community Development. Chicago: The Woodstock Institute.

Kaper, Stacy (2007). Bernanke: Predator Bill Would Be a Good Idea. American Banker, 172(3), 1. Retrieved September 24, 2009 from http:www.americanbanker.com.

Li, Wei, and Keith S. Ernst (2007). Do State Predatory Lending Laws Work? A Panel Analysis of Market Reforms. Housing Policy Debate, 18(2), 347-391.

Marsico, Richard D. (2001). Patterns of Lending to Low-Income and Minority Persons and Neighborhoods: The 1999 New York Metropolitan Area Lending Scorecard. New York Law School, Public Law Research Paper 02/02.

Morgan, Donald P. (2007). Defining and Detecting Predatory Lending. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report No. 273. Retrieved September 28, 2009 from http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr273.pdf

Office of the Comptroller (2004). OCC Issues Final Rules on National Bank Preemption and Visitorial Powers; Includes Strong Standard to Keep Predatory Lending out of National Banks. News Release. Retrieved September 22, 2009 from www.occ.treas.gov/toolkit/newsrelease.aspx?doc=zn9i8h7t.xml

Pennington-Cross, Anthony, and Giang Ho (2008). Predatory Lending Laws and the Cost of Credit. Real Estate Economics, 36, 175-211.

Quercia, Roberto G., Michael A. Stegman, and Walter R. Davis (2007). The Impact of Predatory Lending Loan Terms on Subprime Foreclosures: The Special Case of Prepayment Penalties and Balloon Payments. Housing Policy Debate, 18(2), 311-346.

Renuart, Elizabeth (2004). An Overview of the Predatory Mortgage Lending Process. Housing Policy Debate, 15(3), 467-502.

Rose, Morgan J. (2008). Predatory Lending Practices and Subprime Foreclosures: Distinguishing Impacts by Loan Category. Journal of Economics and Business, 60, 13-32.

Stock, Richard (2001). Predation in the Sub-Prime Lending Market: Montgomery County. Center for Business and Economic Research. Retrieved September 24, 2009 from www.mvfairhousing.org/cber/pdf/Executive%20summary.PDF

Whalen, Gary W. (2008). The Impact of Preemption of the Georgia Fair Lending Act by the OCC on National and State Banks and the Dual Banking System. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 48, 772-791.

Woodridge, Jeff (2007). What's New in Econometrics, Lecture 10, Difference in Difference Estimation. Retrieved January 10, 2010 from http://www.nber.org/WNE/Slides7-31-07/slides_10_diffindiffs.pdf

Jill M. Hendrickson, University of St. Thomas

Mark W. Nichols, University of Nevada
Table 1. Predatory Lending Laws and Legal Indices

                                    Full State Index    Full State
States            Effective Year       from Ho and      Index from
                   of Predatory        Pennington-       Bostic et
                    Lending Law       Cross (2006)      al. (2008)
Alaska
Alabama
Arizona
Arkansas             7/16/2003              8              6.56
California           7/01/2002             11              4.93
Colorado             6/07/2002             13              4.18
Connecticut         10/02/2001             10              4.88
Delaware
Florida              10/2/2002              4              3.75
Georgia              10/2/2002             16              6.83
Hawaii
Idaho                7/01/2003
Illinois             1/01/2004             13              8.11
Indiana              2/04/2005             11              6.76
Iowa
Kansas               4/04/1999
Kentucky             6/24/2003              9              5.86
Louisiana
Maine                9/13/2003              4              3.01
Maryland             5/16/2002              8              3.39
Massachusetts        3/22/2001             14              8.44
Michigan             12/23/02                              5.99
Minnesota            8/01/2007                             7.01
Mississippi          7/01/2002
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada              10/01/2003              4              2.81
New Hampshire
New Jersey          11/27/2003            10.5             7.34
New Mexico           1/01/2004             17              9.90
New York             4/01/2003             10              5.82
North Carolina      10/01/1999             11              6.40
North Dakota
Ohio                 2/22/2002              6              3.47
Oklahoma             1/01/2004              9              4.29
Oregon
Pennsylvania         6/21/2001              7              3.47
Rhode Island        12/31/2006
South Carolina       1/01/2004              9              4.80
South Dakota
Tennessee            1/01/2007
Texas                9/01/2001              8              4.34
Utah                 9/01/2004              6              3.91
Vermont              9/16/1998
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia        6/4/2002                              9.00
Wisconsin            2/01/2005              5
Wyoming

Source: State Profile of State Chartered Banking (2008) and author
interviews with state bank authorities to determine if there is
regulation in place (all non-shaded states) and for the effective date;
Ho and Pennington-Cross (2006) for their full index which captures the
law at the end of 2004, and Bostic et al. (2008) for their full,
additive index for 2004-2005.

Table 2. Largest MSAs in States with and without Predatory Lending Laws

6 Largest MSAs in      6 Largest MSAs in      Largest MSAs in
states with            States without         Bostic Definition of
Predatory Lending      Predatory Lending      non Predatory
Laws                   Laws                   Lending Law States

New York-Northern      Phoenix-Mesa-          Phoenix-Mesa-
New Jersey-Long        Scottsdale             Scottsdale
Island

Los Angeles-Long       Seattle-Tacoma-        Sioux Falls
Beach-Santa Ana        Bellevue

Chicago-Naperville-    St. Louis              Dover
Joliet

Dallas-Fort            Portland-Vancouver-    Portland-Vancouver-
Worth-Arlington        Beaverton              Beaverton

Philadelphia-          Kansas City            Fargo
Camden-Wilmington

Houston-Sugarland-     Richmond               Billings
Baytown

Table 3. DDD Model for the Impact of Predatory Lending Laws on
National Bank Performance: Real Return on Assets

                                     Profile of
                                  State Chartered
                                   Banking (2008)
                 Full Sample         and Ho and        Bostic et al.
                                    Pennington-        (2008) Sample
                                Cross (2006) Sample

PLL               0.655 ***          0.637 ***           0.758 ***
                    (2.76)             (2.70)              (2.66)

OCC               -0.803 **          -1.275 ***          -2.175 ***
                    (2.47)             (5.01)              (2.95)

NAT               0.980 ***          0.866 ***           1.045 ***
                    (3.19)             (2.79)              (3.24)

NAT*PLL           -1.162 ***         -1.046 ***          -1.235 ***
                    (3.41)             (3.05)              (3.47)

NAT*OCC           -1.373 **          -1.795 ***           -1.118 *
                    (2.49)             (2.90)              (1.78)

OCC*PLL             0.117              0.153              1.645 **
                    (0.54)             (0.64)              (2.55)

NAT*OCC*PLL       1.793 ***          2.218 ***            1.538 **
                    (3.09)             (3.43)              (2.35)

ML                 -0.0006             0.0017             0.00001
                    (0.87)             (1.23)              (0.02)

LIM                 -1.109             4.357              -17.500
                    (0.12)             (0.43)              (1.28)

SEC                0.0011 *            0.0085            0.0014 **
                    (1.65)             (1.32)              (1.99)

IDE                -0.0003            -0.0031             -0.0053
                    (0.08)             (0.71)              (1.16)

NUM                 0.002              0.002               0.0031
                    (0.74)             (0.77)              (1.07)

HV                0.024 ***          0.025 ***           0.0326 ***
                    (3.22)             (3.47)              (4.21)

PCPI                0.036              0.001               0.0074
                    (0.77)             (0.03)              (1.30)

PRIME               0.068              0.101               0.0461
                    (0.92)             (1.33)              (0.46)

State Dummies        Yes                Yes                 Yes
Year Dummies         Yes                Yes                 Yes
N                    8277               7922                6666
[R.sup.2]           0.030              0.027               0.035

Absolute value of the t statistic in parentheses. A *, **, and ***
represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent level,
respectively.

Table 4. DDD Model for the Impact of Predatory Lending Laws on
National Bank Performance: Real Return on Equity

                Full Sample       Profile of        Bostic et
                                State Chartered    al. (2008)
                                Banking (2008)       Sample
                                  and Ho and
                               Pennington-Cross
                                 (2006) Sample

PLL                -1.233           -1.251           -0.806
                   (0.42)           (0.46)           (0.28)

OCC              -4.657 **        -11.182 ***        -6.714
                   (2.34)           (8.78)           (1.60)

NAT                6.592             6.459            7.572
                   (1.60)           (1.55)           (1.62)

NAT*PLL           -7.752 *          -7.611          -8.730 *
                   (1.64)           (1.58)           (1.66)

NAT*OCC           -6.795 *         -8.227 **         -6.407
                   (1.68)           (2.15)           (1.36)

OCC*PLL            -1.368           -1.144            0.054
                   (0.76)           (0.61)           (0.01)

NAT*OCC*PLL       7.975 *          9.409 **           7.575
                   (1.92)           (2.41)           (1.58)

ML                 -0.001            0.007           -0.0004
                   (0.20)           (0.77)           (0.07)

LIM                23.095           19.846           43.076
                   (0.34)           (0.50)           (0.42)

SEC               0.014 **         0.015 **         0.015 **
                   (2.10)           (2.23)           (2.20)

IDE                0.0054           -0.021           -0.173
                   (0.11)           (0.43)           (0.36)

NUM                -0.078           -0.077           -0.084
                   (0.76)           (0.75)           (0.76)

HV                 0.105            0.127 *           0.093
                   (1.40)           (1.72)           (0.98)

PCPI               0.159             0.141            0.171
                   (1.32)           (1.13)           (1.40)

PRIME              0.644             0.371            0.724
                  (1.444)           (1.25)           (1.29)

State Dummies       Yes               Yes              Yes
Year Dummies        Yes               Yes              Yes
N                   8277             7922             6666
[R.sup.2]           .010             .010             .010

Absolute value of the t statistic in parentheses. A , **, and
** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1
percent level, respectively.

Table 5. DDD Model for the Impact of Predatory Lending Laws on National
Bank Performance: Real Net Interest Margin

                Full Sample       Profile of        Bostic et
                                State Chartered     al. (2008)
                                Banking (2008)        Sample
                                  and Ho and
                               Pennington-Cross
                                 (2006) Sample

PLL                -0.119          -0.189 **          -0.084
                   (1.12)           (2.21)            (0.69)

OCC              -1.328 ***       -1.000 ***        -1.667 ***
                   (6.52)           (10.68)           (6.60)

NAT                0.167             0.097            0.173
                   (1.55)           (1.57)            (1.49)

NAT*PLL            -0.154           -0.089            -0.161
                   (1.05)           (0.75)            (1.06)

NAT*OCC          -0.380 **          -0.177           -0.415 *
                   (1.99)           (1.37)            (1.63)

OCC*PLL           0.218 **          0.0929          0.699 ***
                   (1.96)           (0.96)            (2.68)

NAT*OCC*PLL       0.415 *            0.212           0.454 *
                   (1.87)           (1.25)            (1.63)

ML              -0.0027 ***       -0.0063 ***      -0.0023 ***
                   (4.04)           (3.39)            (3.70)

LIM                -0.885          -9.055 **          0.784
                   (0.15)           (2.44)            (0.11)

SEC               -0.0010           -0.0006          -0.0007
                   (1.07)           (0.64)            (0.71)

IDE                0.0028           0.0081           -0.0014
                   (0.50)           (1.17)            (0.27)

NUM              -0.0019 **       -0.0019 **       -0.0027 ***
                   (1.96)           (1.97)            (2.69)

HV                 -0.003           -0.002            0.0002
                   (0.76)           (0.71)            (0.07)

PCPI             -0.008 ***       -0.006 ***        -0.010 ***
                   (3.30)           (3.61)            (3.35)

PRIME            0.266 ***         0.218 ***        0.292 ***
                   (6.07)           (11.00)           (5.08)

State Dummies       Yes               Yes              Yes
Year Dummies        Yes               Yes              Yes
N                   8274             7919              6663
[R.sup.2]           .194             .267             0.192

Absolute value of the t statistic in parentheses. A , **, and
** represent statistical significance at the 10, 5, and 1
percent level, respectively.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有