首页    期刊浏览 2024年12月01日 星期日
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Average tax rate cyclicality in OECD countries: a test of three fiscal policy theories.
  • 作者:Furceri, Davide ; Karras, Georgios
  • 期刊名称:Southern Economic Journal
  • 印刷版ISSN:0038-4038
  • 出版年度:2011
  • 期号:April
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Southern Economic Association
  • 摘要:Is fiscal policy procyclical? Should it be? The standard Keynesian model implies that fiscal policy should be countercyclical, that is, government spending should increase in economic contractions and fall in expansions, whereas taxes should follow the opposite pattern. At the same time, Tax Smoothing models inspired by Barro (1979) suggest that the government should smooth the tax rate by borrowing in recessions and repaying in booms. In other words, changes in GDP will be positively correlated with tax revenue but should be uncorrelated with tax rates and tax revenue as a percentage of GDP. (1)
  • 关键词:Fiscal policy;Gross domestic product;Tax rates

Average tax rate cyclicality in OECD countries: a test of three fiscal policy theories.


Furceri, Davide ; Karras, Georgios


1. Introduction

Is fiscal policy procyclical? Should it be? The standard Keynesian model implies that fiscal policy should be countercyclical, that is, government spending should increase in economic contractions and fall in expansions, whereas taxes should follow the opposite pattern. At the same time, Tax Smoothing models inspired by Barro (1979) suggest that the government should smooth the tax rate by borrowing in recessions and repaying in booms. In other words, changes in GDP will be positively correlated with tax revenue but should be uncorrelated with tax rates and tax revenue as a percentage of GDP. (1)

The empirical literature has tried to test the main recommendations of both of these normative theories. (2) Focusing on the cyclicality of government expenditure, the basic finding has been that government spending tends to be slightly procyclical in developed countries and strongly procyclical in developing countries. (3)

These findings have been interpreted as suggesting that fiscal policy behavior is not consistent with Keynesian recommendations and only partly consistent (for some developed countries) with the Tax Smoothing hypothesis.

In contrast, both findings appear to be consistent with the political economy theory of fiscal policy recently proposed by Battaglini and Coate (2008). The economic model underlying this theory is a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model in which a single good is produced using labor, whose productivity depends on the business cycle. The political economy component of the model assumes that policy choices in each period are made by a legislature comprising representatives elected by single-member, geographically defined districts. (4)

The main prediction of this theory is that fiscal policy is procyclical. In particular, the model demonstrates that government spending increases in booms and decreases during recessions, whereas tax rates decrease during booms and increase in recessions. In other words, the theory predicts that government spending as share of GDP should be neutral over the cycle and that tax revenue as percentage of GDP should be negatively correlated with changes of GDP. As we have already said, these predictions appear to be broadly consistent with the empirical evidence on government spending, but are they also consistent with the evidence on tax revenue?

The aim of the present article is to contribute to the literature by investigating the relation between tax rates and GDP changes. In particular, we will try to assess whether tax revenues as a share of GDP are positively or negatively correlated with the cyclical component of real GDP. We will test the predictions of Battaglini and Coate's (2008) positive theory and compare them with the normative frameworks of the standard Keynesian model and the Tax Smoothing hypothesis.

To this purpose we compute the correlations between average effective tax rates and cyclical output using a set of 26 OECD countries for which we have data from 1965 to 2003. The results show that the correlations for the great majority of countries are not statistically significantly different from zero. Moreover, to differentiate between different phases of the business cycle, we compute these correlations over expansions (defined as periods with positive cyclical components) and downturns (defined as periods with negative cyclical components). Again, the results uncover almost no statistically significant correlations.

All our findings are robust to the different types of taxes we tried, which include (i) total taxes; (ii) taxes on income, profits, and capital gains; (iii) social security contributions; (iv) taxes on payroll and workforce; (v) taxes on property; (vi) taxes on goods and services; and (vii) other taxes. Moreover, the results are also robust to the use of a panel framework in assessing the relationship between tax rates and changes in the cyclical component of GDP.

Thus, the empirical evidence of our article is largely consistent with the Tax Smoothing hypothesis, whereas it seems to be inconsistent with both the standard Keynesian recommendations and the predictions of the theory proposed by Battaglini and Coate (2008). Taken together with the literature's findings on the cyclical behavior of government spending, our results call for a new theory of fiscal policy that is consistent with the empirical evidence on the behavior of both government spending and revenue (as well as debt) over the cycle.

The rest of the article is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the empirical methodology and the data we use to assess the pattern of tax revenue over the cycle. Section 3 presents and discusses the empirical results, and section 4 concludes.

2. Data and Empirical Methodology

All tax data are from the Revenue Statistics of OECD Member Countries database, and measure various taxes as a percentage of GDP. In particular, we consider the following average effective tax rates: (i) total taxes; (ii) taxes on income, profits, and capital gains; (iii) social security contributions; (iv) taxes on payroll and workforce; (v) taxes on property; (vi) taxes on goods and services; and (vii) other taxes.

Table 1 provides a list of these 26 OECD economies together with country averages over 1965-2003 for the seven tax series. (5) The average total tax rate has varied from 17.2% in Mexico to 46.7% in Sweden. Although these OECD countries have relied very differently on the various forms of taxes, income taxation has been the largest revenue generator for most of them. (6) Taxes on income, profits, and capital gains have ranged from 4.6% of GDP in Mexico to 25.1% of GDP in Denmark. In nine of the countries, most of the revenues were raised by taxes on goods and services. (7) Only in three countries has the largest share been generated by social security taxes, (8) and in none of the countries by property taxes, which are generally the smallest.

As shown in Figure I, total tax rates in these OECD countries have generally increased over time, but with important differences among countries in terms of starting and ending values.

Real GDP data are obtained from the OECD's Economic Outlook database. We consider the same set of 26 countries, for most of which we have data on taxes from 1965 to 2003. (9)

We have tried several methods of obtaining the cyclical components of GDP. First, we use three different filtering techniques to detrend the (log) output series of each country and estimate its cyclical component: (i) the Hodrick-Prescott (HP) filter with a smoothness parameter equal to 100, (ii) the HP filter with a smoothness parameter equal to 6.25, and (iii) a bandpass (BP) filter. These are among the most commonly used detrending methods in the business cycle literature. As an additional measure of cyclical GDP, we also considered data of the output gap from the OECD Economic Outlook (2009). (10) Because our main findings proved quite robust to these different cyclical measures, we will only report results on the basis of the HP-6.25 filter in the next section to preserve space. (11)

In Figure 2, we plot the business cycle component of real GDP obtained using the HP filter with a smoothness parameter equal to 6.25, our benchmark method. Casual inspection of Figure 2 reveals that countries differ substantially in terms of cyclical behavior. This variability, together with that of the tax rates, should facilitate the empirical identification of the relationship between the tax rates and the business cycle.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

To assess the behavior of a tax rate over the cycle, we then compute the correlation between the tax rate and the cyclical component of the corresponding country's GDP,

corr([tax.sup.j.sub.i,t], [gdg.sup.c.sub.i,t]), (1)

where [gdp.sup.c.sub.i,t] is the cyclical component of (log) output for country i at time t, and [tax.sup.j.sub.i,t] is +the tax rate j for country i at time t.

Moreover, to differentiate between different phases of the cycle, we compute these correlations over expansions (defined as times of positive cyclical components) and downturns (defined as times of negative cyclical components).

As a final test, we try to assess how the tax rates respond to cyclical changes in GDP when all countries are considered together. To this purpose, we estimate a simple bivariate relationship between tax rates (tax revenue as percentage of GDP) and cyclical (log) GDP:

[(Tax / GDP).SUB.i.t] = [alpha] + [beta] x [gdg.sup.c.sub.i,t] + [[epsilon].sub.i,t]. (2)

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

In particular, we estimate Equation 2 with the use of ordinary least squares, country fixed effects (FE), country and time FE, and Instrumental Variables (we instrument cyclical GDP with lagged values of our dependent and independent variables).

3. Results

For a preliminary assessment of the behavior of tax revenue over the cycle, we first compute the average total tax rates over the period 1965-2003 in periods of upturns (positive cyclical components of real GDP) and downturns (negative cyclical components of real GDP) and the value of total tax rates at peaks (the highest value of the cyclical component of real GDP) and troughs (the lowest value of the cyclical component of real GDP). The results are reported in Table 2. Looking at the table, it is possible to see that the behavior of the total tax rate over the phases of the cycle differs among countries. In particular, focusing on the first two columns of the table, it emerges that, whereas for 13 of the 26 countries the tax rate is bigger during downturns than during upturns, for the other half of the sample, the tax rate is bigger during upturns. The differences, however, are never sizable. This balanced behavior during cyclical upturns and downturns is confirmed by averaging the tax rate over all countries in the sample: These averages are virtually identical in the two phases of the cycle. (12)

Similarly, focusing on the last two columns of the table, it seems that Battaglini and Coate's (2008) prediction that tax rates decrease during booms and increase in recessions cannot be confirmed. If that prediction were true, we would expect tax rates at peaks to be lower than tax rates at troughs. In fact, for most of the countries (15 of 26) we find the opposite result, and once again those tax rates averaged over countries are virtually the same at peaks and troughs.

Next, as described in the previous section, we move to a more formal assessment of tax cyclicality by computing the correlations between tax rates and the cyclical components of (log) real GDP for each of the 26 OECD countries over the period 1965-2003. The results are reported in Table 3. The table also reports the correlation between tax rates and GDP in cyclical downturns and upturns (columns 2 and 3).

Looking at the first column of Table 3, one can immediately see that, with the exception of the United Kingdom (for which there is a sizable and weakly statistically significant negative correlation), the correlation between tax rates and GDP is slight and not statistically significant. The result is broadly confirmed when we look at the correlation during cyclical downturns and upturns. However, for some countries (such as Greece and Italy) the absence of correlation over the entire cycle is explained by the negative correlation of tax revenue to cyclical upturns and positive correlations over downturns.

These results are robust to the different filtering methods (HP-100 and BP) used to retrieve the cyclical components of real GDP and to the use of the OECD's output gap measure. In fact, looking at Table 4, one can see that the absence of a strong or statistically significant correlation, or both, is confirmed for the great majority of cases. We note that this finding that the tax rate is essentially uncorrelated with cyclical GDP is consistent with the Tax Smoothing hypothesis but inconsistent with both the standard Keynesian recommendation and Battaglini and Coate's (2008) prediction.

So far, our analysis has focused on the total tax rate. We now continue by looking at various types of taxes and their correlation with cyclical GDP. This is more than a robustness exercise: In fact, many of the relevant theories (including Battaglini and Coate 2008) are formulated specifically in terms of income taxes. Thus, it is important to differentiate between different tax rates. In Table 5, we report the correlation between cyclical GDP and (i) taxes on income, profits, and capital gains; (ii) social security contributions; (iii) taxes on payroll and workforce; (iv) taxes on property; (v) taxes on goods and services; and (vi) other taxes.

Starting with the results for income taxes (first column of Table 5), one readily observes that the correlations are not significantly different from zero for all OECD countries in the sample (including the United Kingdom). This result suggests that income tax rates (i.e., income taxes as a percentage of GDP) are neutral over the cycle, contradicting Battaglini and Coate's predictions of a negative correlation. (13) Similar implications can be drawn for all the different tax rates, with the exception of the payroll tax rate for Canada, Denmark, and Ireland and the tax rate on goods and services for Mexico, which are the only cases to show a statistically significant negative correlation with cyclical GDp. (14)

So far, we have been assuming that the correlations between cyclical GDP and tax rates are time-invariant. We now relax this assumption and allow these correlations to vary with time by estimating them for rolling 20-year windows for each country. Figure 3 shows how these time-varying correlations of the total tax rate with cyclical GDP have evolved over time. Two basic results clearly stand out. First, as expected, the results differ substantially among countries, and second, the assumption of time-invariant correlations appears questionable. For some countries (e.g., Australia, Denmark, Finland, Japan, Norway, Spain, and Sweden) the correlation is increasing over time; for other countries (e.g., Austria, Canada, France, Italy, Korea, Turkey, and United States) it fluctuates around values close to zero (or slightly negative), whereas for the rest of the sample (Belgium, Iceland, Ireland, and Luxembourg) it decreases toward sizeable (and statistically significant) negative values.

Again, however, the results suggest that Battaglini and Coate's prediction of a consistently negative correlation between GDP and the tax rate cannot be confirmed by the empirical evidence in most of the countries analyzed.

As a next test, we try to assess how tax rates respond to a cyclical change of GDP when all countries are considered together. For this purpose, we estimate a simple bivariate relationship between tax rates (again defined as tax revenue as a percentage of GDP) and cyclical GDP (Eqn. 2). The results are reported in Table 6, where in each column we present the results obtained with a different estimation method. (15) Analyzing the results, one can observe that although the point estimate of the coefficient measuring the degree of cyclicality of the tax rate is negative, it is never statistically significant in any specification.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

Next, we allow for a richer lag structure to permit the tax rates to respond to cyclical output changes with some delay. To this end, we re-estimate the simple regression of tax rates with one, two, and three lags of cyclical output. (16) The results, reported in Table 7, still point to the absence of a significant relation.

As a final test, we re-estimate tax rates as functions of cyclical GDP and several control variables and interaction terms. In this way, we try to control for possible omission bias, and we assess whether the smoothness of tax rates might depend systematically on structural country characteristics. In particular, the variables included in the analysis are (i) trade openness (measured by the sum of total exports and imports as a fraction of GDP); (ii) country size (measured by the log of total population); (iii) the Gini coefficient for income inequality; and (iv) a political dummy, left, that takes the value of 1 for "left-leaning" governments and equals zero otherwise. (17) These variables are generally thought to be associated with tax revenue as a share of GDP. For example, smaller and more open economies are generally characterized by a larger government size (Alesina and Wacziarg 1998). Left-leaning governments could also be associated with a larger tax-to-GDP share, and countries with higher inequality might have an incentive to increase tax rates for redistribution purposes. The results in Table 8 show that indeed these variables are associated with the share of total tax revenue in GDP; however, they do not affect the response of tax rates to cyclical GDP. In particular, the estimated coefficients suggest that smaller and more open economies tend to have higher tax rates, and that income inequality also raises tax rates. In contrast, the effect of a left-leaning government on taxes is not statistically significant. The inclusion of these variables, both as control and as interaction terms, however, does not affect the estimated response of tax rates to cyclical GDP, so that the absence of a correlation between the tax rates and cyclical GDP is still confirmed.

Our results are also robust to using different tax rates in the panel regressions. Table 9 reports the results of estimating regression (2) separately for each of the six types of taxes we considered above. As the results indicate, the overwhelming majority of these estimates are statistically insignificant. In particular, the coefficients for the income tax, as well as taxes on goods and services, payroll, and property taxes, are never statistically significantly different from zero. In contrast (at least, when we include country fixed effects) social security contributions appear to be negatively related to cyclical changes, whereas "other taxes" are positively associated with them. Thus, this method also seems to confirm a generally neutral behavior of tax rates over the cycle.

4. Conclusions

This article investigated the cyclicality of the average effective tax rate to investigate the validity of three theories of fiscal policy. According to the standard Keynesian theory, tax policy should be countercyclical; that is, tax rates should decrease in economic contractions and increase in expansions. The Tax Smoothing hypothesis instead implies that changes in GDP should be uncorrelated with tax rates. In contrast to these normative theories, a recent positive theory proposed by Battaglini and Coate (2008) predicts that the tax rate will be negatively correlated with GDP. (18)

This article relies on these very different theoretical implications to test the three theories. We compute the correlations between tax revenue as a fraction of GDP and cyclical output for each of 26 OECD countries for which we have data from 1965-2003. The results show that the correlations are generally quite small and statistically indistinguishable from zero.

This finding is quite robust. It is obtained when we look at the relationship between tax rates and cyclical GDP over upturns and downturns or at business cycle peaks and troughs. It is also valid when we look at different tax rates, in addition to total taxes, such as income taxes, social security contributions, payroll taxes, property taxes, taxes on goods and services, and "other" taxes. The results are also robust to assessing the relationship between tax rates and cyclical changes of GDP in a panel framework.

Overall, the empirical evidence of our article seems to be more consistent with the Tax Smoothing hypothesis than either the recommendations of the standard Keynesian model or the predictions of Battaglini and Coate's (2008) theory. This result calls for a new theory of fiscal policy that will be consistent with the empirical evidence on both government spending and government revenue (as well as debt) over the cycle.

Appendix: Filtering Methods

The first two methods use the Hodrick-Prescott (HP) filter proposed by Hodrick and Prescott (1980). The filter decomposes the series into a cyclical ([c.sub.i,t]) and a trend ([g.sub.i,t]) component by minimizing with respect to [g.sub.i,t] for [lambda] > 0, the following quantity:

[T.summation over (t=1)] [([y.sub.i,t] - [g.sub.i-t]).sup.2]+ [lambda] [T-1.summation over (t=2)] [([g.sub.i,t] - [g.sub.i-t]).sup.2]. (A1)

The first method uses the value recommended by Hodrick and Prescott for annual data for the smoothness parameter ([lambda]) equal to 100. The second method sets the smoothness parameter ([lambda]) equal to 6.25. In this way, as pointed out by Ravn and Uhlig (2002), the Hodrick-Prescon filter produces cyclical components comparable to those obtained by the bandpass (BP) filter.

The third method makes use of the BP filter proposed by Baxter and King (1995) and evaluated by Stock and Watson (1998) and Christiano and Fitzgerald (1999), who also compare its properties to those of the HP filter. The low-pass (LP) filter[alpha](L), which forms the basis for the BP filter, selects a finite number of moving average weights [[alpha].sub.h]), to minimize,

Q [[integral].sup.[pi].sub.-[pi]] [|[delta] ([omega]|.sup.2] d[omega], (A2)

where

[alpha](L) = [[summation].sup.K.sub.h=-K] [[alpha].sub.h] [L.sup.h] (A3)

and

[alpha](K)([omega]) = [[summation].sup.K.sub.h=-K] [[alpha].sub.h] [e.sup.-I [omega]h] (A3) (A4)

The LP filter uses [[alpha].sub.k]([omega]) to approximate the infinite MA filter [beta][omega]. Let's define [delta]([omega]) [equivalent to] [beta]([omega]) - a[omega]. Then, minimizing Q, we minimize the discrepancy between the ideal LP filter [beta]([omega]) and its finite representation [[alpha].sub.K][omega] at frequency [omega]. The main objective of the BP filter as implemented by Baxter and King (1995) is to remove both the high-frequency and low- frequency component of a series, leaving the business cycle frequencies. This is obtained by subtracting the weights of two LP filters. We define[[omega].sub.L]. and[[omega].sub.H], the lower and upper frequencies of two LP filters as 8 and 2, respectively, for annual data. We therefore remove all fluctuations shorter than two or longer than eight years. The frequency representation of the BP weights becomes [[alpha].sub.K] ([[omega].sub.H]) - [[alpha].sub.K]([[omega].sub.H]) and forms the basis of the Baxter-King filter which provides an alternative estimate of the trend and the cyclical component.

References

Alesina, A., F. Campante, and G. Tabellini. 2008. Why is fiscal policy often procyclical? Journal of the European Economics Association 6:1006-36.

Alesina, A., and R. Wacziarg. 1998. Openness, country size and government. Journal of Public Economics 69:305-21.

Barro, R. J. 1979. On the determination of the public debt. Journal of Political Economy 87:940-71.

Battaglini, M., and S. Coate. 2008. Fiscal policy over the real business cycle: A positive theory. NBER Working Paper No. 14047.

Baxter, M., and R. King. 1995. Measuring business cycles: Approximate band-pass filters for economic time series. NBER Working Paper No. 5022.

Beffy, P. O., P. Ollivaud, P. Richardson, and F. Sedillot. 2006. New OECD methods for supply-side and medium-term assessments: A capital services approach. OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 482.

Catao, L., and B. Sutton. 2002. Sovereign defaults: The role of volatility. International Monetary Fund Working Paper 02/149.

Christiano, L., and T. Fitzgerald. 1999. The band pass filter. NBER Working Paper No. 7257.

Gavin. M., and R. Perotti. 1997. Fiscal policy in Latin America. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 12:11-71.

Hodrick, R., and E. Prescott. 1980. Postwar U.S. business cycles: An empirical investigation. Discussion paper 451, Carnegie Mellon University.

Ilzetzki, E., and C. Vegh. 2008. Procyclical fiscal policy in developing countries: Truth or fiction? NBER Working Paper No. 14191.

Kaminsky, G., C. Reinhart, and C. Vegh. 2004. When it rains, it pours: Procyclical capital flows and macroeconomic policies. NBER Working Paper No. 10780.

Lane, P. 2003. The cyclical behaviour of fiscal policy: Evidence from the OECD. Journal of Public Economics 87:2261-675.

Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development (OECD). Revenue statistics of OECD member countries database. OECD. Economic outlook database.

Persson, T. 2001. Do political institutions shape economic policy'? NBER Working Paper No. 8214.

Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. 2001. Political institutions and policy outcomes: What are the stylized facts? CEPR Discussion Paper No. 2872.

Ravn, M. O., and H. Uhlig. 2002. On adjusting the Hodrick-Prescott filter for the frequency of observations. The Review of Economics and Statistics 84:371-5.

Romer, David. 2006. Advanced Macroeconomics. 3rd edition. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Sorensen, B., L. Wu, and O. Yosha. 2001. Output fluctuations and fiscal policy: U.S. state and local governments 1978- 1994. European Economic Review 45:1271-310.

Stock, J., and M. Watson. 1998. Business cycle fluctuations in U.S. macroeconomic time series. NBER Working Paper No. 6528.

Talvi, E., and C. Vegh. 2005. Tax base variability and procyclical fiscal policy. Journal of Economic Development 78:156-90.

(1) Versions of the theory also predict that changes in GDP should be uncorrelated with government spending but negatively correlated with government spending as a proportion of GDP and that debt will be increasing in booms and decreasing in the recessions (i.e., debt is positively correlated with changes in GDP). For an example of the "traditional" Keynesian theory, see Romer (2006, chapter 5). For an exposition of the Tax Smoothing hypothesis in terms of the average effective tax rate, see Romer (2006, chapter 11).

(2) See. for example, Gavin and Perotti (1997); Sorensen, Wu, and Yosha (2001); Lane (2003); Talvi and Vegh (2005); Alesina, Campante, and Tabellini (2008): and Ilzetzki and Vegh (2008).

(3) A possible explanation can be found in the literature of credit supply. In fact, as argued by Catao and Sutton (2002) and Kaminsky, Reinhart, and Vegh (2004), developing countries become credit constrained during economic downturns or can borrow only at very high interest rates. This precludes governments from effectively smoothing economic fluctuations. As a result, government expenditure increases during good times and decreases during bad times (i.e., fiscal policies become procyclical). Another explanation to account for different behavior of fiscal policy is political factors. Persson (2001), Persson and Tabellini (2001), and Alesina, Campante, and Tabellini (2008) find that political and institutional variables also matter for fiscal responsiveness. In particular, Alesina, Campante, and Tabellini (2008) show that most of the procyclicality of fiscal policy in developing countries can be explained by high levels of corruption in those countries. The authors build a model wherein a high degree of corruption means that surpluses accumulated in good times when fiscal policy is countercyclical are not optimal because the electorate knows that corrupt political representation would misappropriate them. It is then rational for the electorate to demand higher spending during expansions (i.e., procyclical fiscal policy).

(4) The model assumes that the government can raise revenues in two ways (via a proportional tax on labor income and by issuing one-period risk-free bonds) and that public revenues are used to finance the provision of public goods. The level of public debt and the persistent level of productivity are the state variables, creating a dynamic linkage across policymaking periods.

(5) Country selection is dictated by data availability only.

(6) To be specific, for 14 countries out of the 26: Australia, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, Japan, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States.

(7) The nine are Austria, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Korea, Mexico, Portugal, Spain, and Turkey.

(8) These three are France, Germany, and Italy.

(9) The exceptions are Iceland (1980-2003), Korea (1972-2003), and Mexico (1980-2003).

(10) See Beffy et al. (2006) for details.

(11) We provide a more detailed discussion of these filtering methods and their properties in the Appendix. We have also preferred the HP-6.25 filter to simple differencing because the HP produces a cyclical component that has a long-run average value of zero. This is a desirable property for a cyclical component, but it is strongly violated by output growth rates.

(12) Similar results are obtained for different tax rates. They are available upon request.

(13) In fact, for the majority of countries, the point estimates of these correlations of cyclical GDP with the income tax rate are positive. It is tempting to observe that this positive sign (although definitely the wrong sign for the Battaglini and Coate prediction) is consistent with the standard Keynesian recommendation, whereas the lack of statistical significance is consistent with the Tax Smoothing hypothesis.

(14) Unlike the results for the income tax, the preponderance of the point estimates of the correlations of cyclical GDP with social security contributions and taxes on goods and services are negative. This sign (although not the lack of statistical significance) is consistent with the Battaglini and Coate (2008) prediction.

(15) We consider as instruments two lags of the cyclical GDP. The Anderson statistics, the Cragg Donald Wald statistics, and the Sargan test of overidentification restrictions suggest that the choice of the instruments is appropriate. For simplicity, we report only the Sargan test's p value in Table 6. Additional results are available from the authors upon request.

(16) We are grateful to an anonymous referee for suggesting this extension, as well as the one outlined in the next paragraph.

(17) Data for trade openness and populations are taken from the OECD Economic Outlook (2009), data for Gini coefficients are from the OECD Main Economic Indicators (2009), and data for left governments are from the Database of Political Institutions political database.

(18) It might be helpful to remind the reader that our locus has been on average effective tax rates (tax-to-GDP ratios) rather than marginal tax rates. Although the latter is the relevant variable for many important economic issues (e.g., the effects of taxes on labor supply or long-run economic growth), our focus here has been on the cyclical properties of aggregate tax revenue, for which the former is appropriate.

Davide Furceri, OECD, 2 rue Andre Pascal. 75775 Paris Cedex 16: E-mail davide.furceri@oecd.org: furceri.economia@ unipa.it.

Georgios Karras, University of Illinois at Chicago. Department of Economics, 601 South Morgan Street, Chicago, IL 60607, USA: E-mail gkarras@uic.edu; corresponding author.

This work has been carried out while Davide Furceri was working as an economist at the Fiscal Policy division of the European Central Bank (ECB). Tile opinions expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB or the Eurosystem, the OECD, or its member countries.

Received September 2009: accepted May 2010.
Table 1. Average Tax Rates (% of GDP, Averaged over the Period
1965-2003)

                                   Income,
                    Total         Profits,         Social
Country              Tax        Capital Gains     Security

Australia            27.1           15.0             --
Austria              26.4           10.6            12.3
Belgium              41.9           15.9            13.0
Canada               32.8           14.9             4.0
Denmark              44.4           25.2             1.4
Finland              40.0           16.2             8.8
France               40.4            7.2            16.3
Germany              36.1           11.8            12.8
Greece               27.7            5.1             8.7
Iceland              32.2           10.0             1.9
Ireland              31.6           11.0             4.1
Italy                34.2           10.6            11.7
Japan                24.6           10.6             7.5
Korea                17.9            5.1             1.3
Luxembourg           38.1           15.3            10.5
Mexico               17.3            4.6             2.5
Netherlands          41.0           12.5            15.8
New Zealand          31.6           19.7             --
Norway               40.3           15.4             8.9
Portugal             26.1            6.3             7.3
Spain                26.3            7.0            10.2
Sweden               46.7           20.4            11.4
Switzerland          26.4           11.4             6.9
Turkey               19.5            6.9             2.8
United Kingdom       35.3           13.7             6.0
United States        26.6           12.6             5.9
Average              32.7           12.2             8.5

                                            Goods and
Country            Payroll      Property     Services      Others

Australia             1.5         2.5           8.2          --
Austria               2.7         1.0          12.8          0.4
Belgium               --          1.1          11.8          --
Canada                0.7         3.4           9.8          0.3
Denmark               0.3         2.1          15.6          0.1
Finland               0.9         1.0          13.5          0.1
France                0.9         2.4          12.3          1.3
Germany               0.2         1.3          10.1          --
Greece                0.3         1.8          12.0          --
Iceland               0.9         2.4          17.0          0.7
Ireland               0.5         2.2          14.0          --
Italy                 0.2         1.5          10.0          1.9
Japan                 --          2.4           4.3          0.1
Korea                 0.1         2.0           9.0          0.5
Luxembourg            0.3         2.7           9.3          0.1
Mexico                0.2         0.3           9.5          0.2
Netherlands           --          1.5          11.0          0.1
New Zealand           0.4         2.3           9.3           -
Norway                --          1.0          15.0          0.2
Portugal              0.4         0.8          11.1          0.4
Spain                 0.2         1.4           7.5          0.2
Sweden                1.6         1.1          12.2          0.1
Switzerland           --          2.2           5.9          --
Turkey                --          1.0           7.3          2.4
United Kingdom        --          4.3          10.8          1.0
United States         --          3.3           4.9          --
Average               0.8         1.9          10.6          0.5

Table 2. Total Taxes over the Cycle (%, Averaged over the Period 1965-
2003)

Country           Downturns     Upturns       Peaks       Troughs

Australia            26.4         27.8         29.4         27.2
Austria              27.0         25.7         30.5         27.0
Belgium              42.0         41.8         37.9         40.6
Canada               33.2         32.4         34.8         33.1
Denmark              43.7         45.8         41.1         40.0
Finland              41.4         38.5         43.0         44.9
France               41.7         39.3         43.0         35.9
Germany              36.5         35.7         36.8         32.2
Greece               28.1         27.4         20.3         21.3
Iceland              31.7         32.7         29.7         28.3
Ireland              31.9         31.3         33.5         26.9
Italy                34.5         33.9         25.7         26.1
Japan                23.5         26.0         22.3         18.2
Korea                17.9         17.9         16.6         21.1
Luxembourg           37.9         38.4         31.4         42.4
Mexico               17.4         17.2         15.7         16.7
Netherlands          41.3         40.9         41.2         41.3
New Zealand          31.1         32.0         30.4         23.2
Norway               40.0         40.7         42.5         43.5
Portugal             25.1         27.0         18.4         20.8
Spain                25.6         27.3         17.5         16.5
Sweden               46.1         47.4         38.5         46.9
Switzerland          26.8         25.9         25.0         28.5
Turkey               20.3         18.7         28.4         35.1
United Kingdom       35.6         34.9         31.4         34.4
United States        26.7         26.6         25.5         27
Average              32.0         32.0         30.4         30.8

Table 3. Correlations between Total Tax Rates and Cyclical Output
(1965-2003)

Country          Overall   Downturns    Upturns

Australia         0.10     -0.04       -0.19
Austria          -0.01      0.41        0.30
Belgium          -0.09      0.00       -0.31
Canada           -0.11     -0.19        0.16
Denmark           0.09      0.10       -0.31
Finland          -0.05      0.23        0.27
France           -0.06      0.27        0.32
Germany           0.06      0.66 ***    0.16
Greece           -0.10      0.45 **    -0.57 ***
Iceland           0.10      0.36       -0.38
Ireland          -0.14     -0.20        0.00
Italy             0.01      0.48 **    -0.47 **
Japan             0.17      0.10       -0.44 **
Korea             0.06      0.03        0.22
Luxembourg       -0.13     -0.02       -0.57 ***
Mexico           -0.13      0.32       -0.40
Netherlands      -0.08     -0.06       -0.06
New Zealand       0.03      0.30       -0.30
Norway            0.02     -0.27        0.10
Portugal          0.02      0.01       -0.33
Spain             0.08      0.09       -0.14
Sweden            0.09      0.07       -0.13
Switzerland      -0.16      0.07       -0.19
Turkey           -0.08     -0.39 *      0.51 **
United Kingdom   -0.27 *    0.02       -0.35
United States     0.04      0.37       -0.10
Average          -0.01      0.09       -0.08

*, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5% and 1%,
respectively.

Table 4. Correlations between Total Tax Rates and Output Business
Cycle (1965-2003)

Country          HP6.25    HP100     BP (a)    Output GAP

Australia         0.10      0.09   -0.03       -0.04
Austria          -0.01     -0.05   -0.08       -0.31
Belgium          -0.09     -0.13   -0.25       -0.48 ***
Canada           -0.11     -0.05   -0.18       -0.20
Denmark           0.09      0.08   -0.06        0.18
Finland          -0.05     -0.06   -0.14       -0.09
France           -0.06     -0.07   -0.26       -0.31
Germany           0.06      0.08    0.06        0.00
Greece           -0.10     -0.09   -0.27       -0.35 *
Iceland           0.10      0.26    0.14        0.07
Ireland          -0.14     -0.20   -0.46 ***   -0.73 ***
Italy             0.01     -0.05   -0.22       -0.46 **
Japan             0.17      0.05   -0.17        0.24
Korea             0.06     -0.05   -0.20       -0.10
Luxembourg       -0.13     -0.16   -0.29       -0.61 ***
Mexico           -0.13     -0.12   -0.29        0.31
Netherlands      -0.08     -0.05   -0.33 *     -0.34 **
New Zealand       0.03      0.09    0.16       -0.41 **
Norway            0.02      0.09    0.26        0.50
Portugal          0.02      0.03   -0.10        0.30
Spain             0.08      0.02   -0.20        0.63 ***
Sweden            0.09      0.08   -0.07        0.05
Switzerland      -0.16     -0.18   -0.44 ***   -0.26
Turkey           -0.08     -0.01    0.09       -0.16
United Kingdom   -0.27 *   -0.25   -0.40 **    -0.27
United States     0.04      0.09    0.00        0.06
Average          -0.01      0.09   -0.08       -0.11

*, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%,
5% and 1%, respectively.

(a) BP correlations are based on fewer observations (6).

Table 5. Correlations between Various Tax Rates and Output Business
Cycle (1965-2003)

                Income, Profits,
Country          Capital Gains     Social Security    Payroll

Australia             0.16               --           0.02
Austria               0.05              -0.05        -0.05
Belgium              -0.04              -0.07           --
Canada                0.00              -0.13        -0.64 ***
Denmark               0.02               0.06        -0.29 **
Finland               0.11              -0.10        -0.18
France                0.12              -0.08        -0.26
Germany               0.06               0.00        -0.22
Greece               -0.07              -0.11         0.00
Iceland               0.04              -0.10        -0.02
Ireland              -0.02               0.01        -0.45 **
Italy                 0.03              -0.03         0.07
Japan                 0.31               0.01           --
Korea                 0.07              -0.03           --
Luxembourg           -0.11              -0.24        -0.12
Mexico                0.37               0.10         0.29
Netherlands           0.02              -0.18           --
New Zealand           0.13               --          -0.27
Norway                0.05              -0.03           --
Portugal              0.09               0.01        -0.19
Spain                 0.11               0.05           --
Sweden                0.30               0.00         0.03
Switzerland          -0.15              -0.15           --
Turkey               -0.03              -0.17           --
United
  Kingdom            -0.17              -0.07           --
United States         0.22              -0.12           --
Average               0.06              -0.06        -0.07

                           Goods and
Country         Property   Services    Other

Australia        -0.01     -0.02         --
Austria          -0.03     -0.10        0.12
Belgium           0.06     -0.30         --
Canada           -0.26     -0.07       -0.23
Denmark           0.09      0.34         --
Finland           0.04     -0.6          --
France           -0.06     -0.11       -0.10
Germany          -0.08      0.18         --
Greece           -0.03     -0.12         --
Iceland           0.00      0.22        0.02
Ireland          -0.11     -0.22         --
Italy            -0.15      0.04        0.37
Japan            -0.02     -0.04         --
Korea             0.08      0.15       -0.03
Luxembourg        0.13     -0.12         --
Mexico            0.36     -0.40 **    -0.20
Netherlands       0.16      0.06        0.02
New Zealand       0.08     -0.07         --
Norway           -0.10      0.15        0.27
Portugal          0.14     -0.03       -0.06
Spain             0.20      0.06       -0.15
Sweden            0.10     -0.09       -0.06
Switzerland      -0.03     -0.09         --
Turkey           -0.16     -0.09        0.33
United
  Kingdom         0.03     -0.17       -0.22
United States    -0.02     -0.13         --
Average           0.02     -0.05        0.01

*, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5% and 1%,
respectively.

Table 6. Response of Tax Rates to Output Business Cycle (1965-2003)

                                                   Country and Time
                            OLS       Country FE          FE

Degree of cyclicality (R)    -4.21     -4.51             -6.32
                            (-0.23)   (-0.79)           (-1.04)
Number of observations      976       976               976
[R.sup.2]                     0.00      0.00              0.13
Sargan statistic p-value

                              IV

Degree of cyclicality (R)   -26.15
                            (-0.42)
Number of observations      947
[R.sup.2]                    --
Sargan statistic p-value      0.84

t-statistics in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical
significance at 10%, 5%n and 1%, respectively.

Table 7. Response of Tax Rates to Output Business Cycle
(1965-2003)--Ordinary Least Squares

                                 [gdp.sup.c.sub.i.t-1]

Degree of cyclicality ([beta])           5.76
                                        (0.32)

                                 [gdp.sup.c.sub.i.t-2]

Degree of cyclicality ([beta])           5.61
                                        (0.31)

                                 [gdp.sup.c.sub.i.t-3]

Degree of cyclicality ([beta])          10.559
                                        (0.52)

t-statistics in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical
significance at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively.

Table 8. Response of Different Tax Rates to Output Business Cycle
(1965-2003)

                                      I            II

Degree of cyclicality ([beta])    -6.16         -6.01
                                 (-0.39)       (-0.35)
Openness                           8.14            --
                                 (19.36) ***       --
Openness*Cyclical output         -15.83            --
                                 (-0.60)           --
Population                           --         -1.67
                                     --        (-9.37) ***
Population*Cyclical output           --          0.22
                                     --         (0.02)
Gini                                 --            --
                                     --            --
Gini*Cyclical output                 --            --
                                     --            --
Left government                      --            --
                                     --            --
Left gov.*Cyclical output            --            --

Number of observations           949           975
[R.sup.2]                          0.28          0.08

                                     III          IV

Degree of cyclicality ([beta])    -1.02        -28.07
                                 (-0.05)       (-1.00)
Openness                             --            --
                                     --            --
Openness*Cyclical output             --            --
                                     --            --
Population                           --            --
                                     --            --
Population*Cyclical output           --            --
                                     --            --
Gini                              31.56            --
                                  (5.71) ***       --
Gini*Cyclical output             -97.29            --
                                 (-0.27)           --
Left government                      --         -0.167
                                               (-0.24)
Left gov.*Cyclical output            --         86.21
                                                (1.80) *
Number of observations           835           634
[R.sup.2]                          0.04          0.01

t-statistics in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical
significance at 1O%, 5% and 1%, respectively.

Table 9. Response of Different Tax Rates to Output Business Cycle
(1965-2003)

                    OLS     Country FE   Country and Time FE     IV

Income tax          5.63      5.22             1.75              0.97
                   (0.51)    (1.13)           (0.44)            (0.03)
Social security    -6.14     -7.09            -6.92            -24.48
                  (-0.41)   (-1.66) *        (-2.32) **        (-0.81)
Payroll            -1.40     -1.09            -0.39              2.98
                  (-0.58)   (-1.19)          (-0.36)            (0.29)
Property           -0.65      0.10             0.42             -1.05
                  (-0.08)     0.09             0.36            (-0.14)
Goods and          -3.69     -3.81            -2.79             -1.48
 services         (-0.55)   (-1.36)          (-0.98)           (-0.06)
Others              0.69      2.30             2.72              1.77
                   (0.35)    (2.11) **        (2.23) **         (0.24)

t-statistics in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical
significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有