The behavior of credit card interest rates during the decline in other interest-rate markets.
Evans, Stephen T.
INTRODUCTION
Although some consider 1949 to be the approximate beginning of the
modern credit-card era (Brooker, 2004), the genesis of this powerful
social phenomenon certainly goes back at least to the early 1900s. In
1914, for example, Western Union was using metal cards to allow its best
customers to defer payments, and the cards became known as "Metal
Money" (ETI, 2003). Prior to World War II it was fairly common for
"department stores, communication companies, travel and delivery
companies, and oil companies" (ETI, 2003) to issue credit cards to
encourage and facilitate the purchases of their own products. But
generally the cards were for "local purchases" at a single
location and rarely used for the products of other companies.
During World War II the use of credit cards was prohibited, but the
practice re-emerged following the war as customers discovered the
"beauties of enjoying now and paying later." In approximately
1949 the Diner's Club card was instituted and allowed "travel
and entertainment people" to use one card to charge purchases from
many retailers. The success of this "one card for many
businesses" encouraged others, and in 1951 the Franklin National
Bank in New York issued the "Charge It" card (ETI, 2003). This
was really the period of time when the idea was established of financial
intermediaries handling credit card processes for other organizations.
MODERN ERA OF CREDIT CARDS
In the 1960s, credit-card organizations began to emerge that issued
licensing agreements to other financial intermediaries. The Bank of
America, for example, created the BankAmericard and licensed its use to
other banks throughout the country. Later to be known as Visa
International, the BankAmericard approach was a new dimension in the
development of the credit-card industry and became the precursor of
companies like Master Card and Discover. The 1970s saw a significant
movement toward the internationalization of credit cards, and the 1980s
were characterized by the development of ATM machines and other
electronic devices designed to facilitate monetary transfers.
The use and effectiveness of credit cards was enhanced in the 1990s
by the personal computer revolution--especially the emergence of the
Internet. And now well into the 21st Century, the Internet and the
emerging cashless society are maturing as major companions of the
credit-card industry. Whether used for big-ticket items like computers
or smaller items like books and videos, over 90 percent of Internet
sales are facilitated by credit-cards (ETI, 2003). At the present time
the five leaders in the credit-card industry are Visa International,
MasterCard, American Express, Discover, and Diner's Club (ETI,
2003), but many overseas credit-card providers are making inroads in
this profitable industry including Euro Card.
EVOLUTION OF THINKING
While the credit-card has evolved institutionally and
organizationally, it has also evolved philosophically and strategically.
Considered initially as a provider of convenience, it soon evolved as a
facilitator of sales revenues with the sales themselves being the means
to enhance profits. During this period it was usually expected that the
card balances be paid off each month, and to encourage that practice an
interest charge was instituted almost as a negative penalty to enforce
compliance. But it didn't take long for the companies to discover
and appreciate the profitability of the interest charges themselves, and
the industry generally shifted from unpaid balances as a negative to a
thinking that was at least neutral on balances being carried forward.
From this era of neutrality toward unpaid balances evolved a more
aggressive strategy that even encouraged the carry-over of balances, and
payments became a main source of income for the credit-card providers.
As a further income source, the methods used to calculate the interest
charges were "enhanced" and resulted in actual interest
charges being greater than advertised or theoretical interest rates. One
article, for example, quoted the Vice-Chairman of a bank who indicated
that the credit-card business was among the most profitable business
segments of the bank and made a return on equity of 34 percent (Zweig,
1997).
As the industry has moved into the 21st century, high interest
rates on credit-card balances have continued to provide major profits
for financial intermediaries, but probably the greatest evolution that
has taken place more recently relates to the charging of fees. For many
credit-card providers, the fees have become a strategic focus for
generating earnings, and the dollar amount, types, and number of fees,
have been extraordinary in growth. And all of the above has evolved into
what some describe cynically as an industry where powerful profit
machines are created to hook as many customers as possible and extract
as much money from them as possible.
IMPACT ON THE ECONOMY AND CULTURE
Whether one thinks of the credit-card industry in such cynical
terms or with a more positive orientation that it has been good for the
consumer-portion of the economy, there is no question that the
credit-card phenomenon has consistently grown faster than the economy as
a whole and has had a powerful impact on it. In the mid-1980s
approximately 75 million Americans had credit cards (Ausubel, 1991) or
about 30 percent of the population. By 2002, "well over one billion
cards (were) in circulation (with) the average household (having) about
a dozen credit cards" (CFA, 2003).
"Since 1997 credit card issuers have nearly doubled the amount
of credit they offer to consumers, to more than $3 trillion-about
$30,000 per household. Revolving debt, which is almost entirely card
debt, increased from $554 billion to $730 billion between 1997 and
2002" (CFA, 2003). And in 2003, the credit-card industry reached
two significant milestones. For the first time in history, Americans
bought more with cards than with cash (Brooker, 2004). Also for the
first time, the industry came close to generating $2 trillion in
transactions in one year (Brooker, 2004). Considering that GDP for the
entire nation is a little more than $10 trillion, credit cards are now a
key part in nearly 20 percent of the economy.
CONCERNS ABOUT THE CREDIT-CARD REVOLUTION
The fact that 20 percent of the economy is now facilitated by
credit cards is obviously a positive in many respects. But there is also
great concern because credit use has grown fastest among debtors with
the lowest incomes. "In the early and mid-1990s, Americans with
incomes below the poverty level nearly doubled their credit card usage,
and those in the $10,000-$25,000 income bracket came in a close second
..." (CFA, 2003). "By 2000, about one-third of lower income
families spent more than 40% of their income on debt repayment, compared
to 20% of moderate income households and 14% of middle income families.
(Likewise), riskier borrowers typically carry a higher debt burden, pay
more interest, and suffer more defaults" (CFA, 2003). "About
sixty percent of cardholders carry credit card debt from month to month.
And the average credit-card debt for households that carry a balance is
more than $10,000" (CFA, 2003).
"Consumer debt has more than doubled in the past ten years to
a record level of $1.98 trillion ... (and) represents primarily credit
card-debt and car loans and does not include home mortgages ... By
itself, credit-card debt--nearly all accruing interest at double digit rates-stands at $735 billion despite the fact that many families have
refinanced their homes in recent years in an attempt to deal with
mounting credit card debts and fees (Nader, 2004). "Skyrocketing
credit card balances is a significant factor in the increasing number of
bankruptcies. Consumer bankruptcies have exceeded one million a year
since 1996, reaching 1.54 million in 2002 and topping 1.25 million in
the first nine months of 2003" (Nader, 2004).
Much of the credit-card burden has "been fueled by deceptive credit card operations, predatory lending and other 'easy
credit' schemes (and is) causing a dark cloud across the national
economy . The numbers paint a sad picture of low, moderate and middle
income citizens caught in impossible burdens of debt plus mounting fees
and late charges" (Nader, 2004). The characteristically high
credit-card interest rates is a cause for concern, but an additional
dimension of the problem is the fact that the credit-card rates do not
noticeably respond when interest rates decline in other financial
markets. In fact, this "stickiness" of interest rates has been
the focus of much research in the fields of economics and finance.
LITERATURE SEARCH
With reference to credit-card interest rates, under classic
economic theory, if and when credit-card profits become excessive, other
credit-card providers will be attracted to this specialized segment of
the financial markets, and the influx of new participants and resulting
competitive forces will tend to pull down the rates and
"normalize" the financial rewards. However, for a variety of
reasons that continue to be explored, these basic economic forces do not
seem to apply as well to the credit-card industry.
In a well-cited journal article in the American Economic Review,
some solid research was presented to partially explain the unusual
interest-rate behavior. Interestingly, the regulatory climate imposed by
the government had been largely removed more than a decade earlier, and
no solid evidence could be found of any significant barriers to entry,
constrained inputs, significant sunk costs, or collusion that might be
at work to thwart the workings of the free market (Ausubel, 1991).
With the industry appearing to have a paradigm of near-perfect
competition, it was a paradox that the interest rates demonstrated such
unresponsiveness to interest-rate changes in other financial markets
(Ausubel, 1991). A possible explanation was found in some evidence that
many consumers apparently make credit-card choices without taking into
account the very high probability that they will eventually need to pay
interest on their outstanding balances. In any case, there was no
question in the research about the fact that credit-card interest rates
do demonstrate a "stickiness" or inelasticity in their
behavior relative to other financial markets (Ausubel, 1991).
In a later journal article in the American Economic Review, similar
evidence was given on the "stickiness" of credit-card interest
rates. It also provided conclusive evidence of abnormally high profits
for many issuers and suggested that the cardholders do not conform to the behavioral assumptions of perfect competition because (1)
cardholders face search costs, (2) cardholders face switch costs, and/or
(3) firms would face an adverse-selection problem if they were to reduce
their interest rates unilaterally. The paper further concluded, and
significantly, that credit-card providers do not cut rates because
consumers are not responsive to rate cuts (Calem and Mester, 1995).
In a journal article in the Journal of Political Economy, further
research was presented to explain why cardholders live with higher
credit-card interest rates. They found that credit cards are useful as a
low-cost method of financing transactions and arranging short-term
loans. Despite large interest rates, rational consumers frequently pay
interest on outstanding credit-card balances rather than pay the
transaction costs associated with arranging loans from banks or other
financial institutions. A rational consumer may also pay interest on
credit-card debts to avoid some of the costs associated with holding
precautionary money balances (Brito and Hartley, 1995).
In an article in The Review of Economics and Statistics, there were
similar findings to suggest that there are two distinct types of
credit-card providers. Some use variable rates that move in lock-step
fashion with other interest markets while other providers adopt a policy
of fixed-rate charges for as long as three to five years. Consistent
with this finding, the article presents a convincing argument that
explains that markets of high rate-cost margins and aggressive non-price
competition for new customers can exist concurrently (Stango, 2000).
Two recent studies also provide helpful data on the relationship
between credit-card interest rates and other general market rates. In a
journal article in the International Journal of Management, evidence is
presented showing that the federal funds rate affects the credit card
rate with a relatively small elasticity of 0.173 but the prime rate and
cost of funds do not affect credit card rates (Yu Hsing, 2003).
As a final research note, the Consumer Federation of America presented some research that recognized the increasing interest-rate gap
between the benchmark rate set by the Federal Reserve and interest rates
charged by credit-card providers. The analysis identified a 4.75-percent
drop in Federal Reserve interest rates in 2001 but only a 1.35-percent
decline in the rates charged by credit-card providers (CFA, 2003). It is
this research data that this study focused on, because a preliminary
review of new data could identify no such drop in credit-card interest
rates. An analysis seemed to be in order to find the discrepancy in
conclusions.
PRELIMINARY OBSERVATIONS
While acknowledging the validity of the economic relationships and
theories that apply to the credit-card industry and the power of the
competitive forces at work in these financial markets, there
nevertheless is much evidence that exceptions exist in some
"pockets" of the industry. If one judges from the number of
credit-card solicitations that the average American home receives each
year and the nature of these advertisements, then two seemingly
contradictory conclusions might be (1) that there is intense competition
within the industry and (2) that profitability remains abnormally high.
The literature that has been described has done much to explain why
some of these exceptions seem to exist, especially in relationship to
the "stickiness" of interest rates. But the research has not
yet adequately explained (1) the trend of the "introductory
interest rates" that are granted to new cardholders for a limited
period of time and (2) the fact that there is a difference in
characteristics between various credit-card providers. It has been
observed, for example, that local depository institutions with
well-established customer relations provide different credit-card terms
than large, aggressive credit-card mail advertisers that have less to
worry about in customer relationships when they solicit new cardholders
from a distance.
As to these aggressive national solicitors, the literature has not
yet fully addressed the level or direction of the "ongoing interest
rates" that have been charged to cardholders after the introductory
rates have expired. It has been especially interesting during the last
three years when other rates have declined to 45-year lows. Although the
report by CFA indicated a 1.35 percent decline in credit-card rates
during 2001 (CFA, 2003), the difference between that finding and this
study showing no such decline might be explained by the possibility that
this study focused exclusively on the mailed solicitations.
In a general review of over 1,000 unsolicited credit-card offers
over the past seven years, the impression has been left that companies
(1) that aggressively market their credit cards through the mail (2) at
long distances from their locations (3) to potential customers who have
no established community relationships with the lenders (4) tend to be
more competitive in the short-term enticements, (5) are less responsive
to longer-term interest rates after the introductory offers expire, and
(6) largely attract many customers who can least afford to service the
debts after the arrangements are established.
HYPOTHESES TO BE TESTED
Having recognized some differences between traditional financial
intermediaries and aggressive credit-card solicitors, it is the purpose
of this paper to focus primarily on #4 and #5 of the previous paragraph.
In other words, the analysis is to look for evidence among
"aggressive marketers" that introductory offers are becoming
more competitive to "hook" the customers and, secondly, that
financial commitments after the introductory period are not as
responsive to market forces, especially those that relate to the ongoing
interest rates.
Specifically, this study tests for the following possibilities: The
first hypothesis is that "introductory interest rates" that
are advertised in mailed credit-card solicitations have been declining.
The second hypothesis is that these "introductory interest
rates" have actually declined at a faster rate in recent years than
other well-publicized rates that have declined to 45-year lows during
the same time period. The third hypothesis is that the so-called
"ongoing interest rates" charged by these credit-card
solicitors after the introductory period have shown little if any
response to declining interest rates in other financial markets. The
fourth and last hypothesis is that these post-introductory-period rates
or "ongoing interest rates" have actually been increasing
while other rates in the financial markets have been declining.
METHODOLOGY
Although the main thrust of this study has been the period of
declining interest rates from January 2001 through December 2003, there
is value in first establishing (1) the more "normal" patterns
of "general interest rates" over a longer period of time and
(2) the more "normal" patterns of "credit-card interest
rates" charged by the more traditional credit-card providers.
Consequently, the well-known federal funds rate and prime rate used in
the banking industry have been identified over an eleven-year period
from January 1993 through December 2003. Also obtained were the interest
rates charged by a representative regional bank over the same 11-year
time period to show a "typical credit-card interest-rate pattern
for a less-aggressive credit-card provider.
For the credit-card interest analysis specifically, over 1,000
credit-card solicitations have been saved over approximately seven years
(from about 1997 through early 2004). The available data was less
substantial for the years 1999 and 2000, but sufficient flyers were
available during the periods under study so the evaluation could be
accomplished. For the most recent year (2003), over 200 new advertising
flyers were acquired and preserved for the study.
For the analysis, two basic approaches were initially contemplated.
The first was to do a head-to-head comparison of advertising flyers
received over time from single companies to determine whether these
companies raised or lowered their interest rates, especially during the
three-year period of greatest interest. While helpful in many regards,
this procedure did not prove to be statistically significant because of
the sparse number of data points that were statistically valid. The
reason related to how many participants even qualified as national
marketers.
This situation was referred to as early as 1991 when only 20 of the
4,000 credit-card providers were considered to be aggressive marketers
(Ausubel, 1991). There are still, perhaps, no more than 30 firms that
aggressively solicit customers on a national scale, and these were the
target of the current study. While mail solicitations were obtained from
most of these companies, much of the data had to be eliminated for
various technical reasons, and the remaining data only related to eight
of the companies. Four of these raised interest rates and the other four
lowered rates over the test period, so the data proved inconclusive.
That left the study with what was considered anyway to be the more
significant statistical sampling procedure. The main analysis was the
random selection of 120 flyers from 30 credit-card providers over the
three-year period of interest from January 2001 through December 2003.
An additional 24 flyers were evaluated for calendar year 1998 to extend
the time horizon somewhat. This will be described in the analysis
section. The aggregate information from the 144 flyers (an average of
three flyers per month) was used to establish average, monthly
interest-rate data on both (1) the "introductory interest
rates" offered by these companies and (2) the "ongoing
interest rates" that were applied after the introductory rates
expired.
While the evaluation was considered statistically significant in
determining the general direction of interest rates over time, the
analysis proved to be more difficult than first envisioned because even
a single company can be involved in a variety of offers to different
demographic targets. There were situations, for example, where two
mailings were received at about the same time by the same person but
with different rate offers. One explanation seemed to be the fact that
address information is regularly purchased from various organizations
and the interest-rate offers are tailored to what are considered to be
the demographic characteristics of that organization. Because of these
data challenges, some degree of judgment needed to be applied in data
extraction, but the resulting data was randomly derived and considered
statistically significant.
RESEARCHING THE INTEREST-RATE ENVIRONMENT
In starting the analysis it seemed crucial to begin by establishing
the general pattern of interest rates in the financial markets over
time, and that did prove helpful both for its orientation value and for
identifying the most fertile period of time for analysis. The most
representative data seemed to be the discount rate (that the Federal
Reserve charges banks), the federal funds rate (that banks charge each
other), and the prime rate (that banks charge their best customers). The
discount rate, however, recently went through a change in assumptions
and formula, so only the federal funds rate and prime rate were used for
the analysis. In the following visual (Exhibit 1), these two rates can
be seen over the 11-year period from January 1993 through December 2003:
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
For this study, the two most significant observations from Exhibit
1 are (1) the strong relationship and lockstep pattern of the two rates
and (2) the dramatic drop in interest rates that began in about January
2001 (data point #97). This interest-rate drop has continued for most of
the last three years and consequently, this period became the target
period for determining if interest rates contained in unsolicited
credit-card offers have been affected much by changes in the general
pattern of interest rates.
Before analyzing the interest rates associated with unsolicited
credit-card offers, it is important to note that the interest rates
charged by many and probably most traditional banking organizations do
follow the interest-rate patterns of the financial markets. To
illustrate this, Zions First National Bank of Salt Lake City, Utah was
selected as a regional bank of intermediate size, and its credit-card
charges associated with Master Card were obtained over the same 11-year
period. The three rates are graphed together in the following visual
(Exhibit 2):
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
As shown in Exhibit 2, the interest-rate charges by Zions First
National Bank on its Master Card (that has consistently been advertised
as nine points over prime) has been strictly adhered to over the
eleven-year period. Of course Zions Bank and other traditional banks in
local communities with strong ties to existing customers have
significant motivation to stay in line with current interest rates.
But staying within "reasonable limits" may not be as much
a motivation for financial intermediaries that aggressively solicit
customers from out of their local service areas. A preliminary review of
the hundreds of credit-card solicitations on file suggest that these
soliciting institutions generally use a combination of low
"introductory rates" to entice customers to sign up for the
credit cards and then high "ongoing rates" to generate high
profits afterwards. Analyses also suggest that the introductory rates
used to "hook" customers have been getting more competitive
over time (dropping) while the ongoing rates following the introductory
period have been remaining steady, perhaps even rising somewhat during
the decline in interest rates in other markets.
ANALYSIS OF INTRODUCTORY INTEREST RATES
To test the first two hypotheses that relate to the
"introductory rates," the advertising flyers that were
randomly selected from the 36-month period did show a decline over time
in the advertised introductory rates. But the individual data points
that are plotted do tend to "jump all over" because of the
individual strategies of the soliciting companies. It is dramatically
apparent that each company has (1) a strategy for hooking the customers
and (2) a strategy for making high profits afterwards. One company, for
example, may have low introductory interest rates coupled with high
service fees while another company may have just the opposite.
With such varied business strategies, the data points don't
show a "tight" visual fit. The correlation coefficient associated with the regression line for the introductory rates only had
a value of .122547, so the data would not be very good for predicting a
single interest-rate value for one period, but the sum total of the 120
data points for the analysis period is statistically significant in
showing the general pattern and direction of the introductory rates over
the three-year period. Exhibit 3 shows (1) the average value of the data
points for each month, (2) an additional "smoothing" line
showing a running average of five monthly data points at a time, and (3)
a straight line that shows the calculated regression line based on the
data points:
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Although the thirty-six months of data shown in Exhibit 3 do show a
slight downward trend in the advertised introductory interest rates, the
numbers do not tell the whole story. Additional analysis shows that the
real competitive forces in introductory rates manifested themselves
before the three-year period. Although sufficient data was not available
for calendar years 1999 and 2000, there was sufficient data for 1998,
and it showed an average introductory interest rate of 7.017 percent for
the flyers sampled for that year compared to an average introductory
rate of 1.753 percent for the three-year period shown in Exhibit 3.
A look at other interest characteristics of 1998 showed the year to
be compatible with the beginning of 2001. For example, the prime rate in
early 2001 (February) was exactly 8.5 percent, and most of 1998 had a
prime rate of 8.5 percent, so there seemed to be considerable value in
splicing 1998 to the 36 months of data beginning in January 2001. As
shown below in Exhibit 4, adding the introductory rates for the 12
months of 1998 to the 36 months shown in Exhibit 3 provides a more
accurate picture of the lowering of introductory rates that has taken
place as solicitors have become more competitive.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Notice that the regression line shown in Exhibit 4 actually drops
slightly below zero at the end of 2003, and that is representative of
what has happened in this competitive arena. Of the random samples
selected from the last nine months of 2003, only one of the nine months
had a sample that showed an introductory rate greater than zero. So the
first hypothesis that introductory rates have declined is statistically
significant, but whether these rates have declined faster than the
general interest rates depends on where the data points begin.
Consequently, the second hypothesis is less significant depending on the
chosen range. More will be said about the degree of decline in later
pages.
ANALYSIS OF ONGOING INTEREST RATES
As to the "ongoing interest rates" charged following the
introductory periods, the two hypotheses were (1) that the ongoing
interest rates of these aggressive credit-card solicitors have not
responded to the declining interest rates in other financial markets and
(2) that the ongoing rates have actually been increasing through the
general period of interest-rate decline. To test these hypotheses, a
similar procedure was used as the one described for the introductory
rates. For the thirty-six-month period beginning with January 2001, the
120 samples provided an average of more than three data points for each
of the 36 months, and these 36 monthly averages are shown below in
Exhibit 5:
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
As with the introductory interest rates, the various business
strategies have led to a pattern that "jumps all over the
board." Collectively, there does seem to be a "flat"
pattern over time, perhaps even a slight increase in the ongoing rates,
but the profit strategies of the companies has lead to a data pattern
that is not a tight fit around the mathematical regression line. With a
correlation coefficient of .056764, the data could hardly be used with
any confidence in predicting the ongoing interest rate for any single
point in time. But the 120 data points randomly selected over the
36-month period do collectively show evidence that the ongoing rates
have remained stable during the 36-month period, thus confirming
Hypothesis #3 that the ongoing rates have not declined with
society's other declining rates.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
In Exhibit 6, shown above, smoothed data (using a five-month
running average) and a regression line have been added to the data on
ongoing interest rates from the previous exhibit. Notice that the
regression line does show a pattern that defies the declining interest
rates that have been characteristic of interest rates in other financial
markets during the three-year period. With a Y-intercept of 14.8047
percent and a slight positive slope of .023802 percent, there is strong
statistical evidence to support Hypothesis #3 that interest rates have
not declined. But the .023802 slope, although positive, does not provide
strong statistical evidence to support Hypothesis #4 that ongoing
interest rates are increasing as an industry pattern.
Although there is less need to splice the 1998 data in front of the
36-month data as was done with the introductory interest rates,
nevertheless the additional 12 months of data is added to the data shown
in Exhibits 5 and 6 to demonstrate that these credit-card solicitors
have been consistent over time in keeping their ongoing rates at higher
levels in spite of declining rates in other financial markets. The 48
months of data for the "ongoing rates" is shown below in
Exhibit 7.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
For the 48-month period, the data has a correlation coefficient of
.034113, so the data would have little value for predicting an
interest-rate amount for a single month, but the collective data, based
on the sample size of 144, does provide evidence of the same pattern
that was shown in Exhibit 6 for 36 months. Namely, the Y-intercept of
15.02687 and the slight positive slope of .011029 is further evidence to
support Hypothesis #3--that ongoing interest rates charged by
credit-card solicitors is inelastic and continues to remain at high
levels in spite of the declining interest rates in other financial
markets. As to Hypothesis #4 relating to a rise in these rates, the data
is not statistically significant. There is a slight upward trend, but it
is not strong enough statistically to suggest that it is part of an
upward trend in that segment of the industry.
Having shown in the exhibits the clear pattern of decline in
introductory rates but relative stability in the ongoing interest rates,
it appears that aggressive credit-card solicitors use a dual strategy of
low introductory rates to lure new customers and the higher ongoing
rates to generate solid profits afterwards. In other words, there is
statistically significant evidence based on the sample data that
Hypotheses #1 and #3 are correct-that introductory rates are declining
and ongoing rates are not declining. A summary of the data is shown
below in Exhibit 8 with the regression lines for the two credit-card
rates plotted with the actual data for the prime rate.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Economically speaking, the data shows that competitive pressures
are felt in the introductory rates but ongoing rates seem to be
unaffected by competitive pressures. Stated another way, it is unlikely
that lowering ongoing rates would attract a significantly greater
customer base. Otherwise, the credit-card solicitors would respond by
using that as a stimulus.
EVALUATING THE DECLINE IN THE INTRODUCTORY RATES
While the basic pattern and direction of the two credit-card rates
are generally clear, there is still a question relating to Hypothesis #2
on whether the introductory rates have declined faster than market
rates. To begin with a comparison was made over the 36-month period
between the prime rate (actual data), federal funds rate (actual data),
and the introductory rates (regression line). The resulting data is
shown in Exhibit 9 on the following page.
Notice that the lines demonstrate highly different characteristics
over time with the prime rate and federal funds rate dropping rapidly in
2001 but leveling off somewhat in 2002 and 2003. The introductory
credit-card rates as a linear regression line (and also the raw data for
the introductory rates) over the same 36 months dropped at a slower pace
in the 2001 period but at perhaps a comparable pace during 2002 and
2003. In other words, whether one dropped more rapidly than another was
greatly dependent on which months were selected for evaluation. After
much analysis, the only conclusion that could be reached is that
Hypothesis #2 was inconclusive based on the 36-month data.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Switching to the 48-month data for the prime rate (actual data),
the federal funds rate (actual data), and introductory interest rate
regression line, the same observations apply. As shown below in Exhibit
10, the prime rate and federal funds rate dropped more rapidly during
2001. In the other periods, the introductory interest rates for credit
cards were at least comparable in decline and perhaps even a little
steeper at times, but the results depended greatly on which months were
selected for evaluation. After considerable analysis, the only
conclusion that could be reached was that the 48-month data also left
Hypothesis #2 without sufficiently conclusive evidence.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Using the 48-month regression line of the prime rate as
representative of the general market rates, the regression lines of the
introductory interest rates and ongoing interest rates charged by the
credit-card solicitors are all plotted together in Exhibit 11 on the
following page. While the slope of the ongoing interest rates is a
positive .011029, the slope of the prime rate is a negative .124408 and
the slope of the introductory rate is a negative .143449. It is true for
the 48-month data that the introductory rate has declined a little more
rapidly than the prime rate.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
For the 36-month period, which is cleaner data, the slope of the
ongoing rate is a positive .023802 while the slope of the prime rate is
a negative .119718 and the slope of the introductory rate is a negative
.032317. In other words, for the 36-month data, the introductory rate is
actually declining a little less rapidly than the prime rate (just the
opposite of the 48-month data). The statistical characteristics of the
data are shown in the following table:
Whether using 36-month data or 48-month data, the overall visual
impression of Exhibit 11 is the main message. Introductory interest
rates charged by the aggressive, mail solicitors of credit cards have
fallen over time commensurate with the decline in other general interest
rates, but the ongoing interest rates charged to credit-card customers
are inelastic. Indeed, they may be described as stubbornly resilient in
a period of declining interest rates.
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
The focus of this paper has been on the advertising materials that
are typically sent to American homes by the so-called aggressive
national marketers of credit-card services. The 144 advertising flyers
from 30 of these national solicitors were analyzed and yielding the
following results in relationship to the four hypotheses:
As to the first hypothesis, the research data leaves no question
that introductory rates have been declining in recent years. The sample
size of 144 was statistically significant and the trend of these rates
can be readily seen in the exhibits that have been shown.
As to the second hypothesis, the question of whether the rates have
been declining faster than other rates in society is considered
inconclusive. The results depended primarily on the time period being
evaluated. In the 36-month data, the introductory rates declined
slightly less rapidly than the general interest rates used in the
analysis. In the 48-month data, the introductory rates declined a little
more rapidly than the general interest rates. Overall, it can be said
that the introductory interest-rate declines have been at least
comparable to declines in other rates.
The ongoing interest rates that were the focus of the third
hypothesis have without question defied the interest-rate declines in
other financial markets. This was statistically significant over both
the 36-month data from 2001 through 2003 and the 48-month data. In other
words, the interest rates charged by the mail advertisers of credit
cards continue to resist any downward pressures. They are resilient and
inelastic.
With the 144 data points that were randomly selected to test the
fourth hypothesis, there was a slight increase in these rates over the
time periods tested, but the results were not considered statistically
significant. The interest levels remained robust and "sticky"
at their recent levels, but the increases were not statistically strong
enough to conclude that they were part of an upward trend in the
industry.
AN ADDITIONAL OBSERVATION
The quantitative and qualitative treatment of the research
information, although providing great insights, did not fully divulge an
even broader phenomenon that is taking place in the credit-card
industry. The motivation of credit-card providers is naturally to make
as much profit as possible, and when interest charges are the primary
source of income, many cardholders "escape the hook" by paying
their balances in full each month. Consequently, a significant increase
in fees continues to be put in place by credit-card providers.
Throughout the research there has been an increasing awareness of this
momentum.
To illustrate the significance of this phenomenon, the following
statement is contained in an advertising flyer that has been received
twice in recent months. In the mass of information that is contained in
the contractual understanding of the application form, it states:
"Available Credit and Cash Advance Limitations: The initial minimum
credit limit will be $250 and the following fees will be billed to your
first statement: Annual Fee of $48.00, Program Fee of $95.00, Account
Set-Up Fee of $29.00, monthly Participation Fee of $6.00 [$72.00
annually], and an Additional Card Fee of $20.00 (if applicable). If you
are assigned the minimum credit limit of $250 your initial available
credit will be $72 ($52 if you choose the additional card option)."
In addition, the itemized fees above do not even include such other
fees as minimum finance charge of $0.50, transaction fee for cash
advances which is the greater of $5.00 or 3% of the amount of the cash
advance, late payment fee of $25.00 each time the payment is late, over
limit fee of $25 each month the balance exceeds the credit limit, $25.00
for returned checks, possible Copying Fees of $3.00, Internet Access Fee
of $3.95, Autodraft Fee of $11.00, and Voice Response Fee of $7.00 per
transaction. As to the Voice Response Fee, the cardholder who signs up
better not make a later telephone call to complain, because $7.00 will
be tacked on with each phone call.
Although the research project focused on the interest rates, as the
rate information was being extracted for the quantitative analysis,
there was increasing amazement at the type of fees, number of fees,
amount of fees, and trend of these fees. After evaluating 144 of the
flyers it can be confidently stated that if the fees and interest rates
had been evaluated together, the upward trend in credit-card charges
would not only have been statistically significant (as concluded in the
third hypothesis), but dramatically upward in the slope of the
regression line. There is no question that this is "fodder"
for the next research project.
REFERENCES
Ausubel, L. M. (1991). The Failure of Competition in the Credit
Card Market. The American Economic Review, 81(1), 50-81.
Ausubel, L.M. (1997). Credit Card Defaults, Credit Card Profits,
and Bankruptcy. American Banker, LJ 249.
Balto, D. A. & B. K. Grube (2002, May). The Visa-Master Card
decision and its implications for high-tech markets. The Business
Lawyer, 57(3).
Berlin, M. & L. J. Mester (2004). Credit card rates and
consumer search. Review of Financial Economics, 13(1), p. 179.
Bhandari, S. B (2002). Some ethical issues in computation and
disclosure of interest rate and cost of credit. Journal of Business
Ethics. 16(5), p. 531-535.
Bianco, C. A. & S. M. Bosco (2002). Ethical Issues in Credit
Card Solicitation of College Students--The Responsibilities of Credit
Card Issuers, Higher Education, and Students. Teaching Business Ethics,
6(1), p. 45.
Boyer, M. (2003, January 8). Industry Notes: Banking. The
Cincinnati Enquirer.
Brito, D. L. & P. R. Hartley (1995). Consumer rationality and
credit cards. The Journal of Political Economy, 103(2), p. 400-433.
Brooker, K. (2004, February 23). Just One Word: Plastic--How the
rise of the credit card changed life for the FORTUNE 500-and for the
rest of us. Fortune, p. 125-138.
Calem, P. S. & L. J. Mester (1995), Consumer Behavior and the
Stickiness of Credit-Card Interest Rates. The American Economic Review,
85(5), p. 1327-1336.
Cargill, T. F. & J. Wendel (1996, Winter). Bank credit cards:
Consumer Irrationality versus market forces. The Journal of Consumer
Affairs. 30(2), p. 373-389.
Consumer Federation of America (CFA) (2003). Facts About Consumer
Credit Card Debt and Bankruptcy. P. 4.
Cornett, M. M. & J. Musumeci (1999, Autumn). How Legislation
Affects Value: The Failure of Credit Card Cap Legislation. Financial
Management.
Gross, D. B. & N. S. Souleles (2002, February). Do Liquidity
constraints and interest rates matter for consumer behavior? Evidence
from credit card data. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 117(1), p.
149.
Hamilton, R. & M. Khan (2001, July). Revolving Credit Card
Holders: Who Are They and How Can They Be Identified? Service Industries
Journal, 21(3), p. 37-48.
Kara, A., E. Kaynak & O. Kucukemiroglu (1994). Credit card
development strategies for the youth market: The use of conjoint
analysis. The International Journal of Bank Marketing. 12(6), 30-36.
Mantripragada, K. G & H. Benerjee (1992). Credit Card Interest
Rate Caps Do Not Make Sense. Review of Business, 14(1), p. 19-24.
Mayer, R. N. & C. D. Zick (1996). The cost of "free"
credit card benefits. Consumer Interests Annual, 42, p. 161-166.
Moskowitz, H., D. Cohen, B. Krieger & S. Rabino (2001).
Interest and reaction time analysis of credit card offers: Managerial
implications of high level research procedures. Journal of Financial
Services Marketing. 6(2), p. 172-189.
Mosler, W. (2003/2004, Winter). Credit cards and interest rates:
theory and institutional factors-a critical view. Journal of Post
Keynesian Economics, 26(2), p. 303-307.
Nader, R. (2004, January 9). Deeper and Deeper in Debt. The Nader
Page, www.nader.org.
Parloff, R. (2004, February 23). The $50 Billion Card Game.
Fortune.
Reddy, A. (2003, April 16). Consumer Loans Boost Bank Profits.
Washington Post, p. E01.
Scholnick, B. (2000). Regulation, competition, risk in the market
for credit cards. Canadian Public Policy, 26(2), p. 171.
Sinkey, J.F., Jr. & R. Nash (1997). On Competition, Risk, and
Hidden Assets in the Market for Bank Credit Cards. Journal of Banking
and Finance, p. 89-112.
Stango, V. (2000, August). Competition and pricing in the credit
card market. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(3), p. 499-508.
Stauffer, R. F. (2003/2004, Winter). Credit cards and interest
rates: theory and institutional factors. Journal of Post Keynesian
Economics, 26(2), p. 289-301.
Stavins, J. (1996). Can demand elasticities explain sticky credit
card rates? New England Economic Review, p. 43-54.
Stavins, J. (2000, Jul/Aug). Credit card borrowing, delinquency,
and personal bankruptcy. New England Economic Review, p. 15-30.
Steindl, F. G. (2000, Summer). Credit Cards, Economization of
Money, and Interest Rates. Journal of Economic Education, 31(3), p.
271-279.
Toh, K. G. (1996, March). Are credit-card late fees "interest?
Michigan Law Review, 94(5), p.1294.
Warnick, J. & P. Mansfield (2000). Credit card consumers:
college students' knowledge and attitude. The Journal of Consumer
Marketing. 17(7), p. 617.
Yu Hsing, J. G., T. Lin & D. Wallace (2003, September).
Determinants of credit card rates and policy implications. International
Journal of Management, 20(3), p. 395.
Zweig, P. L. (1997, October 27). The New Stars of Finance. Business
Week, p. 122-125.
Stephen T. Evans, Southern Utah University
Summary of Regression and Correlation Values
Intercept
Data for Ongoing Rates +14.80467
36 months Prime Rate +7.454508
Federal Funds Rate +4.416365
Introductory Rates +2.350635
Data for Ongoing Rates +15.02687
48 months Prime Rate +9.066339
Federal Funds Rate +6.051569
Introductory Rates +6.583245
Slope Correlation
Coefficient
Ongoing Rates +.023802 +.056764
Prime Rate -.119718 +.872041
Federal Funds Rate -.118332 +.869246
Introductory Rates -.032317 +.122547
Ongoing Rates +.011029 +.034113
Prime Rate -.124408 +.940051
Federal Funds Rate -.124197 +.939417
Introductory Rates -.143449 +.510362