首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月15日 星期五
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:An experimental investigation of trust and sequential trade.
  • 作者:Deck, Cary A.
  • 期刊名称:Southern Economic Journal
  • 印刷版ISSN:0038-4038
  • 出版年度:2010
  • 期号:April
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Southern Economic Association
  • 摘要:To study a complex phenomenon, economists often reduce it to a tractable abstract problem. For example, the trust game of McCabe and Smith (2000) is a model of sequential trade with no external contract enforcement as described by Coricelli, McCabe, and Smith (2000). In the standard trust game, the first mover can decide to either end the game with both parties receiving $10 or continue the game with the total payoff increased to $40. If the first mover does not end the game, the second mover can decide to either keep the entire $40 or keep $25 and return $15 to the first mover. The first mover can be viewed as a stylized seller who incurs a $10 cost to provide an item valued by the buyer at $30 in exchange for a $15 payment.
  • 关键词:Commerce;Cooperation;Cooperation (Economics)

An experimental investigation of trust and sequential trade.


Deck, Cary A.


1. Introduction

To study a complex phenomenon, economists often reduce it to a tractable abstract problem. For example, the trust game of McCabe and Smith (2000) is a model of sequential trade with no external contract enforcement as described by Coricelli, McCabe, and Smith (2000). In the standard trust game, the first mover can decide to either end the game with both parties receiving $10 or continue the game with the total payoff increased to $40. If the first mover does not end the game, the second mover can decide to either keep the entire $40 or keep $25 and return $15 to the first mover. The first mover can be viewed as a stylized seller who incurs a $10 cost to provide an item valued by the buyer at $30 in exchange for a $15 payment.

The voluntary trade is mutually welfare improving, but it requires the first party to forego something of value and risk not having the transaction completed; thus the first mover must trust that the second mover is trustworthy. (1) Behavior in the trust game is fairly robust; Cox and Deck (2005) and Gillies and Rigdon (2008) replicate the results of McCabe and Smith (2000). Approximately half of the first movers trust and about two-thirds of the second movers are trustworthy. However, second-mover behavior is sensitive to the level of social distance. Cox and Deck (2005) report a reversal of second-mover behavior when the experimenters could not identify who took what action using a double-blind protocol.

What does behavior in the trust game say about behavior in naturally occurring trading opportunities? A comparison of the well-understood simplified version of the game and the original problem of interest identifies additional complicating features appropriate for further investigation in an attempt to answer this question. The trust game differs from naturally occurring trades in several ways. When people consider a trade, they weigh the gain from a successful trade against the loss from an unsuccessful one. (2) The price determines the size of the potential gain and loss. In the naturally occurring economy, prices are formed through some endogenous process; yet prices are exogenously fixed by the experimenter in the trust game. In the laboratory, payoff information is usually public; whereas in practice a seller does not know the willingness to pay of the buyer, nor does the buyer know the seller's cost. Experiments by McCabe, Rassenti, and Smith (1998) and Gillies and Rigdon (2008) demonstrate that the effect of payoff privacy is behavior more consistent with the traditional self-interested model than what is typically observed with public information. Further, previous trust game experiments have been intentionally abstract. Eckel and Grossman (1996) argue "...that social and psychological factors affect economic decision making, and the importance of social factors can only be introduced by abandoning, at least to some extent, abstraction" (p. 189). Direct evidence of the effect of a buyer-seller framing in the related ultimatum game is mixed (see Hoffman et al. 1994; Cox and Deck 2005). (3)

This article moves towards a more complete story of sequential trade by imbedding endogenously determined variations of the trust game into a richer experimental environment with payoff privacy and buyer-seller framing. The next section details the experimental design and a separate section presents the behavioral results, which differ from previous work. A fourth section explores which factors cause the behavioral shift and a final section concludes.

2. Experimental Design and Procedures

The experiments involve variations of the trust game and a related game where the order of play is reversed. In the standard trust game, the second-mover buyer providing payment makes a one for one transfer to the first-mover seller. When the order is reversed so that the buyer initiates trade, then the second-mover seller makes a one for three transfer to the first mover. The difference is that surplus is generated when the good is exchanged, but not when the payment is made. (4) Figure 1 describes the seller-first trust game (left panel) and the buyer-first modified trust game (right panel) in terms of endowments of the buyer and seller ([E.sub.B] and [E.sub.s], respectively), value to the buyer (V), cost to the seller (C), and the price (P). In the experiments, the induced value of the good was V = $15, and the induced cost of producing and "shipping" the good was C = $5. The buyer was endowed with [E.sub.B] = $15, and the seller was endowed with [E.sub.s] = $10. (5) As was explained to the subjects, all amounts are in U.S. dollars.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

The experiment was framed as an opportunity for a buyer and seller to trade. The directions used the terms buyer, seller, value, cost, price, and so on. (6) The trust game was presented in extensive form with the branches labeled "Pay" and "Not Pay" for the buyer and "Ship" and "Not Ship" for the seller. Figure 2 shows an example screen for a buyer who is moving second. Payoff information was private. That is, a buyer knew her own endowment and value but not the endowment or cost of the seller. (7) Similarly, a seller knew his cost and endowment but not the buyer's value and endowment. As shown in Figure 2, buyers observed E and C, denoting the seller's endowment and cost. The buyer knew that her failure to pay resulted in the seller earning E - C while payment resulted in the seller receiving E - C + the price.

Previous trust game experiments have assumed a fixed price. In the current experiments, prices were determined through a bargaining process. Subjects were randomly matched with someone in the opposing role and had five minutes to negotiate a price. During the bargaining process, subjects could adjust the game displayed on their screen to reflect any price between 0 and 25. Figure 2 shows the decision tree for a price of P = 5. There was no imposed order of offers, nor was there an improvement rule, but sellers could not suggest a price below the current price proposed by the buyer, nor could a buyer suggest a price above the current price proposed by the seller. Prices were required to be whole dollar amounts, and a no bankruptcy condition was imposed. Sellers could not post or agree to a price below C = $5, and buyers could not post or accept a price above V = $15, but this was private information. A contract was only reached when one party accepted the price put forward by the other party. If time expired without a contract being reached, both subjects received their respective endowments.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

A price agreement depends upon the first mover's beliefs that the trade will be completed at that price as well as the potential payoffs associated with the price. If first movers anticipate that second movers are more likely to complete trades where the price favors the second mover, then first movers find themselves in a situation similar to a first price auction; one could ask for a larger but less likely payoff or one that is smaller and more likely. Such a belief is commonly expressed by the old adage that "if a deal looks too good to be true, then it probably is." At the same time, the second mover must agree to the negotiated price as well, and thus the price reflects the second mover's distributive preferences and intended action. A second mover that plans to defect would be willing to agree to any price but would want to act like a well-intentioned second mover so as not to arouse the suspicion of the first mover. Given the exploratory nature of this work, no formal prediction is made with respect to the prices that are likely to emerge.

Even without price predictions, one can hypothesize how price will impact behavior in the endogenously formed trust game conditional on price. Consider a second-mover buyer's decision to make a payment. Cox and Deck (2005) find that second-mover cooperation is higher when the stakes are lower. Thus, a buyer may be more likely to send a $6 payment than a $14 payment once the good is received. More generally, one would expect that the lower the agreed-upon price, the more likely a second-mover buyer is to send payment. It would also seem reasonable that the larger the payment that has been received, the more willing a second-mover seller may be to forgo $C due to reciprocal motivations or increased social indebtedness.

Based upon previous research, one would expect that second-mover sellers are more likely to complete initiated trades than are second-mover buyers. Andreoni and Vesterlund (2001) and Andreoni and Miller (2002) study dictator games where $1 given up by the dictator results in the recipient receiving $[alpha], where the conversion rate [alpha] varies between 1/3 and 3. They find that dictators give more as [alpha] increases. By making the payment, a second-mover buyer increases the seller's payoff by SP, exactly the amount that the buyer forgoes. On the other hand, second-mover sellers give up $C to transfer $V to the buyer. As long as the trade is strictly mutually beneficial, it must be that $V > $P > $C. Hence a seller knows that each foregone dollar generates more than one dollar for the buyer. In Deck (2009) the conversion rate, [alpha] = V/C = 3, was known, and sellers were found to be more likely to complete a trade. This pattern may explain why buyers move first in many trades, as denoted by the common expression: "Sorry, no CODs." In the current study, a seller only knows [alpha] = V/C > 1, and thus, this study provides a robustness test of the relationship between generosity and the conversion rate as previous studies have found that payoff privacy leads to more self-interested behavior and may therefore mitigate the conversion rate effect.

The rate of trust by first movers is approximately 50% in the standard trust game. Payoff privacy encourages self-interested behavior, while the negotiated prices might encourage trust since the first mover has already agreed to the price before acting. The buyer-seller framework may encourage trust since defection is explicitly reneging on an agreement. There is no a priori basis for predicting the relative influence of these factors, and no explicit predictions are made, reflecting the exploratory nature of this work.

The experiments were conducted at a state university, and subjects were drawn from the population of business school undergraduates. For each of the 12 sessions, groups of between 8 and 12 subjects entered the laboratory and were allowed to sit at any active computer station. (8) Subjects participated in a single session and had not participated in any related experiments. The computer stations were separated by privacy dividers so that no one could see any other subject or any other active computer screen. Subjects read role--and order-specific directions. After all subjects had completed the directions and were given the opportunity to ask questions, additional directions explaining the double-blind payoff procedures were distributed. The subjects drew sealed envelopes containing mailbox keys with which they would anonymously collect their cash earned at the conclusion of the experiment. Once the experimenters left the room, subjects opened their envelopes and entered the identification codes on the mailbox keys in their computers. (9) After all codes were entered, the experiment began. When the payoffs were determined, money was placed in envelopes, which were in turn placed in mailboxes. Subjects were allowed to collect their earnings outside the view of the experimenter and then leave.

Sessions lasted approximately 20 minutes, although subjects were recruited for half-hour sessions. As was made explicit in the directions, subjects went through this process once, in only one role and one order. Failure to trade did not result in another opportunity to trade with the same or another party.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

3. Experimental Results

A total of 62 subject pairs completed the experiment; 31 pairs per trading order. Of these 62 pairs, 23% completed a mutually beneficial trade. The overall rate of trade success did not differ by order based upon a two-sample proportions test with a null hypothesis of equality against the two-sided alternative (p = 0.224). Figure 3 shows the frequency of each outcome by treatment pooling across prices.

In this experiment, a subject pair could fail to make a successful trade for three reasons: The second mover may not complete an initiated trade, the first mover may decide to not initiate a trade, and the parties may not be able to agree upon a price. This third reason is not present in the typical trust game and accounted for 16% of the total pairs in the experiment. Four pairs failed to reach a price agreement when the seller moved first, and six pairs failed to reach an agreement when the buyer moved first, a difference that is not significant based upon a two-sample proportions test of equal proportions against the two-sided null (p = 0.490). It is interesting to note that 79% of the observed agreements occurred as the result of the second mover accepting the first mover's price. (10) This proportion is larger than would be expected to occur randomly (p < 0.001) and is intuitive since the first mover bears all of the risk.

The majority of trade failures were where the second mover failed to complete the transaction. Of the second-mover buyers who received the item, only 38% (9 of 9 + 15) subsequently sent payment. For second-mover sellers who received payment, only 29% (5 of 5 + 12) went ahead and shipped the item. Second-mover behavior did not vary with trading order (p = 0.591 for the test of equal proportions against the one-sided alternative that sellers were more likely to complete a trade). The nominal pattern of sellers being less trustworthy contradicts previous research by Andreoni and Vesterlund (2001), Andreoni and Miller (2002), and Deck (2009). However, the general pattern that less than half of second movers are trustworthy is similar to what has been reported previously (Cox and Deck 2005; Gillies and Rigdon 2008; and Deck 2009).

First movers were considerably more likely to trust their counterpart and initiate a trade as compared with previously reported results. Of the first-mover sellers who reached a price agreement, 89% (15 + 9 of 15 + 9 + 3) shipped the item. Of the first-mover buyers who reached a price agreement, 68% (12 + 5 of 12 + 5 + 8) sent the payment. For comparison, these numbers were 56% and 35% for first-mover sellers and buyers, respectively, in Deck (2009). More than half of the subjects exhibit trust (p < 0.001, = 0.071 for first-mover sellers and buyers, respectively). The differences in percentages in the current study and those reported in Deck (2009) are highly significant (p = 0.002 and 0.004 for first-mover sellers and buyers, respectively). (11) Here order has a significant impact on trust; sellers were more likely to initiate trade (p = 0.065). Given that the price could not be less than C = $5, first-mover sellers risked a smaller loss than did first-mover buyers, which could explain this result. As discussed above, first movers overwhelmingly set the price determining the risk and reward from exchange. First movers who set the price are nominally, but not statistically, more likely to trust the second mover. The probability that a first mover will trust is 79% when the first mover sets the price and 67% when the first mover accepts a price set by the second mover (p = 0.421 in the two-sided two-sample proportions test).

Figure 4 shows the behavior observed during the experiment for both orderings at the negotiated prices. The average agreed-upon price is $10.78 when the seller moves first, and it is $11.36 when the buyer moves first. This difference is not significant (t-statistic = 0.656). For comparison, the original trust game provides 75% of the gain to the second-mover buyer, which translates to a price of $7.50 in this context. A price of $10 would split the gains evenly regardless of order. While prices were higher than the equal split level in both conditions, the difference is not dramatic in economic terms. For first-mover buyers who actually sent their payment, the average agreed-upon price was $10.41, and for first-mover sellers who actually shipped the good it was $11.29. This difference remains insignificant (t-statistic = -0.940).

Based upon the probit regression results shown in Table 1, there is evidence that the price impacts the likelihood that a first mover will initiate trade regardless of role. Sfirst is a dummy variable for the treatment and takes the value of 1 if the seller moves first and 0 otherwise. Surplus is the dollar amount the first mover would gain from a successful trade. For a first-mover buyer this variable equals $V minus the negotiated price and for a first-mover seller it is the negotiated price minus $C. Thus the estimation results reveal that the larger the potential return, the more likely subjects are to engage in trust and this effect does not differ by role.

Although price does impact the likelihood that a trade is initiated, it does not appear to impact the likelihood that a trade is completed. The average price that second-mover buyers paid for received goods was $11.11 while the average price for which second-mover buyers did not send payment upon receipt of the good was $10.40. This difference is not significant (U = 122, p = 0.3942). (12) The average price received by second-mover sellers for goods that were subsequently delivered was $10.80, and the average payment for orders left unfilled was $10.25. Again, this difference is not significant (U = 47, p = 0.4165). The probit analysis shown in Table 2 also confirms the conclusion that price does not impact the likelihood that an initiated trade is successfully completed. Ssecond is a dummy variable for the treatment and takes a 1 if the seller moves second and 0 otherwise. Surplus is measured as before. Based upon estimation results neither of these variable impacts the likelihood of a successful trade. The expression that "if a deal looks too good to be true, then it probably is" holds, technically. Such deals are unlikely to be true, but less favorable deals are also unlikely to be true.

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

4. Further Exploration

The experiments reported in the previous section differ from standard trust game experiments in several ways including introducing a buyer-seller frame and negotiated prices. The combined effects of these changes are minimal for second movers. The observed behavior is similar to what has been previously reported for games with double-blind procedures and public payoff information (Cox and Deck 2005) and for games with single-blind payoff procedures and private payoff information (Gillies and Rigdon 2008). Data from these papers are shown in Table 3 along with data from the seller first treatment of Deck (2009). It appears that either payoff privacy or the double-blind procedures leads to low levels of trustworthiness, and these effects dominate any tendency to increase cooperation that the buyer-selling framing or negotiated prices might engender, although second movers are slightly more trustworthy with the buyer-seller framing.

Where the observed behavior does differ dramatically from previous experiments is the level of "trust" exhibited by the first mover. While this rate is normally around 50% even for experiments with double-blind payoff procedures, Gillies and Rigdon (2008) report that approximately two thirds of subjects do not trust when payoffs are private. In the current experiments the opposite behavior occurs; the vast majority of subjects are trusting.

Both the framing and the negotiated prices could explain the increase in trust. By framing the decision as a buyer-seller interaction, a social connotation is associated with not completing the transaction. First movers may (incorrectly) believe that second movers are unlikely to explicitly steal. Alternatively, the negotiation process which requires first movers to agree to the price may increase trust by setting the level of risk at (or below) a level the first mover is willing to tolerate. To explore the relative impacts of price negotiations and the buyer-seller framework, an additional set of seller-first experiments was conducted with 21 new subject pairs. (13) These experiments were similar to those reported in the previous section with the exception that the price was fixed at p = $10.

The results of the additional experiments are shown in the right-most column of Table 3. A nominally higher, but statistically indistinguishable 81% of the first movers trusted as compared with the case with negotiated prices (p = 0.431). For comparison, the rate of trust is also higher than that observed by Cox and Deck (2005) with double-blind payoffs, fixed prices, public information, and neutral framing (p = 0.037); Rigdon and Gilles (2008) with single-blind payoffs, fixed prices, neutral framing, and private information (p < 0.001); and Deck (2009) with fixed price, neutral framing, and public information (p = 0.053). While one should always be cautious of comparisons across studies, this pattern suggests that the substantial increase in trust is due to the buyer-seller framing and not the negotiated prices. (14) Approximately 40% of the second-mover buyers actually sent payment conditional on receiving the good. As expected given the lack of a price response by second movers, this is statistically indistinguishable from the case of negotiated prices (p = 0.812) indicating that negotiated prices do not affect trustworthiness. The 40% figure is also not statistically different from second-mover behavior in Cox and Deck (2005), Rigdon and Gilles (2008), or Deck (2009) with p-values of 0.388, 0.197, and 0.478, respectively.

5. Conclusion

Laboratory experiments are intended to inform researchers about behavior in the naturally occurring world. The trust game and the related investment game have received considerable attention from experimental economists. While previous work has discussed the trust game as a model of sequential trade, this article reports experiments that explore this interpretation more directly. Here the game is framed to the subjects as the interaction of a buyer and a seller. Costs and values that would normally be private information in a naturally occurring trade are kept private. The price, which determines how the potential gains from trade are to be shared, is determined endogenously in practice and in the experiment. There are some features of the experiment that are distinct from naturally occurring trades. One is the order of moves, which serves as a treatment in this study. Others differences include the double-blind payoff procedure, the use of induced values, and the total inability of first movers to retaliate.

As compared with the findings of previous studies, first movers were far more likely to trust regardless of role. Based upon additional experiments, this surprising result is found to be the result of the buyer-seller framing rather than the negotiated prices. Second movers were not trustworthy. This is similar to previous results from experiments with double-blind payoff procedures or payoff privacy. In the experiments price did not impact the likelihood that a trade was successfully completed. Contradicting previous results, the role of the second mover did not impact the probability that an initiated trade was completed in this environment where traders could not observe the social gains from exchange. This suggests that people need precise rather than vague information about how a choice will benefit others before undertaking a costly action.

This article demonstrates the need to closely consider the abstractions that are made when simplifying a problem as argued by Eckel and Grossman (1996). However, the norm in experimental economics continues to be that individual choice experiments rely upon "neutral" language. The abstract trust game has been widely used to study individual choice behavior in bilateral exchange. The current results suggest that previous studies have underestimated the amount of trust that occurs in naturally occurring trading opportunities. This also suggests that subjects do not see the trust game as an exchange no matter how well that interpretation seems to fit in theory. Researchers need to be cautious in interpreting lab results, not only for the trust game but for other stylized games as well. This should not be misconstrued as an argument that experiments with abstract games do not provide valuable insight. The very consistency of behavior in such games is evidence that they reveal real patterns of human decision making. Clearly, additional work on the effect of context is warranted. Hoffman et al. (1994) found a similar behavioral effect by placing a market frame on the ultimatum game, but this result was not replicated by Cox and Deck (2005).

Appendix 1: Subject Directions--First-Mover Seller with Price Negotiation

You are going to participate in an experiment like the one pictured below in which a "buyer" and "seller" have the opportunity to trade a fictitious good. In the experiment, you will have to make decisions that will have a direct impact on your cash payoff'. The numbers represent the $US amounts that you and your randomly selected counterpart will be paid at the end of the experiment, including the $5 show-up fee that each of you is receiving for participating in this experiment.

You have been assigned the role of seller and your counterpart has been assigned the role of buyer. Your role will be clearly indicated on the top of your screen. To assist you, items on your screen that refer to you are highlighted in yellow, while information regarding your counterpart is in blue.

[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]

The seller (you) is endowed with $10 and the buyer (your counterpart) is endowed with $E. By incurring a cost of $5, you can produce and ship a good which the buyer values at $V. This information is contained in the tables at the top of the screen. Your counterpart does not know your endowment or cost, and since no one knows their counterpart's identity, "CP" is displayed on the buyer's table.

As the seller, you will first have to decide to "Ship" or "Not Ship" the fictitious good. If you decide to "Not Ship" you will receive $10, and the buyer will receive $E. If you decide to "Ship" you will incur the $5 cost, and the buyer will receive $V. At this point, the buyer would have to decide to "Pay" or "Not Pay." If the buyer decides to "Pay," you will receive $10 endowment--$5 cost + price = price + $5 and the buyer will receive SE + $V - price. If the buyer decides to "Not Pay," you will receive $10 endowment - $5 cost = $5 and the buyer will receive SE + $V.

The decision tree on the bottom portion of your screen contains all of this payoff information. The seller has the first decision and thus is at the first node of the decision tree. If the seller chooses to "Ship", this leads to the second node at which the buyer will have to make a decision. If and when you need to make a decision, "???" will appear beside each of your choices on the decision tree. To make a decision, you click on the desired branch in the decision tree, which will highlight your selection in green. To confirm your decision you must click the green "Confirm" button that will appear on your screen.

So how is the price determined? It is determined by you and the buyer. To suggest a price, you can type it in the blue box at the top of the screen and press the "Propose Price of" button. After you do this, the price you proposed will be displayed as your proposed price, and the buyer will be able to accept it. Any price the buyer proposes will be displayed in the purple box at the top of your screen, and you can accept it by clicking on the "Accept Price of" button. If either of you accepts the price the other person proposed, the decision tree will reflect the agreed-upon price and the experiment will proceed as described above. While determining a price, you can see the decision tree for any price by using the dropdown tool just above the decision tree. The example screen image shown above has a price of $15. if neither of you accept a price within five minutes, you will receive $10, your counterpart will receive $E, and neither of you will have any further decisions to make in this experiment. A clock counts down the remaining seconds.

You will only go through this process only once during this experiment. After all participants' earnings have been determined as described above, you will receive your money and be dismissed from the experiment. If you have any questions, please raise your hand; otherwise please wait quietly.

References

Andreoni, James, and John Miller. 2002. Giving according to GARP: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica 70:737-53.

Andreoni, James, and Lise Vesterlund. 2001. Which is the fair sex? Gender differences in altruism. Quarterly Journal of Economies 116:293-312.

Coricelli, Giorgio, Kevin McCabe, and Vernon Smith. 2000. Theory-of-mind mechanism in personal exchange. In Affective minds, edited by G. Hatano, N. Okada, and H. Tanabe. Amsterdam, Netherlands: Elsevier Science, pp. 249-60.

Cox, James C., and Cary A. Deck. 2005. On the nature of reciprocal motives. Economic Inquiry 43:623-35.

Deck, Cary A. 2009. An experimental analysis of cooperation and productivity in the trust game. Experimental Economics 12:1-11.

Eckel, Catherine, and Philip Grossman. 1996. Altruism in anonymous dictator games. Games and Economic Behavior 16:181-91.

Gillies, Anthony, and Mary Rigdon. 2008. Epistemic conditions and social preferences in trust games. University of Michigan Working Paper.

Hoffman, Elizabeth, Kevin A. McCabe, Keith Shachat, and Vernon L. Smith. 1994. Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games and Economic Behavior 7:346-80.

Houser, Dan, Daniel Schunk, and Joachim Winters. 2006. Trust games measure trust. University of Munich Discussion Paper 2006-38.

McCabe, Kevin A., Stephen J. Rassenti, and Vernon L. Smith. 1998. Reciprocity, trust, and payoff privacy in extensive form bargaining. Games and Economic Behavior 24:10-24.

McCabe, Kevin A., Mary L. Rigdon, and Vernon L. Smith. 2003. Positive reciprocity and intentions in the trust game. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 52:267-75.

McCabe, Kevin A., and Vernon L. Smith. 2000. A comparison of naive and sophisticated subject behavior with game theoretic predictions. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 97:3777-81.

Cary A. Deck, Department of Economics, Walton College of Business, University of Arkansas and Economic Science Institute, Chapman University, 402 WCOB, 1 University of Arkansas, Fayetteville, AR 72701, USA; E-mail cdeck@walton. uark.edu.

The author wishes to thank two anonymous referees and Bart Wilson for extremely helpful suggestions and Taylor Jaworski for research assistance. Support from the Center for Retailing Excellence at the Sam M. Walton College of Business is gratefully acknowledged.

Received March 2008; accepted June 2009.

(1) Various institutions have evolved to protect against such risks. These institutions include the court system, escrow accounts, and reputation mechanisms such as the one used on eBay. However, there are numerous (potential) trading situations in which these institutions are not available or practical. For example, when buying a ticket from an illegal scalper before a sporting event, the seller could simply pocket the money, leaving the buyer little recourse. A person purchasing narcotics on the street runs the risk that the received goods are impure. Undocumented workers may not receive promised wages. A handyman may receive money for supplies and never complete a project. Restaurant owners are exposed to the risk that a customer will "dine and dash" without paying. The cost of legal proceedings makes it unlikely one party would sue if an item priced at a few dollars turned out to be defective. Measuring the value of trades that are not completed or even initiated due to such incomplete contracting concerns would be difficult.

(2) Recent evidence by Houser, Schunk, and Winter (2006) indicates that subjects view the decision to trust differently from a lottery with a similar payoff structure.

(3) In the ultimatum game the first mover proposes an allocation of a fixed pie. The second mover can accept this allocation or reject it, in which case both sides receive 0. The first mover can be considered a seller (buyer) setting a price, and the second mover can be considered a buyer (seller) making a purchase (sell) decision.

(4) See McCabe, Rigdon, and Smith (2003) for a variation of the trust game in which the transaction can be thought of as barter with surplus generated at both stages.

(5) In the original trust game of McCabe and Smith (2000), the seller moved first and the parameters were [E.sub.B] = [E.sub.S] = $10, V = $30, C = $10, and P = $15. See Deck (2009) for a discussion of the impact on behavior of changes to these parameters including asymmetric endowments.

(6) The Appendix contains the directions for a subject in the role of a first mover seller. Copies of the other directions arc available from the author upon request.

(7) Subjects did not receive a separate participation payment; the $5 promised in recruiting was included in their endowments as was made explicit in the directions (see Appendix). In this respect, it was public information that there was a minimum endowment.

(8) Each session contained male and female subjects, although precise demographic information was not collected.

(9) From an adjoining room the experimenter could monitor that subjects did not talk during the experiment without compromising privacy.

(10) Due to an error in the computer program, the negotiation data were lost for some sessions.

(11) The subject pool, laboratory, and double-blind payoff procedures were the same as those used in Deck (2009).

(12) The comparison of first mover behavior is based upon a t-test. Given the relatively small number of observations, comparisons of second-mover behavior are based upon the nonparametric Mann-Whitney test. In both cases, the null hypothesis is no effect, and the alternative is two-sided.

(13) The purpose of the additional experiments is to explore the effects of various aspects of the experimental design. The seller-first format is comparable to existing literature, thereby allowing more general comparisons. It is possible that payoff privacy, price negotiations, or the buyer-seller framing interact with the player order, although there is no a priori reason to suspect they do.

(14) It is possible that both the framing and negotiations effects are the same but have no interaction effect.
Table 1. Probit Regression for Likelihood That First Mover Initiates
Trade

Variable           Coefficient   Standard Error   z-Statistic   p-Value

Sfirst                -0.21           0.84           -0.25       0.80
Surplus                0.19           0.09            2.09       0.04
Sfirst x Surplus       0.21           0.24            0.87       0.39
Constant              -0.15           0.39           -0.41       0.68

Table 2. Probit Regression for Likelihood That Second Mover
Completes Trade

                                  Standard
Variable            Coefficient     Error     z-Statistic   p-Value

Ssecond                -0.48         0.81        -0.60        0.55
Surplus                -0.08         0.10        -0.85        0.40
Ssecond x Surplus       0.12         0.15         0.82        0.41
Constant               -0.26         0.44        -0.59        0.56

Table 3. Comparison of Behavior Across Studies

                            Cox     Gillies
                            and       and
                            Deck    Rigdon     Deck
                           (2005)   (2008)    (2009)

Double blind                Yes       No       Yes
Private payoffs              No       Yes       No
Fixed price                 Yes       Yes      Yes
Buyer seller framing         No       No        No
Percent of "trusting"
  first movers              52%       33%      56%
Percent of "trustworthy"
  second movers             29%       20%      30%

                           Current   Current
                           Article   Article

Double blind                 Yes       Yes
Private payoffs              Yes       Yes
Fixed price                  No        Yes
Buyer seller framing         Yes       Yes
Percent of "trusting"
  first movers               77%       81%
Percent of "trustworthy"
  second movers              38%       41%
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有