The choice of private versus public debt in an emerging economy: does information asymmetry play a role?
Rajagopal, Sanjay
INTRODUCTION
More concentrated ownership and greater flexibility to
renegotiation in the private debt market is argued to result in superior
ex-ante information among private lenders, and in an increased creditor
control over the borrower's investment and liquidation decisions.
This mitigates in private markets the problems of adverse selection and
moral hazard associated with credit generation (see, for example, Smith
& Warner (1979), Diamond (1984), Blackwell & Kidwell (1988), and
Berlin & Loeys (1988)). However, there are also costs to private
debt in the form of monitoring costs, bank regulatory taxes, premiums
for reduced liquidity, and agency costs of delegated monitoring (see
Berlin & Loeys (1988), Diamond (1991), and Zwick (1980)), and the
tradeoff of benefits and costs suggests the existence of an
"optimal" level of private debt. This line of argument
suggests that for firms with larger information asymmetries, the
benefits of private debt will tend to outweigh the costs of private
lender monitoring, ceteris paribus.
A growing body of literature has addressed, from both a theoretical
and an empirical perspective, the precise factors influencing this
private/public debt choice (e.g., Rajan (1992), Diamond (1993), Houston
& James (1996), Johnson (1997), and Krishnaswami et al. (1999)).
While the results of this research generally suggest a unique role for
private debt markets in the presence of information asymmetry-and
consistently indicate the relevance of a well-defined set of
firm-specific factors to the choice of debt source-the empirical work
remains largely limited to the context of a developed economy such as
the US.
In contrast to the bulk of the extant research, the current paper
focuses on the firm's private/public debt choice in the context of
an emerging economy, India. This country represents an interesting case
because, while its traditionally over-regulated domestic capital markets
and commercial banking system have increasingly been exposed to the
discipline of market forces, the process of reform has by no means
brought its financial system yet to quite the levels of competition,
efficiency and relative transparency found in developed countries (see
indications of this in, for example, the Guha-Khasnobis & Bhaduri
(2000) study). In this state of "partial adjustment" towards a
competitive financial system, does private debt play a significant
monitoring and certification role? Or is a predominantly publicly-owned
banking and financial sector-the principal lenders in the private debt
market-so constrained by regulation, so shielded from the discipline of
market forces, or so affected by inefficiencies, nepotism and corruption
that the existence of private debt relations with its institutions do
not convey any valuable information to the investor? By using a logistic
regression model, this paper examines whether the likelihood of a
publicly traded Indian firm's exclusive dependence on private debt
is systematically related to firm-level measures of information
asymmetry. If there is a systematic positive relationship between that
likelihood and information asymmetry, the results would be consistent
with private lenders having a special monitoring role similar to the one
documented in developed economies.
The primary purpose of this study, then, is to ascertain whether
the observed role of lenders in the private debt market in a developed
economy such as the US can be generalized to an emerging economy like
India, in which the financial institutions have traditionally been
largely under state control and shielded from market discipline. Its
findings are potentially significant in assessing any progress the
country has made in reforming its financial sector. The paper is
organized as follows. The section below provides an overview of the
financial sector reforms undertaken by India during the 1990s. Following
that, the literature on the firm's private/public debt choice is
reviewed. The end of that section also presents the hypothesized
relationships for the current study. The next section discusses the data
and variables used in the study, along with criteria for sample
selection, and a univariate differences-in-means analysis of the group
of firms relying solely on private debt versus the group of firms with
public debt in their capital structure. In the section following,
multivariate logistic regressions results on the private/public debt
choice are provided and discussed. The final section provides
conclusions and implications, along with suggestions for further
research.
A BRIEF OVERVIEW OF FINANCIAL SECTOR REFORM IN INDIA
Financial sector reform has been an integral part of the new
economic policy adopted by India beginning in 1991 (see, for example,
Guha-Khasnobis & Bhaduri (2000)). This process of financial reform
has entailed, among other things, a significant reduction in the cash
reserve requirement (CRR) and the statutory liquidity ratio (SLR).
Between 1991 and 1998, for instance, the SLR declined from 38.5% to 25%,
and the CRR has declined from about 25% to 10.5% (for a more detailed
discussion of the reforms, see Ahluwalia (1999); Beim & Calomiris
(2001); and Laeven (2003), from which much of the discussion in this
section is adapted, and which are also the source for the data quoted
herein). Thus, the proportion of incremental resources to banks (from
deposits) that was pre-empted by the government was roughly 65% prior to
the reforms; that number now stands at about 36%. Put another way, the
"tax" on financial intermediation has significantly been
reduced over the 1990s.
In addition, interest rate controls have been eased progressively,
moving the loan market away from a regime of subsidized rates and
towards a more rational, market-based system. Thus, banks are relatively
more free to price loans on the basis of fund costs and credit risk. The
easing of entry restrictions to a traditionally state-controlled banking
sector, which occurred in 1993, is reflected in the fact that between
1991 and 1997, the market share of private and foreign banks increased
from roughly 11% to approximately 18%.
Another significant development has been the introduction of
capital adequacy standards for banks. Prudential norms somewhat similar
to the ones recommended by the Basle Committee were phased in by 1996,
which, in addition to lending a certain transparency to the balance
sheets of banks, lean on the institutions to improve asset quality. Bank
supervision has also been strengthened, with the establishment of the
Board for Financial Supervision within the Reserve Bank of India (RBI),
India's central bank. The role of internal controls and audit, and
that of external auditors have been shored up, and the time taken for
the inspection and follow-up cycle has been cut in half.
Despite the improvements described above, though, the question
which is of particular relevance to the current paper is how the new,
reformed standards compare with international practice. As Ahluwalia
(1999) notes, the government-appointed Committee on Banking Sector
Reforms (CBSR) has reported several deficiencies with regard to the
comparability of the new Indian banking norms with international
standards. For instance, capital to "risk-weighted" assets for
banks continue to be below international standards. Indian standards are
more lax with regard to the reclassification of "substandard"
and "doubtful" assets; a greater period of delinquency is
allowed by Indian banks before such assets are downgraded.
"Directed credit policies", which require banks to earmark 40%
of their commercial loans to "priority" sectors identified by
the government, remain in place. Significantly, the government still
maintains a majority ownership of public sector banks (which account for
a significant share of the market). This public ownership "involves
'politicization' and 'bureaucratization' of
banking" (Ahluwalia (1999); p.44). Thus, it is quite possible that
Indian banks, despite the recent progress in liberalization, are beset by "cronyism" in loan making, and an impaired ability to
respond to commercial and customer needs (or dictates of the market).
It is this "transitional" nature of the Indian financial
sector that provides the context for the current paper, and motivates
the question as to whether the private/public debt choice determinants
identified for firms in developed economies also play a significant
explanatory role in India. For example, if banks are operating in an
environment divorced from the pressures of the market, are making credit
decisions not on the basis of a rational assessment of risk but for the
sake of political expediency, and have little incentive to monitor the
borrower, or generate information that is economically valuable to loan
making, then the roles of variables such as the "age",
"size", "risk", or "collateral asset
value" of the borrowing firm, which appear to systematically
explain the private/public debt choice in developed economies, might not
be significant factors in the Indian context. Put another way, if
private lending practices are not "fair" and
"economically rational", then we are unlikely to observe
economically sensible patterns in the private/public debt choice of
Indian firms. This point will be elaborated upon at the end of the
following section.
THE PRIVATE VS PUBLIC DEBT CHOICE AND INFORMATION ASYMMETRY
Since the theoretical and empirical research on the monitoring role
of banks and private lenders is well established and abounds in the
literature (the theoretical more so than the empirical), this section
will provide only a brief overview of a representative sample of these
studies. The main concern of this part of the paper will be to provide a
justification for the inclusion of the (six) explanatory variables in
our study, and to provide a basis for its a priori expectations. These
explanatory variables, along with their expected influence on the
private/public debt choice, are summarized at the end of the section.
Financial policy research has sought to explain the cross-sectional
variation in the "placement" choice of debt. Most of the work
on this subject has demonstrated either theoretically or empirically a
special "monitoring" role for lenders in the private debt
market. Since in private markets the ownership of debt is more
concentrated than in the public debt markets, and there is also greater
flexibility to renegotiation in the former, it is argued that private
lenders have superior ex-ante information and increased control over the
borrower's investment and liquidation decisions. This mitigates in
private markets the problems of adverse selection and moral hazard
associated with credit generation (see, for example, Smith & Warner
(1979), Diamond (1984), Blackwell & Kidwell (1988), and Berlin &
Loeys (1988)). Interest in the subject has been sustained through the
past decade, and the more recent studies on the issue include Diamond
(1991), and Rajan (1992). The first study stresses a "reputational
capital" effect in the debt source choice, wherein larger firms,
with established reputations (to maintain) are more likely to access the
public debt market since they do not need to rely now on the monitoring
role of banks. The study by Rajan (1992) stresses possible "hold
up" problems when firms borrow from a single bank (which might have
an informational monopoly), which makes reliance on bank debt less
likely for firms with high quality projects. Recent empirical work on
the subject has been conducted by Easterwood & Kadapakkam (1991),
Houston & James (1996), Johnson (1997a), and Krishnaswami et al.
(1999), among others. On balance, the vast majority of these studies
have confirmed the presence of a special monitoring function for
privately negotiated debt.
Easterwood & Kadapakkam (1991), who study the effect of
transactions costs and leverage-related costs on the private/public debt
choice, find that larger firms, with their larger issue sizes, save on
transactions costs (the large "fixed" cost portion being
spread over a large issue size), and tend to lean on public debt more
than medium-sized firms do. While it is their conjecture that
information asymmetry are also likely to be important to the
private/public debt choice, they do not directly test this proposition.
Houston & James (1996) find evidence consistent with Rajan's
(1992) "hold up" problems model, a problem mitigated by having
multiple-banking relationships. Johnson (1997a) finds, among other
things, that firms have a greater reliance on public debt if they face
lower information and monitoring costs. Krishnaswami et al. (1999) also
find evidence consistent with the hypothesis that younger firms, and
those with greater potential information asymmetries, will tend to rely
more on private debt.
It should be noted that some theoretical studies distinguish
between bank and non-bank private lenders; and they ascribe the unique
monitoring role to the former. But most theoretical and empirical
studies of debt ownership do not. And when the distinction is made, the
evidence is not consistent (see Johnson (1997a), who considers the
distinction between bank and non-bank private debt to be an empirical
issue.)
Several studies employ the natural logarithm of a firm's total
assets as a proxy for information availability and/or economies of scale
in flotation costs (as found in the Easterwood & Kadapakkam (1991)
study). Some of the studies employing this proxy include Krishnaswami et
al. (1999), and Hadlock & James (2002). This "size"
variable is therefore expected to have a negative effect on the
likelihood of a firm issuing private debt.
Barclay & Smith (1995), Krishnaswami et al. (1999), and Hadlock
& James (2002) use the market-to-book ratio as a proxy for a
firm's growth options. To the extent that these options are
difficult to value, the market value-to-book ratio can be used as a
proxy for asymmetric information. Given the special monitoring role of
private lenders, it is expected that the market value-to-book ratio will
have a positive relationship with the likelihood of a firm choosing
private debt.
Krishnaswami et al. (1999) employ the residual volatility in a
firm's stock returns as a proxy for information asymmetry. Hadlock
& James (2002) argue that firms with greater stock return volatility
are more likely to possess large information asymmetry between insiders
and outsiders. The latter measure this volatility as the standard
deviation of the firm's daily stock returns. It is expected that
there will be positive relationship between the volatility measure and
the likelihood of privately placed debt. Note that this is the variable
of primary interest in the present study, which focuses on information
asymmetry; while other variables such as "size" or
"market value-to-book" ratio might also proxy for asymmetric
information, they are also related to other factors that affect the
private/public debt choice-such as economies of scale in flotation
costs, or growth options, as noted earlier.
Johnson (1997a) uses "age", or the number of years since
incorporation, as a proxy for reputation to test the Diamond (1991)
hypothesis regarding the role of reputational capital and choice of
public debt. Since the reputational capital of older firms ensures that
they will avoid actions harmful to creditors even if unmonitored (since
their reputation is valuable and represents a large investment at risk
if tarnished), it is expected that the "age" variable will be
negatively related to the likelihood of choosing private debt.
Johnson (1997a) and Johnson (1997b) employ the ratio of fixed
assets to total assets as a proxy for the assets that can be used as
collateral to reduce the asset substitution problem. The reduction in
asset substitution problems should increase access to public debt. Hoshi
et al. (1993) argue that firms with more valuable "assets in
place" will use public debt since the implied "collateral at
risk" will bond the firm's investment decisions and mitigate
the asset substitution problem. The fixed asset ratio is therefore
expected to be negatively related to the likelihood of use of private
debt.
Diamond (1993) suggests that the more leveraged firms may limit the
use of bank (private) debt so as to frequent firm liquidation (by
private/bank lenders). Hadlock & James (2002) suggest that leverage
might be a proxy for lower agency costs of debt. Consequently, the
leverage variable is expected to be negatively related to the likelihood
of choosing private debt.
In the present study, therefore, the standard deviation of stock
returns and market value-to-book ratio are used as proxies for
information asymmetry. The size of the firm also serves as a proxy for
asymmetric information (with a smaller firm size suggesting greater
informational opacity), but, as has already been pointed out, the size
measure could also proxy for the firm's access to the public debt
market, which is characterized by economies of scale in issuance. The
age of the firm proxies for the entity's reputational capital,
which has been argued by researchers to influence the choice of debt
source. The fixed asset ratio measures the value of the firm's
assets that might be used as collateral in order to mitigate asset
substitution problems. Finally, the firm's leverage is also
included as a negative indicator of the firm's agency costs of
debt.
DATA AND UNIVARIATE ANALYSIS
The data used in this study are collected from a publicly available
database compiled by the Center for Monitoring the Indian Economy
(CMIE). This dataset provides a comprehensive coverage of firms
operating in India's industrial sector, and carries substantial
financial statement information and some market data. All the income
statement data in this study pertain to the year ending December 2002,
and all the balance sheet information is as of December 31, 2002. Market
data are averaged over the 365 days ending December 31, 2002.
This study employs the following seven variables, using the
acronyms indicated:
Variables: Acronyms and Definition
PVTDEBT This is a binary variable which takes a value of 1 if the
firm has only private debt, and 0 otherwise. This serves
as the dependent variable in the logistic regression.
AGE Age is the number of years since the firm's incorporation,
as of the year 2002.
FAR The fixed asset ratio (FAR) is calculated as the ratio of
the firm's net fixed assets to total assets.
MVB The market value-to-book ratio (MVB) is the firm's the
sum of the book value of liabilities plus market
capitalization, divided by the book value of total assets.
SD This measure of stock volatility is the standard deviation
of the firm's daily returns average over a 365-day period.
LNASS This is the natural log of the firm's total assets, and is
used as a proxy for firm size.
LEV Leverage (LEV) is calculated as the ratio of the book
value of total liabilities over the book value of total
assets.
In order to enter the sample, a firm had to meet the following the
criteria:
Criteria for Entry into the Sample
1. The firm is categorized as a manufacturing firm in the
CMIE dataset.
2. The firm is publicly traded.
3. The firm has some debt in its capital structure.
4. There is firm-specific data available on all seven variables
for the firm for the time period of interest.
These four restrictions yield a final sample of 949 firms, of whom
633 (or about 67%) borrow solely in the private debt market. The table
below provides the overall average for each variable, along with each
variable's average for the sample partitioned into two groups-one
that relies exclusively on private debt, and the other that has some
public debt in its capital structure. The table also provides a simple
difference-in-means test for each variable between the two groups.
The variable means in the table above reveal clear differences
between firms that depend solely on private debt, and those that carry
public debt. Firms that borrow solely in the private debt market are, on
average, younger, smaller, have a smaller fixed assets-to-total assets
ratio, have greater stock return volatility, and carry less leverage.
These differences are statistically significant at the 1% level.
However, there is no significant difference in the average market
value-to-book ratios for the two groups of firms.
It should be noted that these univariate comparisons of firms in
the Indian manufacturing sector yield results that closely parallel the
ones reported by Hadlock & James (2002) for firms in the US. They
too find firms without public debt to be, on average, smaller, younger,
less levered, and characterized by greater stock return volatility. The
market value-to-book ratio does not differ significantly between the two
groups of firms in their study either. Unlike their study, however, we
find that there is a distinct difference in the proportion of fixed
assets between the two groups. The following section supplements these
univariate comparisons with the results of a multivariate logit
regression which estimates the likelihood that a firm will rely solely
on private debt.
MULTIVARIATE LOGIT REGRESSION RESULTS
The data summary indicates that approximately two-thirds of the 949
firms in the sample rely solely on private debt for their borrowing
needs, while the others carry public debt in their capital structures.
Also, it is apparent that there are considerable differences between the
two groups of firms on almost all the explanatory variables included in
study. The focus of the our analysis now turns to ascertaining whether
the likelihood of a firm's exclusive dependence on private debt is
systematically related to proxies for information asymmetry. Again, the
presumption is that private lenders can more closely monitor the
borrower, and more accurately price a firm's claims, thereby
mitigating adverse selection problems. The benefit of private debt
financing, if it indeed exists in the case of India, should be greater
for those firms that are characterized by greater information asymmetry
or opacity.
As noted previously, the standard deviation of stock returns (SD)
and market value-to-book ratio (MVB) are used as proxies for information
asymmetry. The size of the firm (LNASS) also serves as a proxy for
asymmetric information (with a smaller firm size suggesting greater
informational opacity), but, as has already been pointed out, the size
measure could also proxy for the firm's access to the public debt
market, which is characterized by economies of scale in issuance. The
age of the firm (AGE) proxies for the entity's reputational
capital, which has been argued by researchers to influence the choice of
debt source. The fixed asset ratio (FAR) measures the value of the
firm's assets that might be used as collateral in order to mitigate
asset substitution problems. Finally, the firm's leverage (LEV) is
also included as a negative indicator of the firm's agency costs of
debt. These proxies have been employed by previous studies, which have
been cited above and are not repeated here. The following table provides
the results of three estimated models; the motivation for estimating
three models is provided below.
The empirical analysis in this section is built around the model of
debt source choice estimated by Hadley & James (2002). Model 3,
which is the most "inclusive" in that it incorporates all the
six regressors in the equation, conforms to the relationship defined by
Hadley & James. However, both theoretical and practical
considerations compel us to begin with a model with just AGE, FAR, MVB,
and SD. Recall that our main focus is on the signs and significance of
the two proxies included purely to represent information
asymmetry-namely MVB and SD; the other regressors enter as control
variables. Yet, as the list of variables grows, the chance of
multicollinearity among any pair of variables rises considerably. As the
correlation matrix below indicates, there is a high degree of
collinearity between the size variable (LNASS) and several of the
variables included in Model 1. In addition to the issue of
multicollinearity, one has to contend with the theoretical basis for
expecting a relationship between leverage (LEV) and several of the other
regressors in the model. Indeed, in his empirical study of the ownership
structure of corporate debt in the US, Johnson (1997a) confronts this
issue, noting that the inclusion of the leverage variable in the
equation renders the interpretation of the regression coefficients
problematic, since theory suggests that this debt measure is related to
such variables as asset collateral value and firm size.
Given that we need to contend with these two methodological issues,
we begin by estimating a simplified model employing only AGE, FAR, MVB,
and SD as the explanatory variables, and recognizing the possibility of
the confounding effects of omitted variables. However, note that the
omitted variable LNASS plays a dual role, in that it represents the
accessibility that larger firms have to the public debt market, but it
also proxies for information availability. This fact might mitigate the
"omitted variable" problem, given the main focus of this
study. This, least inclusive, logit regression (Model 1) yields results
that are entirely in keeping with our expectations: all the variables
have the hypothesized signs, and are significant at the 1% level. While
the "pseudo R-square" is reported, it should be interpreted
with caution as in any logistic regression (see, for example, Aldrich
& Nelson (1984)); we include the information purely to facilitate a
comparison across the three models.
Model 2 attempts to address the issue of omitting LNASS by
including an instrumental variable (LNASSr) in place of the missing size
variable. This instrumental variable represents the residuals from the
regression of LNASS on AGE, FAR, MVB, and SD. LNASSr is highly
correlated with LNASS (rho=0.901, as the correlation matrix below
indicates), but is orthogonal to the other regressors, and does not
affect their coefficient estimates. The inclusion of LNASSr in the model
leaves the sign and significance of all variables unaffected, except for
MVB; the coefficient for this variable maintains its sign, but is no
longer significant even at the 10% level. Significantly, the other
measure of information asymmetry, SD, maintains its sign and
significance. While the results are not reported here, we used an
instrumental variable for SD (constructed in a manner similar to
LNASSr), and found that the general nature of the results were identical
to the those reported for Model 2; only the precise magnitudes of
coefficients were slightly different, but their signs and significance
were maintained.
Model 3 attempts to address the issue of the simultaneous inclusion
of leverage and other variables (age, size, asset collateral value,
etc.) with which it is theoretically related. As in Johnson (1997a), we
partition leverage (LEV) into an "endogenous" ascribed to the
other regressors, and an "exogenous" part that is independent
of those variables. The latter, LEVr, represents the residuals from the
regression of LEV on the other explanatory variables. This
"exogenous" portion of LEV, which is highly and significantly
correlated with LEV (rho=0.91) is then used as an instrumental variable
in the logistic regression. The results of Model 3 indicate considerable
stability in the magnitude of the coefficients, all of which-with the
exception of MVB-maintain their signs and significance. The coefficient
of the market value-to-book ratio maintains its negative sign, but is
now significant at the 10% level. It should be noted that our inclusion
of "instrumental variables" to try and circumvent multicollinearity or simultaneity problems is similar to the approach
taken by other studies pertaining to corporate financial policy, such as
Johnson (1997a) mentioned earlier and Bah & Dumontier (2001).
Overall, the results of the logistic regressions confirm the
stylized facts that emerged from the univariate analysis of the previous
section. The likelihood that an Indian manufacturing firm will have an
exclusive dependence on private debt is found to be positively related
to stock price volatility, and negatively related to size, age, fixed
asset ratio and leverage. The market value-to-book ratio appears not to
play a significant role, though it does enter as a mildly significant
variable in Model 3, with the hypothesized sign. These results closely
conform to the findings in the recent private/public debt choice studies
conducted on US firms (e.g., Houston & James (1996), Johnson
(1997a), and Hadlock & James (2002)).
CONCLUSION
The results of this study are entirely in keeping with the
hypothesized relationships which were based upon observed relationships
in developed economies, and predicated upon banks and other private
lenders playing a unique monitoring function. Since traditionally the
role of the private debt market has been studied in the context of these
developed economies, with their well-functioning, competitive, and
market-oriented financial institutions (which accounts for the bulk of
private lending), the present study, with its contrasting look at an
emerging economy, constitutes a useful addition to the study of private
lending.
India serves as a useful context within which to study the role of
private debt markets, and the choice-of-debt source question because its
commercial banking sector and other financial institutions have
traditionally been over-regulated, but are now undergoing a process of
liberalization. In such a situation of "partial adjustment"
towards market discipline, the current study considered whether private
debt played a role similar to the one observed in developed economies.
The results of this paper suggest that that question may be answered in
the affirmative, at least to the extent that the debt source choice
appears to be related to information asymmetry in the case of Indian
firms as well. This finding is consistent with the idea that the process
of financial sector reform which gained momentum in the latter part of
the 1990s has had a positive impact on a traditionally state-dominated
industry. In that regard, these results counter some of the more bleak
conclusions about the liberalization process in India that might be
drawn from other studies, such as that by Guha-Khasnobis & Bhaduri
(2000).
Since the process of financial sector reform is continuing in
India, it might be informative to extend the time frame of this study in
either direction of 2002, which was our time period of interest. For
instance, a comparison might be made between the relationships observed
for 2002 in this study, and another estimated model for, say 1992, which
would pre-date a bulk of the reforms that were put into place by the
Indian government during the 1990s. This would document the changing
role of the financial institutions and intermediaries as monitors and
information producers across different regimes of "financial
repression". Finally, the study can also be made more comprehensive
by including firms from the growing services sector within India.
REFERENCES
Ahluwalia, M. S. (1999). Reforming India's Financial Sector:
An Overview. In J.A. Hanson & S. Kathuria (Eds.), India: A Financial
Sector for the Twenty-First Century (pp. 29-54). OUP: India.
Aldrich, J. H. & F. D. Nelson (1984). Linear Probability,
Logit, and Probit Models. Sage Publications.
Bah, R.& P. Dumontier (2001). R&D Intensity and Corporate
Financial Policy: Some International Evidence. Journal of Business
Finance & Accounting, 28, 671-692.
Barclay, M. & C. Smith (1995). The Maturity Structure of Debt.
Journal of Finance, 50, 609-631.
Beim, D. O. & C. W. Calomiris (2001). Emerging Financial
Markets. McGraw-Hill.
Berlin, M. & J. Loeys (1988). Bond Covenants and Delegated
Monitoring. Journal of Finance, 43, 397-412.
Blackwell, D. & D. S. Kidwell (1988). An Investigation of Cost
Differences Between Public Sales and Private Placements of Debt. Journal
of Financial Economics, 22, 253-278.
Diamond, D. W. (1984). Financial Intermediation and Delegated
Monitoring. Review of Economic Studies, 51, 393-414.
Diamond, D.W. (1991). Monitoring and Reputation: The Choice Between
Bank Loans and Directly Placed Debt. Journal of Political Economy, 99,
689-721.
Diamond, D.W. (1993). Seniority and the Maturity of Debt Contracts.
Journal of Financial Economics, 33, 341-368.
Easterwood, J. C. & P. Kadapakkam (1991). The Role of Private
and Public Debt in Corporate Capital Structures. Financial Management,
Autumn 1991, 49-57.
Guha-Khasnobis, B. & S. N. Bhaduri (2000). A Hallmark of
India's New Economic Policy: Deregulation and Liberalization of the
Financial Sector. Journal of Asian Economics, 11, 333-346.
Hoshi, T., A. Kashyap & D. Scharfstein (1993). The Choice
Between Public and Private Debt: An Analysis of Post-Deregulation
Corporate Financing in Japan. Working Paper, NBER (1993).
Houston, J. & C. James (1996). Bank Information Monopolies and
the Mix of Private and Public Debt Claims. Journal of Finance, 51,
1863-1889.
Hadlock, C. & C. James (2002). Do Banks Provide Financial
Slack? Journal of Finance, 57 (3), 1383-1419.
Johnson, S. (1997). An Empirical Analysis of the Determinants of
Corporate Debt Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis, 32, 47-69.
Krishnaswami, S., P.A. Spindt & V. Subramaniam (1999).
Information Asymmetry, Monitoring, and the Placement Structure of
Corporate Debt. Journal of Financial Economics, 51, 407-434.
Laeven, L. (2003). Does Financial Liberalization Reduce Financing
Constraints? Financial Management, 32, 5-34.
Rajan, R. (1992). Insiders and Outsiders: The Choice Between
Informed and Arm's Length Debt. Journal of Finance, 47, 1367-1400.
Smith, C. & J. Warner (1979). On Financial Contracting: An
Analysis of Bond Covenants. Journal of Financial Economics, 7, 117-161.
Sanjay Rajagopal, Montreat College
Variables: Hypothesized Direction of Relationship With
Likelihood of Private Debt
Variable Hypothesized Influence on Private Debt Choice
Age Negative
Fixed Asset Ratio Negative
Market Value-to-Book Positive
Volatility Positive
Size Negative
Leverage Negative
Data Summary and Univariate Analysis
Variable All Firms With With t-statistic
(N=949) Private Public
Debt Only Debt
(N=633) (N=316)
AGE 26.45 23.63 32.12 -6.01 ***
LNASS 4.93 4.32 6.16 -19.75 ***
MVB 0.94 0.95 0.92 0.91
FAR 0.40 0.38 0.46 -6.10 ***
SD 0.07 0.08 0.05 5.16 ***
LEV 0.59 0.54 0.69 -11.01 ***
*** The difference in means between the "no public debt" and
public debt groups is significant at the .01 level.
Logit Models of Private Debt Choice
Variable Model 1 Model 2 Model 3
AGE -0.0196 -0.033 -0.035
(-5.23) *** (-7.60) *** (-7.57) ***
FAR -2.73 -3.28 -3.52
(-6.86) *** (-7.01) *** (-7.22) ***
MVB 0.5275 0.2717 0.492
(2.84) *** -1.38 (1.88) *
SD 0.2149 0.036 0.096
(7.9) *** (2.71) *** (2.92) ***
Logit Models of Private Debt Choice
Variable Model 1 Model 2 Model 3
LNASS -- -1.09 -1.103
(-12.99) *** (-11.59) ***
LEV -- -- -3.23
(-5.89) ***
Intercept 0.5731 2.7488 2.424
(1.73) * (7.87) *** (5.24) ***
N 949 949 949
Ps. R-Sq 0.14 0.28 0.30
Notes:
Each cell shows the estimated coefficient, with the asymptotic
t-values in parentheses.
*** indicates that the coefficient is significant at the .01
level; * indicates significance at the 0.10 level. The size
proxy in Models 2 & 3 is the residual from the regression of
LNASS on AGE, FAR, MVB, SD. Leverage in Model 3 is the residual
from the regression of LEV on the other explanatory variables.
Correlation Matrix for Regressors
AGE FAR MVB SD
FAR -0.080
MVB 0.042 -0.063
SD -0.077 -0.021 -0.100
LNASS 0.301 0.095 0.181
LEV 0.209 0.291 0.021 0.009
LNASSr 0.000 0.000 0.000
LEVr 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
LNASS LEV LNASSr
FAR
MVB
SD
LNASS -0.271
LEV 0.269
LNASSr 0.000 0.901 0.191
LEVr 0.000 0.907 0.000