Consolidation in the banking industry and the viability of small commercial banks: x-efficiency and bank size.
Rogers, Kevin E.
INTRODUCTION
The advent of the Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching
Efficiency Act has relaxed historical geographic restrictions on banks,
contributing to the trend of consolidation in the U. S. commercial
banking industry. The prospect for such extensive change has led
researchers to speculate about the future composition of the banking
industry. Forecasts predict that a small number of large banks will
control most financial assets in the industry, but many small banks will
still survive (Berger, Kashyap & Scalise, 1995; Moore, 1995). The
asset size composition of the industry has received much attention
recently due to the concern that small business lending might decline if
banks consolidate (Berger et al., 1998; Peek & Rosengren, 1998;
Strahan & Weston, 1998). In fact, these studies have found that
small business lending may not decline. They find evidence against the
hypothesis that small business lending will decline as banks become
larger. If small banks' presence in credit markets is reduced, then
there may be an impact on the availability of credit to small borrowers.
Petersen and Rajan (1994) find that the availability of credit is
increased when a firm has close ties with its lender. If consolidation
results in the disappearance of these lenders, then some loans may cease
to have positive net present values and not be made.
One area of research that is relevant to the viability of small
banks in a consolidating industry is that of efficiency. When new
geographic markets are opened to allow more competition, inefficient
banks will be forced to improve or be driven out of the industry by
relatively more efficient, larger banks. Previously protected small
banks could also be acquired by expanding banks, especially if de novo branching is not permitted. Hence, comparisons of X-efficiency in
different bank size classes should reveal some information on the
ability of small banks to compete with larger banks. Given standard
approaches of X-efficiency estimation used with banks, such a comparison
is not that meaningful. As noted by Berger (1993), because of the
preponderance of small banks in any nationwide data sample of banks, the
estimated frontier tends to fit small banks better, resulting in higher
efficiency scores compared to larger banks. For this reason, comparing
small banks with larger institutions is problematic. As a result of
consolidation, small, medium, and large banks will in some cases share
the same market even though they do not share the same technology.
Hence, to provide a useful comparison between small banks and their
future competitors, X-efficiency needs to be measured relative to
efficient banks in larger size classes. Under this framework, more
meaningful comparisons can be made between small banks and their
potential competitors as the banking industry consolidates.
This paper attempts to make such comparisons. Following the
procedure introduced in Mester (1997), frontiers for different size
classes are estimated separately. Using the distribution free approach
of Berger (1993), cost and profit X-efficiency of small banks are
compared to medium and large banks. The results suggest that even after
adjusting the frontiers for size classes, small banks still tend to be
more cost efficient than large banks, but less profit efficient than
some medium-sized banks. This suggests that while many small banks will
be able to compete with larger banks in terms of costs, they may not be
as profitable as the industry consolidates.
THE CONSOLIDATION OF THE BANKING INDUSTRY
Historically, states have placed geographic restrictions on the
branching activities of commercial banks in the U. S. (For a more
detailed summary of geographic restrictions on commercial banking, see
Kaufman (1995, pp 373-377)). As noted by Kane (1996), these restrictions
were implemented and have persisted to protect local markets from
outside competition. Branching restrictions varied among states, with
the most stringent limiting banks to only one office. The restrictions
also applied to banks with national charters. The National Bank Act of
1864 did not address the ability of national banks to branch. They were
effectively limited to only one office. National banks could not branch
unless they had previously operated as a state chartered bank with
branches and then converted to a national charter. The McFadden Act of
1927 permitted national banks to open branches within the same city, as
long as branching was allowed in the state. It was not until the Banking
Act of 1933 that national banks were given the same rights to branch
within a state as state chartered banks.
Multibank holding companies evolved to circumvent geographic
restrictions on banking. A bank could operate in different markets
through multiple subsidiaries all owned by the same parent holding
company. However, in 1956, the Douglas Amendment to the Bank Holding
Company Act made it illegal for a holding company to open a bank or
purchase an existing bank in a state which did not permit it. States
effectively prohibited interstate banking by holding companies until
1978, when Maine started allowing out-of-state holding companies to
operate banks in their state. Since then, interstate banking through
multibank holding companies has spread as various reciprocity agreements
and regional compacts have been enacted.
The removal of geographic restrictions took a major step forward
with the Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of
1994 (IBBEA). IBBEA permits banks to acquire banks in other states,
consolidate subsidiaries of the holding company into one bank, and open
de novo branches across state lines (States can elect to "opt
out" of the consolidation provision and have to "opt in"
to allow de novo branching in their state. Kane (1996) constructs a
rent-seeking model to examine the selection of regulatory regime in this
application.). IBBEA would effectively permit a single bank to branch
nationwide without having to work through a holding company.
The passage of IBBEA has resulted in much speculation on the
potential impact of the removal of geographic restrictions on the
composition of the U. S. banking system. In a study of banking in the
1980's, Rose and Wolken (1990) find that affiliation with a
geographically diversified bank holding company does not provide a
long-term comparative advantage over small, independent banks. This
result suggests that many small banks will survive the consolidation
process. Berger, Kashyap, and Scalise (1995) conduct a simulation to
assess the effect of nationwide banking on the distribution of banking
assets and the number of banks. Their model predicts that within five
years after nationwide banking is implemented, the share of banking held
by banks with less than $100 million in assets will be cut in half, and
there will be about 4,000 fewer banks. Per-capita, these numbers are
comparable to California that has always permitted unlimited branching
to its state banks.
Analysis of consolidation has addressed the impact on efficiency.
Hughes et al. (1996) examine bank holding companies involved in
interstate banking. They find that geographic expansion moves
inefficient banks closer to the efficient frontier in both risk and
return dimensions. The wave of bank mergers in recent years has resulted
in a number of studies that look for changes in efficiency after
mergers. In an investigation of megamergers, Berger and Humphrey (1992)
found that of the megamergers of the 1980's, 55 to 72 percent of
the acquiring banks were more efficient than the acquired banks.
However, despite these potential efficiency gains from mergers, the
scale diseconomies actually reduce overall efficiency. On average, they
find no significant cost efficiency benefits resulting from megamergers.
The result changes as profit efficiency is considered. Akhavein, Berger,
and Humphrey (1997) find that although there was no significant increase
in cost efficiency, profit efficiency did improve on average from
megamergers. While costs may not improve, the merged banks were able to
shift their output into more profitable areas.
These two studies on megamergers point to the usefulness of
estimating both cost and profit efficiency. The benefits to
consolidation may not be restricted just to cost savings. Revenues may
also be enhanced as merged banks can shift resources into more
profitable areas. Akhavein, Berger, and Humphrey (1997) suggest that
there may be benefits due to diversification. As a bank grows in size
through mergers, its potential customer base also expands. This
diversification may result from the larger geographic base for the same
products or the new types of products now profitable because of
increased size. By estimating profit in addition to cost efficiency the
full impact of consolidation can be measured.
The following is an attempt to apply cost and profit efficiency to
small versus larger banks and examine the viability of small banks in a
consolidating market. In the empirical analysis that follows, small
banks refer to those with total assets less than $100 million. These
banks are compared to different classes of medium and large banks with
minimum size of at least $100 million. If small banks are inefficient
relative to larger banks, then consolidation should result in a
significant drop in the number of small banks. Conversely, if small
banks tend to be more efficient, then many should survive and compete
with their larger competitors.
A MODEL OF COST AND PROFIT EFFICIENCY
The distribution free approach is used to estimate cost and profit
efficiency. Separate cost and profit frontiers are estimated for a panel
of banks assuming that X-efficiency is constant over the sample period.
Each bank is assigned an efficiency score ranging over [0,1], with the
most efficient firm receiving a score of 1.
The cost frontier is structured to allow the comparison of the
actual cost of producing a particular bundle of outputs to the minimum
cost necessary to produce that same bundle. Here X-efficiency is the
deviation from minimum cost. The cost frontier is given by the
following:
C = C(y,w, [u.sub.C], [v.sub.C]) Formula (1)
where:
C = costs
y = vector of output quantities
w = vector of input prices
[u.sub.C] = cost inefficiency
[v.sub.C] = random error
The cost inefficiency component, [u.sub.C], raises costs above
minimum costs. Each bank in the sample can be assigned an efficiency
score, CostEFF, which is equal to the ratio of minimum predicted costs
to actual predicted costs.
The profit frontier is constructed according to the alternative or
nonstandard approach used by Berger and Mester (1997) and Humphrey and
Pulley (1997). While the standard profit frontier treats output prices
as exogenous, expressing profits as a function of the prices of inputs
and outputs, the alternative specification takes output quantities as
exogenous:
Pr = Pr(y,w, [u.sub.C], [v.sub.C]) Formula (2)
where:
Pr = profit [u.sub.Pr] = profit inefficiency [v.sub.Pr] = random
error
In this case, [u.sub.Pr] represents how much profits could be
augmented by efficient production. Given the estimation of Eq. (2), each
bank can be given an efficiency score, ProfitEFF, which is equal to the
ratio of actual predicted profits to maximum predicted profits. In
practice, Eqs. (1) and (2) have identical explanatory variables with
costs and profits as dependent variables, respectively.
This alternative specification for the profit frontier is preferred
when banks have some degree of market power. The issue of market power
can be important in considering small banks. Many small banks may
operate in markets protected from competition previous to consolidation.
In addition the quality of output may vary across banks allowing some to
charge higher prices. In this situation, a specification that allows
endogenous prices for bank output seems appropriate. The price of bank
output is also difficult to measure accurately. For these reasons, the
alternative profit frontier is used in this paper.
For the purposes of analyzing efficiency and bank size, Eqs. (1)
and (2) are estimated using a nationwide sample of banks and various
subsets of the entire sample. This approach has also been used in Mester
(1997) for the estimation of frontiers in different Federal Reserve
districts. The National model consisting of all 12 districts combined
into one sample was rejected in favor of the District model that allows
the efficient frontier to vary across each district. When the full
sample of banks is used, small banks tend to dominate the sample,
forcing the frontier to reflect the attributes of efficient, small
banks. Herein, the frontiers are estimated separately for subsets of
medium and large banks as well. Efficiency scores are then assigned to
small banks according to the frontiers of medium and large banks. This
provides for a more suitable comparison of efficiency between banks of
different sizes. By constructing estimates of efficiency in this manner,
small banks can be more accurately compared to their efficient
counterparts and future competitors as branching restrictions are
removed.
EMPIRICAL ESTIMATION
For the estimation of the frontiers in Eqs. (1) and (2) above, the
familiar translog specification was selected using five outputs and four
inputs. The only difference in the two frontiers is the dependent
variable.
Given the translog specification, estimates of cost and profit
efficiency are constructed for bank i according to the following:
Cost[EFF.sub.i] = [u.sub.C.sup.min] / [u.sub.C.sup.i] Formula (3)
Profit[EFF.sub.i] = [u.sub.Pr.sup.i] / [u.sub.Pr.sup.max] Formula (4)
where:
[u.sub.C.sup.min] = minimum cost inefficiency factor
[u.sub.C.sup.i] = cost inefficiency for bank i
[u.sub.Pr.sup.max] = maximum profit inefficiency factor
[u.sub.Pr.sup.i] = profit inefficiency for bank i
Measuring relative efficiency using the minimum cost or maximum
profit inefficiency factor may distort estimates due to outliers.
Following Berger (1993), truncated versions of the u's are
constructed to reduce the impact of outliers. For this study, the top 5
percent of banks are considered fully efficient.
The data used in the estimation are taken from the Reports of
Income and Condition, also known as "Call Reports." A panel
was constructed of annual data from 1991-1996. The six year time series
has been found to be appropriate for estimating efficiency with the
distribution free approach. DeYoung (1997) finds that a six-year time
series is long enough to allow random error to balance out, but still
short enough to assume that inefficiency is unchanging over time. A
balanced panel of 8,386 banks was constructed of banks with nonmissing
observations over the entire time series. The use of a balanced panel is
associated with some costs. Although an acquiring bank in a merger would
be included in the sample, an acquired bank would be left out due to a
lack of nonmissing data after the merger, leading to a survivorship
bias. However, it would also be difficult to interpret estimates from
these banks if they were included since the random error would have had
less time to cancel out of the residual term used in the distribution
free approach. Outputs and inputs were selected according to the
intermediation approach. Outputs consist of demand deposits, time and
savings deposits, real estate loans, and all other loans. Inputs used
were labor, physical capital, deposits, and purchased funds. For each of
the inputs, prices were computed as the ratio of total expenditure on
that input to the quantity of that input.
As discussed above, cost and profit frontiers are estimated with
different subsamples of the data set according to size. First, for
comparability, a frontier is estimated for the entire sample. As in
Mester (1997), this specification is called the National model. Then,
frontiers are estimated separately for five subsets comprised of banks
with total assets of less than $100 million, $100 million to $300
million, $300 million to $500 million, $500 million to $1 billion, and
over $1 billion. Collectively, these frontiers are called the Size model
(The National model is a restricted version of the Size model which does
not allow the frontier to vary across the five different size
classifications.).
Following the distribution free approach, after estimating each
frontier an average residual is computed for all banks, including those
omitted from the frontier estimation. The average residual is the
difference between actual cost (profit) and the efficient level of cost
(profit) predicted by the frontier. Once the average residuals are
computed, efficiency scores can then be calculated as in Eqs. (3) and
(4). The resulting efficiency scores can be used to compare efficiency
across different size classes.
Table 1 presents the estimates of mean cost and profit efficiency.
The results reported in Tables 1 and 3 were computed with a 5 percent
truncation of the residuals. Here, the best 5 percent of the sample are
considered fully efficient (Standard errors of the estimates of cost and
profit efficiency were computed using bootstrapping techniques as
outlined by Simar 1992). In all cases, as shown in tables 1 and 3, mean
efficiencies were significantly less than one). The estimates in columns
1 and 3 are computed using the entire data sample for estimation of the
frontier (the National model). Mean efficiency across all banks is
reported as well as the mean efficiency across each of the five
subsamples. At small banks, mean cost efficiency is 74.4 percent while
mean profit efficiency is 77.5 percent. For the other four subsamples,
mean efficiency ranges from 70.8 to 72.3 percent for costs and from 68.9
to 76.3 percent for profits. As expected, small banks are on average
more efficient than medium and large banks. In columns 2 and 4,
estimates of mean efficiency are reported for each of the subsamples
(the Size model). For these estimates, five separate frontiers were
estimated, one for each subsample, and then mean efficiency was computed
for each group. Inspection of the estimates yields the same conclusion
as before. Small banks have higher mean cost and profit efficiency, 76.3
and 77.6 percent respectively, than their larger counterparts with cost
efficiency ranging from 49.5 to 65.9 percent and profit efficiency
ranging from 69.4 to 76.4 percent. A series of specification tests were
conducted to compare the National model to the Size model. For each
year, an F-statistic was computed to test the null hypothesis that the
frontier is the same across all size classes. The results given in Table
2 suggest that for both cost and profit frontiers, the null hypothesis
can be rejected, implying that the Size model is more appropriate.
In an attempt to compare small banks to their potential
competitors, small banks were also evaluated using the efficient
frontiers of medium and large banks. The results from this procedure are
reported in Table 3 for cost and profit efficiency. Five different
frontier models were estimated including the National model and the four
size classes with total assets above $100 million. Columns 1 and 3
report mean efficiency at small banks when evaluated at the respective
frontiers. For example, when small banks are measured relative to the
efficient banks in the $100 to $300 million size class, mean cost
efficiency at small banks is 65.2 percent. The mean efficiency of the
banks comprising the frontier sample is given in columns 2 and 4.
The results for cost efficiency imply that even when compared to
the efficient frontier of larger banks, small banks are more cost
efficient on average. Although mean efficiency at small banks declines
relative to mean efficiency for the small bank size class (76.3 percent,
from Table 1), mean efficiency is significantly higher than mean
efficiency of each of the larger size classes. The results differ for
profit efficiency. Using the same procedure for comparison, small banks
are found to be more profit efficient, on average, than banks with $100
to $300 million and over $1 billion in total assets. This finding is
reversed when small banks are compared to banks with total assets
between $300 million and $1 billion; small banks are less efficient than
these banks on average.
The results comparing small banks to banks with $300 million to $1
billion in total assets suggest that when the efficiency of small banks
is estimated relative to the frontier of medium- sized banks, small
banks are more cost efficient but less profit efficient. The advantages
to operating at a small scale appear to be reflected in costs, not
revenues. At the same time, the benefits to large scale production seem
to be evidenced in higher revenues rather than reduced costs. At least
some of the advantages to these medium sized banks must be through
greater diversification of earnings. Since these banks have a broader
customer base, they face a more diverse set of revenue sources and can
hence shift resources into more profitable areas. Small banks, in
contrast, are less likely to be able to take advantage of these
opportunities. However, small banks can be more cost efficient,
especially in local markets due to low cost information resulting from
ongoing customer relationships. Although this study does not consider
specific mergers, these results appear to correspond with the two
studies on mergers mentioned above (Berger & Humphrey, 1992;
Akhavein, Berger & Humphrey, 1997). These studies found that
increasing bank size through mergers provided benefits through enhanced
profit efficiency, not cost efficiency.
As stated above, the results differ when small banks are compared
to the largest banks (over $1 billion in assets). On average, small
banks are more cost and profit efficient when evaluated relative to the
most efficient large banks. Interpreting these results is quite
difficult, however, since large banks derive a greater share of income
from various fee generating activities. The output from these activities
is not measured in the frontier specification used to compute the
estimates in Table 3. As shown by Rogers (1998), cost and profit
efficiency tends to be understated when these activities are not
included as part of bank output. This problem would tend to be more
serious for large banks, implying that the differences between the two
groups (4.2 and 3.1 percent for cost and profit efficiency,
respectively) are understated, and possibly even negative. The frontiers
could be re-estimated allowing for output from fee generating
activities. However, such a specification would not be very helpful
either. Small banks cannot realistically produce large quantities of
this output, and large banks are not likely to expand these activities
greatly by moving into markets with small banks. For this reason,
comparing small banks to large banks would still be problematic. Neither
approach adequately compares small banks to the largest banks. It must
be noted that heterogeneity in the cost and profit function may be due
to more than just differences in size. Differences in product mix,
geographic markets, and organizational form, to name a few, might also
account for differences in X-efficiency. Nevertheless, it does appear
that size may proxy for some of these factors.
Overall, the results indicate that when compared according to
relative X-efficiency, many small banks are viable competitors in the
banking industry. Although small banks may not be as profitable, they
are more efficient with respect to costs. Banks should be able to
continue to compete with larger competitors as geographic restrictions
are relaxed. This outcome supports the predictions mentioned above on
the number of banks after consolidation. While the number of banks will
decline, we will still observe a significant quantity of small banks
after consolidation.
CONCLUSIONS
In the above analysis, cost and profit frontiers were constructed
to provide estimates of efficiency for banks for five different size
classes. Three methods were used to compute these estimates. First, the
National model that uses all banks to construct the frontier was
estimated, resulting in an efficiency score for each bank. Mean
efficiency was then computed for each of the five size classes. Next,
using the Size model, a separate frontier was estimated for each size
class, allowing for the computation of mean efficiency in each size
class from the efficiency score assigned in each individual frontier. In
a specification test, the National model was rejected in favor of the
Size model. Lastly, using the frontiers estimated in the Size model,
efficiency scores were assigned to small banks based on the efficient
frontiers of each of the other four size classes. Under this procedure,
small banks do not dominate the data sample, allowing for a comparison
of small banks to their efficient competitors in larger size classes.
The results of the National and Size model both suggest that small banks
are more cost and profit efficient, on average, than medium and large
banks. When small banks are evaluated using the efficient frontiers of
medium and large banks, small banks are still found more cost efficient,
but are less profit efficient, on average, than medium sized banks.
Overall these results imply that small banks may be more cost efficient,
but not necessarily more profit efficient. This supports predictions
about the post-consolidation composition of the banking industry that
forecast a reduced but still significant presence of small banks. Many
small banks that are relatively more efficient should still survive.
REFERENCES
Akhavein, J. D., A. N. Berger & D. B. Humphrey (1997). The
effects of megamergers on efficiency and prices: Evidence from the
profit function. Review of Industrial Organization, 12, 95-130.
Berger, A. N. (1993). 'Distribution-free' estimates of
efficiency in the U. S. banking industry and tests of the standard
distributional assumptions. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 4, 261-92.
Berger, A. N. & D. B. Humphrey (1992). Megamergers in banking
and the use of cost efficiency as an antitrust defense. Antitrust
Bulletin, 33, 541-600.
Berger, A. N., A. K. Kashyap & J. M. Scalise (1995). The
transformation of the US banking industry: What a long strange trip its
been. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 55-218.
Berger, A. N. & L. J. Mester (1997). Inside the black box: What
explains differences in the efficiencies of financial institutions?
Journal of Banking and Finance, 21, 895-948.
Berger, A. N., A. Saunders, J. M. Scalise & G. F. Udell (1998).
The effects of bank mergers and acquisitions on small business lending.
Journal of Financial Economics, 50, 187-229.
DeYoung, R. (1997). A diagnostic test for the distribution-free
efficiency estimator: An example using U. S. commercial bank data.
European Journal of Operational Research, 98, 243-249.
Hughes, J. P., W. Lang, L. J. Mester & C. Moon (1996).
Efficient banking under interstate branching. Journal of Money, Credit,
and Banking, 28, 1045-1071.
Humphrey, D. B. & L. B. Pulley (1997). Banks' responses to
deregulation: Profits, technology, and efficiency. Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking, 29, 73-93.
Kane, E. J. (1996). De jure interstate banking: Why only now?
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 28, 141-161.
Kaufman, G. G. (1995). The U. S. financial systems: Money, markets,
and institutions. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Mester, L. J. (1997). Measuring efficiency at U. S. banks:
Accounting for heterogeneity is important. European Journal of
Operations Research, 98, 230-242.
Moore, R. R. (1995). Does geographic liberalization really hurt
small banks? Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Financial Industry Studies,
December, 1-12.
Peek, J. & E. S. Rosengren (1998). Bank consolidation and small
business lending: It's not just bank size that matters. Journal of
Banking and Finance, 22, 799-819.
Petersen, M. A. & R. G. Rajan (1994). The benefits of lending
relationships: Evidence from small business data. Journal of Finance,
49, 3-37.
Rogers, K. E. (1998). Nontraditional activities and the efficiency
of U. S. commercial banks. Journal of Banking and Finance, 22, 467-482.
Rose, J. T. & J. D. Wolken (1990). Geographic diversification
in banking, market share changes, and the viability of small independent
banks. Journal of Financial Services Research, 4, 5-20.
Simar, L. (1992). Estimating efficiencies from frontier models with
panel data: A comparison of parametric, non-parametric and
semi-parametric methods with bootstrapping. Journal of Productivity
Analysis, 3, 167-203.
Strahan, P. E. & J. P. Weston (1998). Small business lending
and the changing structure of the banking industry. Journal of Banking
and Finance, 22, 821-845.
Kevin E. Rogers, Mississippi State University
Table 1
Mean Efficiency Cost
(percent)
(1) (2)
Data Sample National Model Size Model
(total assets)
All Banks 73.45 (a) *****
(0.303) *****
0 - $100 m 74.35 (a) 76.33 (a)
(0.309) (0.392)
$100 m - $300 m 72.11 (a) 62.62 (a)
(0.323) (0.686)
$300 m - $500 m 71.67 (a) 65.90 (a)
(0.515) (1.31)
$500 m - $1 b 72.26 (a) 49.50 (a)
(0.645) (1.96)
over $1 b 70.77 (a) 59.65 (a)
(0.516) (0.948)
Mean Efficiency Profit
(percent)
(3) (4)
Data Sample Model National Size Model
(total assets)
All Banks 76.64 (a) *****
(0.0984) *****
0 - $100 m 77.49 (a) 77.55 (a)
(0.100) (0.179)
$100 m - $300 m 76.17 (a) 75.72 (a)
(0.085) (0.445)
$300 m - $500 m 76.34 (a) 76.40 (a)
(0.125) (2.23)
$500 m - $1 b 74.98 (a) 69.40 (a)
(0.143) (3.28)
over $1 b 68.88 (a) 72.43 (a)
(0.124) (2.56)
(a) Significantly different from 100 percent at the 5
percent level, two tailed test.
Table 2: National Model vs. Size Model
Null Hypothesis: The frontier does not vary across size classes.
Year Cost Profit
1991 63.22 33.44
1992 66.54 31.19
1993 88.19 20.64
1994 74.63 22.63
1995 45.48 25.53
1996 17.94 31.85
Note: critical value for F36,8206 .1.62, at a 99 percent
significance level
Table 3
Mean Efficiency Cost
(percent)
(1) (2)
Frontier Sample Small Banks (b) Frontier Banks
All banks 74.35 (a) 73.45 (a)
(0.309) (0.303)
$100 m - $300 m 65.20 (a) 62.62 (a)
(0.683) (0.685)
$ 300 m - $ 500 m 68.78 (a) 65.90 (a)
(0.958) (1.31)
$ 500 m - $1 b 52.66 (a) 49.50 (a)
(1.04) (1.96)
over $1 b 63.84 (a) 59.65 (a)
(0.838) (0.948)
Mean Efficiency Profit
(percent)
(3) (4)
Frontier Sample Small Banks (c) Frontier Banks
All banks 77.49 (a) 76.64 (a)
(0.100) (0.0984)
$100 m - $300 m 77.38 (a) 75.72 (a)
(0.460) (0.445)
$ 300 m - $ 500 m 74.30 (a) 76.40 (a)
(2.26) (2.23)
$ 500 m - $1 b 65.69 (a) 69.40 (a)
(3.29) (3.28)
over $1 b 75.60 (a) 72.43 (a)
(2.63) (2.56)
(a) Significantly different from 100 percent at the 5 percent
level, two tailed test.
(b) For each frontier sample, mean cost efficiency for small
banks is significantly different from mean cost efficiency for
the frontier banks.
(c) For each frontier sample, mean profit efficiency for small
banks is significantly different from mean profit efficiency for
the frontier banks.