Public pollution abatement, regional capital mobility, and tax competition.
Hadjiyiannis, Costas ; Hatzipanayotou, Panos ; Michael, Michael S. 等
1. Introduction
In response to growing environmental concerns, governments and
international organizations have designed policies of pollution
abatement and control (PAC). In a 2003 report the Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) defines PAC activities as
... the purposeful activities aimed directly at the preservation,
reduction, and elimination of pollution nuisances arising as a
residual of production processes or the consumption of goods and
services .... In total, PAC expenditure comprises the flow of
investment, internal current expenditure, subsidies and fees that
is directly aimed at pollution abatement and control, and which is
incurred by the public sector, the business sector, private
households and specialized producers of PAC services.... (Linster
and Zegel 2003, p. 9)
In the same report, PAC expenditures in OECD countries vary from
0.7% (Portugal, 1994) to 2.6% (Austria, 1998) of Gross Domestic Product
(GDP) per annum in the period extending from 1990 to 2000. A revealing
stylized fact of this report is that a significant part of these
expenditures are undertaken by the public sector. For most countries,
public expenditures account for about 40-60% of total PAC. These
statistics reveal two important stylized facts. First, PAC expenditures
as a percentage of GDP are sizeable, and second, a significant part of
these expenditures are incurred by the public sector. (1)
Thus, it is important that both the private and the public
sectors' abatement are taken into consideration in analyzing
environmental policies, especially in light of the fact that emission
tax revenue is often earmarked for pollution abatement activities by
governments. For example, Brett and Keen (2000) note that in the United
States it is quite customary for environmental taxes to be earmarked for
specific environment-related public expenditure. In particular, such tax
proceeds are commonly paid into trust funds that finance various
clean-up activities or are spent on road and public transport networks.
Yet by and large, the literature on pollution abatement has assumed that
pollution abatement is entirely undertaken by the private sector in
response to emission taxes on private producers (see, for example,
Copeland and Taylor 1995; Copeland 1996; Ludema and Wooton 1997; Silva
and Caplan 1997). (2)
Hatzipanayotou, Lahiri, and Michael (2002, 2005) and Chao and Yu
(1999) provide some of the very few studies that explicitly consider the
simultaneous provision of pollution abatement by the private and public
sectors. Chao and Yu (1999) examine the welfare implications of
international transfers when public pollution abatement is financed by
foreign aid and emission tax revenue. Hatzipanayotou, Lahiri, and
Michael (2002) examine optimal policies for the donor and recipient
countries in a similar framework but also incorporate cross-border
pollution. Hatzipanayotou, Lahiri, and Michael (2005) examine the
optimal policy implications of a number of multilateral reforms in a
two-country model with cross-border pollution, in which public sector
abatement is financed through a fraction of environmental tax revenue.
These studies, however, ignore an important feature of open
economies--that of international capital mobility. On the other hand,
there is a large body of literature examining various aspects, including
optimal environmental policies, of the interaction between international
capital mobility and the environment but without accounting for the
simultaneous abatement of pollution by the private and public sectors
(e.g., Copeland 1994; Copeland and Taylor 1997; Rauscher 1997).
The present paper bridges the gap in the literature by
incorporating both capital mobility and public pollution abatement. To
this end, we construct a general equilibrium model of a regional block
(RB) with two non-identical countries and free commodity and capital
flows. We assume that pollution, a by-product of production, is
generated in each country, is transmitted across borders, and is abated
partly by the private producers, in response to an emissions tax, and
partly by the local governments. Governments finance their public
pollution abatement activities using lump-sum and pollution tax revenue.
We derive the cooperative and Nash optimal pollution taxes and relate
them to the marginal cost of public pollution abatement.
This paper offers two innovations. The first is the generalization
of the existing models, which incorporate simultaneous provision of
public and private pollution abatement. In this more general model, we
incorporate all the features that different papers have stressed as
important features in studying environmental policies, such as
cross-border pollution and asymmetries between countries. The second
innovation is the analysis of these policies in the presence of capital
mobility. Changes in environmental policies in the presence of public
pollution abatement create externalities between neighboring countries
because of cross-border pollution. At the same time, such changes affect
tax revenue and therefore public pollution abatement. On the other hand,
environmental policies affect capital mobility, which in turn affects
emissions.
This generalized model allows us to identify interactions between
these features that have been ignored by the literature thus far.
Capital mobility affects the optimal choice of pollution taxes in the
two countries since higher taxes lower the return to capital and drive
capital out of the country. That restricts the ability of governments to
finance public pollution abatement. We show that the coexistence of all
these features affects optimal pollution taxes by comparing the general
results to the special cases in which (i) there is no cross-border
pollution; (ii) countries are identical; (iii) there is no capital
mobility; and (iv) there is no public pollution abatement.
2. The Analytical Framework
The Model
We develop a general equilibrium model of a RB comprising two small
open economies, Home and Foreign, which trade freely with each other and
the rest of the world. (3) As a result, commodity prices in the two
countries are constant and equal to the world commodity prices. In both
countries pollution of the eyesore type is generated as a by-product of
production and is transmitted across national borders. Identical
residents, inhabiting each country, are adversely affected and suffer
disutility from locally generated pollution and from pollution emitted
by foreign producers and transmitted across borders. With respect to the
flows of factors of production, it is assumed that capital is freely
mobile within the RB but immobile between the region and the rest of the
world. Other factors of production, such as labor, are intra-regionally
and internationally immobile. (4)
Without loss of generality, we call the capital-importing country
Home; the model of Foreign, the capital-exporting country, follows
analogously. Home's maximum value of production of private goods is
denoted by the revenue function R(p, v, t, K), defined as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (1)
where p is the vector of exogenously given world commodity prices,
[phi] (v, K) is the country's aggregate technology set denoting
private production and abatement technologies, v is the endowment vector
of the immobile factors, [bar.K] is Home's capital endowment,
[k.sup.f] the amount of foreign capital operating in Home (and thus K is
the domestic supply of capital), x is the vector of net outputs, and z
is the amount of pollution emission by the private sector, net of the
amount abated by the private sector. (5) In the present analysis, since
(v) and (p) are invariant, for notational simplification the revenue
function is written as R(t, K). By the envelop theorem, the partial
derivative of the revenue function with respect to K (i.e., [R.sub.K])
is the marginal revenue product of capital, and by the same theorem, the
level of pollution, z, generated by the private sector is given by (6)
z = -[R.sub.t](t, K). (2)
We assume that the R(t, K) function is strictly concave in K (RKK
< 0) and strictly convex in t ([R.sub.u] > 0). The latter
assumption implies that a higher emission tax level lowers the amount of
pollution emissions by the private sector. We also assume that the
polluting activity is capital intensive, that is, [R.sub.tK] < 0 and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Accounting for both private and public sector pollution abatement,
the overall net pollution, r, affecting the home country residents is
r = z - g + [THETA]([z.sup.*] - [g.sup.*]), (3)
where the parameter [THETA][member of] [0, 1] is the rate of
cross-border pollution or the spillover parameter, g is the level of
public pollution abatement in the home country, and [z.sup.*] and
[g.sup.*] denote the levels of pollution net of private abatement and
the level of public pollution abatement, respectively, in the foreign
country. (7) We also assume that private firms can only abate pollution
by reducing production, and that they do not have access to the imported
abatement good. This is because in some cases, it is in the best
interest of the government to forbid its use by private firms. Allowing
firms access to this good restricts the government's ability to use
pollution taxes to capture terms of trade effects in the capital market.
For example, if pollution taxes are higher than the cost of the
abatement good, firms abate all pollution using the abatement good,
avoiding pollution taxes altogether. That makes pollution taxes
completely ineffective in capturing the terms of trade effect in the
capital market.
As for the country's public sector, we assume that it imports
from the rest of the world, at a constant price [P.sub.g], a commodity
used to provide public pollution abatement at the level g. The
assumption of the constant world price [P.sub.g] for the public
abatement good implies constant marginal abatement cost (MAC). The cost
of the imported good (i.e., [P.sub.g]g), used for public pollution
abatement, is financed through the emission tax revenue [i.e.,
-t[R.sub.t](t, K)] and lump-sum taxes (7). Thus, the government's
budget constraint is written as
[P.sub.g]g = -t[R.sub.t](t, K) q- T. (4)
This formulation reflects the requirement in many countries that
pollution tax revenues are earmarked for environmental clean-up. We also
allow governments to use lump-sum taxes to finance public pollution
abatement. (8) We abstract from all other activities of the government
in an effort to isolate the effects that relate to optimal environmental
policies.
Turning to the demand side of the economy, we assume that each
country comprises identical individuals. Utility is adversely affected
by both local and foreign pollution transmitted across borders. Let E(u,
r) denote the minimum expenditure required to achieve a level of
utility, u, at constant prices, p, omitted from the expenditure function
for reasons noted earlier and at the given level of net pollution, r.
The partial derivative of the expenditure function with respect to u,
[E.sub.u], denotes the reciprocal of the marginal utility of income.
Since pollution adversely affects household utility, the partial
derivative of the expenditure function with respect to r, [E.sub.r], is
positive, denoting the households' marginal willingness to pay for
a reduction in pollution (see Chao and Yu 1999), which is the same as
the marginal damage of pollution (MD). (9) That is, a higher level of
net pollution requires a higher level of spending on private goods to
mitigate its detrimental effects so that a constant level of utility is
maintained.
Home's budget constraint requires that expenditures by the
private [E(u, r)] and the public sector (Peg) and payments to foreign
capital [[k.sup.f][R.sub.K](t, K)] equal total revenue from production
[R(t, K)] and pollution tax revenues [-t[R.sub.t](t, K)]. Thus, the
economy's income expenditure identity is
E(u, r) + [P.sub.g]g + [k.sup.f] [R.sub.K](t, K) = R(t, K) -
t[R.sub.t](t, K). (5)
Using Equation 4 in Equation 5 reduces the income expenditure
identity to
E(u, r) = R(t, K) - [k.sup.f] [R.sub.K](t, K) - T. (6)
The model of Foreign, the capital-exporting country, is similarly
developed. The corresponding equations for Foreign are
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (7)
[r.sup.*] = [z.sup.*] - [g.sup.*] + [[THETA].sup.*] (z - g), (8)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (9)
[E.sup.*] ([u.sup.*], [r.sup.*]) = [R.sup.*] ([t.sup.*], [K.sup.*])
+ [k.sup.F] [R.sub.K] (t, K) - [T.sup.*], (10)
where [r.sup.*] is the level of total net pollution for Foreign,
[[THETA].sup.*] is the rate of cross-border pollution in that country,
and [K.sup.*] is the supply of capital. By the assumptions of the model,
dK = [dk.sup.f] = - [dK.sup.*]. (10)
Finally, international capital mobility, though non-existent
between the RB and the rest of the world, is perfect within the RB
(i.e., between Home and Foreign). Since it is assumed that capital
earnings are untaxed by both countries, perfect regional capital
mobility equalizes the
factor's reward in the two countries. That is, equilibrium in
the RB's capital market requires that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (11)
Appendix A of the paper lays out the complete comparative statics
of the system.
Pollution Taxes, Public Abatement, and Net Pollution
In this section, we derive and briefly discuss the effects of
raising pollution taxes (t and [t.sup.*]) on net pollution (r and
[r.sup.*]). These preliminary results are of use in the analysis to
follow and highlight the effects that other studies ignore by omitting
either public pollution abatement or capital mobility from the analysis.
In Home, the effect of a higher pollution tax (t) on domestic net
pollution (r) can be derived as follows: Using Equations 2 and 3 and
Appendix A we obtain
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (12)
where H = [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] and
[mathematical and are negative. Intuitively, Equation 12 shows that a
higher tax (t) affects domestic net pollution (r) in three ways. First,
it affects r directly by reducing the level of pollution taxed (i.e., -
[R.sub.tt] < 0). The second effect is through its impact on public
abatement in Home and Foreign, since additional tax revenues are
earmarked for public abatement. This effect is not captured by the
literature that does not account for public pollution abatement. (11)
Third, it affects r through a pollution-haven effect. That is, a higher
t induces a capital outflow from Home (i.e., dK/dt < 0), which
reduces production-generated pollution z, and net pollution. (12) On the
other hand, the higher t raises the stock of capital in Foreign, which
raises production-generated pollution [z.sup.*], which in the presence
of cross-border pollution also raises net pollution in Home. (13)
Moreover, the combination of the last two effects also highlights the
importance of including both capital mobility and public pollution
abatement in the model.
Equivalently, the effect of the higher pollution tax (t) on
Foreign's net pollution ([r.sup.*]) is shown to be
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (13)
The reduced form of Equation 13 is given in Appendix A. Analogous
results are inferred for an increase in Foreign's pollution tax
([t.sup.*]) on the Home and Foreign countries' levels of net
pollution.
Public pollution abatement and cross-border pollution are important
determinants of the impact of emission taxes on pollution in each
country. Note that in the absence of public sector pollution abatement
and of cross-border pollution in both countries (i.e., [THETA] =
[[THETA].sup.*] = 0), we unambiguously obtain that dr/dt(= dz/dt) < 0
and d[r.sup.*]/dt(= [dz.sup.*]/dt) > 0. In the absence of public
sector abatement but in the presence of cross-border pollution, we
obtain dr/dt < 0 and [dr.sup.*]/dt < 0 if [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. Therefore, a model that fails to account for
public pollution abatement and cross-border pollution would give biased
results on the impact of emission taxes.
3. Taxes and Welfare
In this section, we examine the effect of a higher domestic
pollution tax (t) on levels of national welfare, (u) and ([u.sup.*]).
Analogous results are stated for the effects of a higher tax ([t.sip.*])
on the aforementioned variables. We also examine the effects of higher
lump-sum taxes, T and [T.sup.*], for each country's level of
national welfare.
We first analyze the welfare effects of small changes in policy
variables and show how the coexistence of public pollution abatement and
capital mobility alters the existing results. Differentiating Equation 6
gives
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (14)
Lump-Sum Taxes and Welfare
Using Appendix A, the effect of an increase in the domestic
(foreign) lump-sum taxes on domestic (foreign) welfare is given by (14)
du / dT = [S.sub.g] / [E.sub.u][P.sub.g] (15)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (16)
where [S.sub.g] [equivalent to] ([E.sub.r] - [P.sub.g])= (MD -
MAC)and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. Public
pollution abatement is locally optimally provided in Home (Foreign) if
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]--that is, if MD =
MAC ([MD.sup.*] = [MAC.sup.*]). This is the Samuelson rule for optimal
public good provision within each country. Given this, we say that the
public pollution abatement is locally under(over)-provided in Home if
[S.sub.g] > 0 (< 0) and in Foreign if [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. Therefore, raising lump-sum taxes is
unambiguously welfare improving (deteriorating) if the public pollution
abatement is locally under(over)-provided. (15)
Pollution Taxes and Welfare
Using Equations 14 and 12, the welfare effect of an increase in
Home's pollution tax (t) on its own welfare is given by
du/dt = 1/[E.sub.u] {[R.sub.t] - [E.sub.r] dr/dt - [k.sup.f]
([R.sub.Kt] + [R.sub.KK] dK/dt)}. (17)
The reduced form of Equation 17 is given in Appendix A. Equation 17
shows that the increase in (t) affects Home's level of welfare in
three ways. First, the higher (t) induces a transfer of additional
resources from production of goods to pollution abatement by private
producers. As a result, real income, and therefore welfare, is reduced
(i.e., [E.sup.-1.sub.u][R.sub.t] < 0). Second, it affects (u) through
changes in domestic net pollution [i.e., - [E.sup.-1.sub.u][E.sub.r]
(dr/dt)]. Namely, since [E.sub.r] captures the MD of pollution to
households, then -[E.sup.-1.sub.u][E.sub.r](dr/dt) is a measure of the
marginal benefit/damage of changes in (r) due to the increase in (t) on
households' utility. Through this term, the increase in (t)
increases (u) if dr/dt < 0. Third, the term -[E.sup.-1.sub.u]
[k.sup.f] ([R.sub.Kt] + [R.sub.KK](dK/dt)) captures the effect of (t) on
(u) through changes in payments to foreign capital operating at home.
This change in payments to [k.sup.f] is due to changes in the domestic
marginal revenue product of capital, [R.sub.K], induced by the higher
(t). Namely, by assumption, a higher (t) reduces [R.sub.K] and thus
payments to [k.sup.f] In addition, as previously discussed, dK/dt < 0
causes an increase in the marginal revenue product of capital and thus
an increase in payments to [k.sup.f] It can be shown, however, that the
positive direct effect (-[E.sup.-1.sub.u][k.sup.f][R.sub.Kt]) always
dominates the negative indirect effect [-[E.sup.-1.sub.u][k.sup.f]
[R.sub.KK](dK/dt)]. Thus, the overall impact of (t) on (u) through
changes in payments to [k.sup.f] is positive. (16)
The effect of an increase in (t) on Foreign's level of welfare
is given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (18)
The reduced form of Equation 18 is given in Appendix A. Equation 18
shows that an increase in (t) affects ([u.sup.*]) through its effect on
net pollution, ([r.sup.*]), and its effect on repatriated payments of
its capital operating in the home country. The discussion of the first
effect follows the discussion of Equation 13, and the discussion of the
second effect follows that of Equation 17. Analogously, using Appendix
A, we get the reduced-form expressions of an increase in ([t.sup.*]) on
welfare in Foreign ([u.sup.*]) and in Home (u).
4. Optimal Lump-Sum and Pollution Taxes
In this section, we turn to the derivation of the optimal pollution
taxes, (t) and ([t.sup.*]), and lump-sum taxes, T and [T.sup.*], in the
presence of all these interactions generated by the coexistence of
public pollution abatement, capital mobility, and cross-border
pollution. We first derive the optimal tax rates under the assumption of
policy cooperation between the two countries and then under the
assumption of lack of such a cooperation.
Cooperative Taxes
A standard result in the literature of environmental economics is
that in the presence of cross-border pollution externalities, the
optimal policy requires either the adoption of cooperative policies
among regions or the mandate of policies by a central (e.g., federal)
authority. Here, we begin our analysis of tax policy choices by
presenting the first-best policy choices of the RB. This regime entails
the simultaneous cooperative choice of lump-sum and pollution taxes that
maximize the two countries' joint welfare. This regime constitutes
a benchmark solution to which the Nash equilibrium results to follow are
compared.
Cooperative Lump-Sum Taxes
The maximization of the countries' joint welfare requires
setting du/dT + [du.sup.*]/dT = 0 and du/[dT.sup.*] +
[du.sup.*]/[dT.sup.*] = 0, where [du.sup.*]/[dT.sup.*] and
[du.sup.*]/[dT.sup.*] are given by Equations 15 and 16, respectively.
Moreover, using Appendix A we obtain
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (19)
and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (20)
From Equations 15, 16, 19, and 20, we determine that the
cooperative first-best policy choice for provision of public abatement
requires that (17)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (21)
and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (22)
where [lambda] = ([MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII]) denotes the ratio of Foreign's marginal utility of income
to that of Home. (18) It should be noted that allowing transfers between
the two countries would equalize their marginal utility of income,
leading to [lambda] = 1. This is reasonable to assume in a perfectly
cooperative environment. However, transfers between countries may not
always be feasible. For example, it is a lot more difficult for a
government to persuade its citizens to embrace monetary transfers to
another country than it is to secure cooperation in taxation. Therefore,
we present the more general formulation that allows for [lambda] [not
equal to] 1.
With this in mind, the economic interpretation of Equations 21 and
22 is as follows. A unit of pollution generated by Home causes Er damage
domestically and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
damage in Foreign. Thus [[bar.E].sub.r] is the global MD caused by a
unit of locally generated pollution weighted by the relative marginal
utilities of income, ([lambda]). Similarly [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is the weighted global MD caused by a unit of
pollution generated in Foreign. Therefore, [[bar.E].sub.r]
([[bar.E].sup.*.sub.r]) is the weighted global MD of the Home-generated
(Foreign-generated) pollution. When [[bar.E].sub.r] = [P.sub.g], we say
that the public pollution abatement by Home is globally optimally
provided, and when [[bar.E].sub.r] - [P.sub.g] > 0 (< 0), public
pollution abatement in Home is globally under-provided (over-provided).
Similar definitions apply to Foreign.
Equations 21 and 22 indicate that maximizing joint welfare requires
that lump-sum taxes in each country are set at a level at which the
weighted global MD of pollution generated in each country equals the MAC
of providing it (i.e., [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII]). Note that these two equations represent the relevant Samuelson
rule for optimal provision of regional public (pollution abatement)
goods. Moreover, because of the existence of cross-border pollution, the
relevant Samuelson rule accounts not only for the marginal willingness
to pay for pollution abatement within the emitting country, but also for
the marginal willingness to pay for it in the other country, weighted by
the relative marginal utilities of income.
Note that in the absence of cross-border pollution (i.e., [THETA] =
[[THETA].sup.*] = 0), changes in one country's lump-sum taxes have
no effect on the other country's welfare level and that the
first-best cooperative choice for public good provision reduces to
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. This result is
achieved without cooperation between the two countries.
Cooperative Pollution Taxes
Deriving the cooperative first-best choice of pollution taxes
requires setting du/dt + [du.sup.*]/dt = 0 and du/[dt.sup.*] +
[du.sup.*]/[dt.sup*] = 0, where the expressions for du/dt,
[du.sup.*]/dt, [du.sup.*]/[dt.sup.*], and du/[dt.sup.*] are given in
Appendix A. In general, the cooperative pollution taxes, [t.sup.c] for
Home and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] for
Foreign, assuming that the two countries also cooperate in lump-sum
taxes, are given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (23)
and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (24)
From Equations 23 and 24, note that in a perfectly cooperative
environment with international transfers (i.e., [lambda] = 1), we get
that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. In this case,
the cooperative optimal policies require that [t.sup.c] = [P.sub.g] =
[[bar.E].sub.r] and are independent of capital mobility. If
international transfers are not feasible (i.e., [lambda] [not equal to]
1), capital mobility affects the cooperative pollution taxes. (19) This
is because payments to Foreign's capital operating in Home
constitute a direct income transfer from the latter to the former. Since
the marginal utility of income differs in the two countries, the
transfer of repatriated capital income affects global welfare. In other
words, despite the fact that the income lost by Home is exactly the same
as that gained by Foreign, the utilities that correspond to that income
are different, and therefore they affect the maximization of their joint
welfare. The sign of the coefficient of (1 - [lambda]) in the right-hand
side of Equations 23 and 24 is assumed to be positive. (20) Thus, from
Equation 23 for [lambda] > 1 we get that [t.sup.c] > [P.sub.g] and
from Equation 24 that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII], For [lambda] > 1, Home's marginal utility of income is
lower than Foreign's, which means that Home is relatively richer,
which calls for a higher pollution tax in Home and a lower pollution tax
in Foreign. The intuition is as follows: Pollution taxes allow countries
to redistribute income between them through their effect on repatriated
income of Foreign's capital in Home. As [t.sup.c] increases and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] decreases the return
to capital in Home decreases, while that in Foreign increases, causing
capital outflow from Home to Foreign. This increases the return to
capital and thus increases the repatriated capital income going from
Home to Foreign. If [lambda] > 1, the marginal utility of income is
higher in Foreign. This means that joint welfare can increase if income
is transferred from Home to Foreign. The following proposition
summarizes the result.
PROPOSITION l. If the marginal utilities of income across countries
are the same ([lambda] = 1) and both countries cooperate in the choice
of both policy instruments, the first-best policy choice is achieved
when [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. If, however,
[lambda] > 1, the first-best is achieved when [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. If [lambda] < 1, the
first-best is achieved when [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII].
Nash Equilibrium Lump-Sum and Pollution Taxes
We now derive the optimal Nash equilibrium lump-sum and pollution
taxes for Home and Foreign and compare them to the benchmark cooperative
case. The two countries choose these taxes simultaneously.
Nash Equilibrium Lump-Sum Taxes
Setting Equations 15 and 16 equal to 0, we derive the Nash
equilibrium lump-sum taxes. The emerging Nash equilibrium conditions
require that lump-sum taxes are chosen such that MD = MAC for Home and
[MD.sup.*] = [MAC.sup.*] for Foreign.
Nash Pollution Taxes
Setting (du/dt) = 0 and ([du.sup.*]/[dt.dup.*]) = 0, we derive the
following reaction functions:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (25)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (26)
Given that the structure of the game is such that lump-sum taxes
are locally optimally chosen (i.e., [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]), solving simultaneously Equations 25 and 26
gives the following expressions for each country's Nash equilibrium
pollution taxes: (21)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (27)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (28)
where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and is positive. From Equations 27 and 28 we note that when
lump-sum taxes are locally optimally chosen, the effect of pollution
taxes on payments to Foreign's capital operating in Home
constitutes the only difference between the Nash and cooperative tax
rates derived when [lambda] = 1. Note that the Nash pollution taxes are
independent of the marginal utilities of income since in the Nash
equilibrium each country is only concerned about its own welfare.
Observing the above expressions, we note that in general the Nash
pollution taxes can be greater or smaller than the unit cost of the
public pollution abatement, as opposed to the benchmark case of
cooperative choice of both instruments and [lambda] = 1. We resolve some
of this ambiguity by considering some special cases, as stated in the
following proposition:
PROPOSITION 2. Under the conditions of the model and when each
country chooses all taxes to maximize its own welfare, leading to
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] = 0,
1. If [THETA] = 0 and [lambda] = 1, then [t.sup.N] > [t.sup.c] =
[P.sub.g]. (22,23)
2. If [[THETA].sup.*] 0 and [lambda] 1, then [[MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]].
3. If the two countries are symmetric in the sense that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
4. If [lambda] = 1 and the two countries have identical factor
endowments and production technologies, leading to [k.sup.f] = 0, then
the Nash and cooperative pollution taxes are the same and equal to the
marginal cost of public pollution abatement (i.e., [t.sup.N] = [t.sup.c]
= [P.sub.g] and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]).
5. If [lambda] < 1 and [THETA] [approximately equal to] 0, then
[t.sup.N] > [P.sub.g] > [t.sup.c]. Similarly if [lambda] < 1
and [[THETA].sup.*] [approximately equal to] 0, then [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
6. If [lambda] > 1 and [THETA] [approximately equal to] 0, then
[t.sup.N] > [P.sub.g] and [t.sup.c] > [P.sub.g]. Similarly, if
[lambda] > 1 and [[THETA].sup.*] [approximately equal to] 0, then
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The proof of Proposition 2 follows from Equations 27 and 28. Note
that cases 1-4 assume that the marginal utilities of income between the
two countries are the same. Intuitively, the first three cases of
Proposition 2 capture terms of trade effects in capital markets and are
directly derived from the assumption that Home is the capital-importing
country and Foreign is the capital-exporting country and from the
assumption that pollution is capital intensive in both countries. That
is, a higher t reduces the payment of foreign capital, leading to a
higher domestic Nash pollution tax level. The reverse holds for Foreign,
the capital-exporting country.
Case 4 of Proposition 2 highlights a counter-intuitive result. When
countries are identical in the above sense, Nash pollution taxes are
efficient ([t.sup.N] = [t.sup.c], and [t.sup.*N] = [t.sup.*c]), while
Nash lumpsum taxes are not. Nash lump-sum taxes are too low and lead to
too little abatement since countries fail to take into account the
damage their pollution causes to the other country. Cases 5 and 6 show
that the relationship between the Nash and cooperative pollution taxes
depends on the relative marginal utilities of income in the two
countries. (24) Two key features of our model highlight the contribution
of this paper to the literature.
First, contrary to most of the literature, we allow countries to be
non-identical. Second, we introduce public pollution abatement in
addition to private pollution abatement. The remainder of this section
examines the role of country differences, while in the section to follow
we examine the role of public pollution abatement in detail.
To show how differences between the two countries affect optimal
taxes, we first consider the case in which the two countries are
identical. If countries are identical, the return on capital is
identical and [k.sup.f] = 0. In that case, if both taxes are chosen
optimally [t.sup.N] = [t.sup.c] = [P.sub.g] and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. However, from Equations 21 and 22, [T.sup.N]
[not equal to] [T.sup.c] and [T.sup.*N] [not equal to] [T.sup.*c].
Therefore, if countries are identical and both taxes are chosen
optimally, there is no need for cooperation in pollution taxes since
Nash taxes are efficient. On the other hand, there is scope for
cooperation in lump-sum taxes. If, however, the two countries are
non-identical and choose both taxes optimally, Nash pollution taxes are
not efficient. From Equations 21 and 22 we still get that [T.sup.N] [not
equal to] [T.sup.c] and [T.sup.*N] [not equal to] [T.sup.*c].
Proposition 2 summarizes the sufficient conditions for [t.sup.N] >
[t.sup.c] and [t.sup.*N] < [T.sup.*c]. (25)
5. The Role of Public Pollution Abatement
To highlight the role of public pollution abatement, consider the
case in which all pollution abatement is undertaken by the private
producers, in response to the emissions tax, and in which pollution tax
revenue is lump-sum distributed to local households in each country.
Moreover, for simplicity we only consider the case in which [lambda] =
1.
The level of production-generated pollution by the private sector
in the two countries is again given by Equations 2 and 7, and overall
net pollution affecting Home and Foreign, respectively, are defined as
r = z + [theta][z.sup.*] and [r.sup.*] = [z.sup.*] + [theta]z. (29)
The income-expenditure identities for the two countries are given
by
E(u, r) = R(t, K) - t[R.sub.t](t, K) - [k.sup.f][R.sub.K](t, K),
(30)
and
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (31)
Equilibrium in the RB's capital market is given by Equation
10. Appendix B presents the comparative statics of this system.
The cooperative first-best choice of pollution taxes is [t.sup.c] =
[[bar.E].sub.r] and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII]]. Note that this cooperative policy choice is different from the
solution with public pollution abatement, in which [t.sup.c] = [P.sub.g]
= [[bar.E].sub.r] and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII], since in the latter [P.sub.g] and [[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], the cost of public sector abatement in each
country is exogenous, and it is to this specific value that the
pollution tax and the global damage of a unit of pollution are equated.
Also, since dr/dT < 0, when g > 0 we have less r for the same t;
thus [t.sup.c](g = 0) > [t.sup.c](g > 0). That is, the higher g
and [g.sup.*], the lower the optimal cooperative tax; hence, public
abatement substitutes for private abatement. This is one of the ways in
which public pollution abatement affects optimal taxes.
Using Appendix B, we get that the Nash equilibrium pollution tax
for Home is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (32)
To highlight the differences between the two cases consider the
following special case. Let the two countries have identical factor
endowments and technologies, leading to [k.sup.f] = 0, and let [THETA]
> 0; [THETA].sup.*] > 0 (two-way cross-border pollution). From
Equation 32, observe that Nash pollution taxes are inefficient; that is,
[t.sup.N] < [E.sub.r] and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII]. On the other hand, and in direct contrast to this result,
case 4 of Proposition 2 indicates that in the presence of public
pollution abatement, Nash pollution taxes are efficient, while lump-sum
taxes are not. This is because Home knows that Foreign has public
pollution abatement at its disposal, and that it will use it optimally,
thus decreasing the amount of cross-border pollution back into Home.
Thus, it can afford to increase pollution taxes to their efficient
level. The intuition is as follows: A higher t induces capital outflow
from Home, increasing the stock of capital and pollution in Foreign. In
the absence of public pollution abatement this increases cross-border
pollution and net pollution in Home. This increased cross-border
pollution mitigates the benefit from increasing pollution taxes, leading
to lower equilibrium taxes. On the other hand, in the presence of public
sector abatement, Foreign increases [g.sup.*] and ends up with the same
level of net pollution. Thus, there is no extra cross-border pollution
into Home. This is because optimal behavior requires the MD
([MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],) of Foreign to be
equal to the exogenous MAC ([MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII]), which is constant. Therefore, the benefits of an increase in
pollution tax are higher in the presence of public pollution abatement,
leading to higher pollution taxes. (26)
These results are summarized in the following proposition:
PROPOSITION 3. If the two countries have identical factor
endowments and production technologies, leading to [k.sup.f] = 0 and
[lambda] = 1, then
1. In the presence of public pollution abatement, Nash equilibrium
lump-sum taxes require that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII] and are inefficient, while Nash pollution taxes are efficient
(i.e., [t.sup.N] = [t.sup.c] = [P.sub.g] and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION
NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]).
2. In the absence of public pollution abatement, Nash equilibrium
pollution taxes are inefficient (i.e., [t.sup.N] < [E.sub.r] <
[t.sup.c] = [[bar.E.sub.r] and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII].
Proposition 3 has important policy implications. When countries are
identical, there is no need for cooperation in emission taxes. On the
other hand, even identical countries need to cooperate in lump-sum
taxes. To see that, recall that cooperative lump-sum taxes require that
([MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], while Nash
lump-sum taxes require that [E.sub.r] = [P.sub.g] and [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. Proposition 3 demonstrates that
the existence of public pollution abatement drives this result. It
provides an additional policy tool, making it easier to achieve the
first-best emission taxes. The other important policy implication of
this section is that cooperation in both emission and lump-sum taxes is
very important when countries are different.
6. Conclusion
There is ample real-world evidence that the public sector is a key
player in pollution abatement activities. Despite this stylized fact,
the literature has paid little attention to it. On the other hand, the
few attempts at modeling public pollution abatement ignore another
important feature of open economies, that of international capital
mobility. This paper extends the existing literature in two ways: (i) It
offers a generalized model of simultaneous private and public pollution
abatement, which includes asymmetric countries and cross-border
pollution; and (ii) It considers public pollution abatement in the
presence of international capital mobility. Within this framework, we
examine the cooperative and Nash pollution taxes of the countries
involved.
To address these issues, the paper presents a model of a RB with
two non-identical countries with cross-border pollution, free trade in
goods, and perfect capital mobility within the region. Pollution, a
by-product of production, adversely affects welfare and is abated by the
private and public sectors in both countries. The government uses
revenue collected from pollution and lump-sum taxes to finance public
pollution abatement.
The major results of the paper are summarized in the various
propositions, and to avoid repetition, we do not cite them here. A few
general remarks, however, are worth emphasizing, since they highlight
effects the literature has ignored so far. First, the cooperative
lump-sum taxes need to account for the existence of cross-border
pollution and the relative marginal utilities of income between the two
countries. Second, the Nash equilibrium pollution taxes depend on
whether the country is a net capital importer or capital exporter, on
the factor intensity of the polluting activity, and on the degree of
cross-border pollution. Contrary to the cooperative taxes, Nash
pollution taxes are independent of the relative marginal utilities of
income. Third, when countries are symmetric, and in the presence of
public pollution abatement, the Nash equilibrium taxes are efficient,
while in the absence of public pollution abatement they are not, as a
result of the effects of cross-border pollution.
The key policy implication of these results is that cooperation is
more important when countries are different. However, there is still
scope for cooperation in lump-sum taxes when countries are identical but
not in emission taxes.
Appendix A: Comparative Statics
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Appendix B: The Model without Public Pollution Abatement
Differentiating Equation 30 using Equations 30 and 11, we obtain
the following matrix system:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is the
determinant of the matrix of the unknowns.
Received March 2007; accepted January 2008.
References
Brett, Craig, and Michael Keen. 2000. Political uncertainty and the
earmarking of environmental taxes. Journal of Public Economics 75:31540.
Bygrave, Stephen, and Jane Ellis. 2003. Policies to reduce
greenhouse gas emissions in industry Successful approaches and lessons
learned: Workshop report. Discussion paper, OECD.
Chao, Chi-Chur, and Eden S. H. Yu. 1999. Foreign aid, the
environment, and welfare. Journal of Development Economies 59:553-64.
Copeland, Brian R. 1994. International trade and the environment:
Policy reform in a polluted small economy. Journal of Environmental
Economies and Management 26:44-65.
Copeland, Brian R. 1996. Pollution content tariffs, environmental
rent shifting, and the control of cross-border pollution. Journal of
International Economics 40:459-76.
Copeland, Brian R., and M. Scott Taylor. 1995. Trade and
transboundary pollution. American Economic Review 85:716-37.
Copeland, Brian R., and M. Scott Taylor. 1997. A simple model of
trade, capital mobility and the environment. NBER Working Paper No.
5898.
Hatzipanayotou, Panos, Sajal Lahiri, and Michael S. Michael. 2002.
Can cross-border pollution reduce pollution? Canadian Journal of
Economics 35:805-18.
Hatzipanayotou, Panos, Sajal Lahiri, and Michael S. Michael. 2005.
Reforms of environmental policies in the presence of cross-border
pollution and public-private clean-up. Scandinavian Journal of Economics
107:315-33.
Linster, Myriam, and Frederique Zegel. 2003. Pollution abatement
and control expenditure in OECD countries. Discussion paper, OECD.
Ludema, Rodney D., and Ian Wooton. 1997. International trade rules
and environmental cooperation under asymmetric information.
International Economic Review 38:605-25.
Rauscher, Michael. 1991. National environmental policies and the
effects of economic integration. European Journal of Political Economy
7:313-29.
Rauscher, Michael. 1997. International trade, factor movements, and
the environment. New York: Clarendon Press.
Silva, Emilson C. D., and Arthur J. Caplan. 1997. Transboundary
pollution control in federal systems. Journal of Environmental Economics
and Management 34:173-86.
Turunen-Red, Arja H., and Alan D. Woodland. 2004. Multilateral
reforms of trade and environmental policy. Review of International
Economics 12:321-36.
Costas Hadjiyiannis, * Panos Hatzipanayotou, ([dagger]) and Michael
S. Michael ([double dagger])
* Department of Economics, University of Cyprus, P.O. Box 20537,
1678 Nicosia, Cyprus; E-mail costah@ucy.ac.cy; corresponding author.
([dagger]) DIEES, Athens University of Economics and Business 76
Patission str., Athens 104 34, Greece; E-mail hatzip@aueb.gr.
([double dagger]) Department of Economics, University of Cyprus,
P.O. Box 20537, 1678 Nicosia, Cyprus; E-mail m.s.michael@ucy.ac.cy.
(1) In particular, table 3b of the same report provides evidence
that in many countries a significant part of the financing of
cross-border pollution abatement is undertaken by the government. For
example, in 1994 the U.S. government spent 0.3% of the GDP on abating
air pollution, which accounted for 33% of the total expenditure on air
pollution abatement. In the period ranging from 1990 to 2000, punic PAC
expenditures as a percentage of total PAC expenditures averaged 55% in
Canada, Finland, France, and Korea; 77% in Germany; 35% in Japan; and
40% in the United States.
(2) The OECD, in a 2003 workshop report, provides evidence that
many countries impose emission taxes. For example, most European Union
(EU) countries, including the United Kingdom, Germany, France, and
Italy, impose energy and C[O.sub.2] taxes (see Bygrave and Ellis 2003).
(3) Following the standard convention, we denote all the variables
of the foreign country with an asterisk.
(4) The model may resemble the case of a region---either with all
its members developed (e.g., EU), some developed, and some developing
(e.g., NAFTA), or two regions in a federal state vis-a-vis the rest of
the world. In such a context, there is free commodity trade within the
region and nearly free commodity trade between the region and the rest
of the world.
(5) For simplicity, we assume only one type of pollution emission
is generated in one sector. A prime (') denotes a transposed vector
or matrix, and p'x - tz is the value of factor income. Finally,
[PHI](v, K) includes production technologies and abatement technologies
in various private sectors, as they carry out some pollution abatement
in response to the emission tax (t).
(6) Copeland (1994) and Turunen-Red and Woodland (2004), among
others, define pollution in the same way.
(7) This formulation of additive level of net pollution, r, implies
that the two countries emit the same pollutant. Generalizing the present
specification to one in which the two countries emit different types of
pollutants only results to unwarranted algebraic complications without
providing substantive analytical insight.
(8) Lump-sum taxes can be positive or negative depending on whether
pollution tax revenues cover abatement costs. This means that the
government has two policy instruments. One can think of the government
choosing t and T, with g being residually determined, or choosing t and
g, with T determined residually to balance the budget. The two
formulations are equivalent.
(9) In Copeland's (1994) terminology, [E.sub.r] is a measure
of the marginal damage to consumers from pollution.
(10) The cost of the public pollution abatement good may be
different in the two countries for country-specific reasons, such as
transportation or transaction costs. The case of [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is a special case of the more
general specification presented in this paper.
(11) The effects of environmental policies on pollution, without
public sector abatement, in the presence of capital mobility are
examined in other studies, such as that of Rauscher (1991) and Copeland
and Taylor (1997).
(12) The third effect is a "leakage effect," by which
higher domestic emission taxes raise production in Foreign and so raise
pollution in Foreign; hence, lower domestic pollution "leaks"
into Foreign production.
(13) Hatzipanayotou, Lahiri, and Michael (2002) examine the effect
of a higher t on r in a model with [THETA] = 0 and no capital mobility.
(14) All derivatives presented in the paper assume that all other
instruments are given.
(15) Recall that in this model, lump-sum taxes are exclusively used
to finance public abatement. Thus, with t fixed, dT [P.sub.g]dg, and,
hence, for welfare considerations what really matters is du/dg. That is,
[p.sub.g](du/dT) = (du/dg) = [S.sub.g]/[E.sub.u] [??] 0.
(16) In Appendix A, this is shown by the last term (i.e.,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]) of the reduced form
of Equation (17).
(17) Throughout the analysis, we assume interior solutions for the
policy instruments and for interior allocations of capital and pollution
levels.
(18) If g and t are used as the policy instruments and T is
determined residually, the corresponding optimality conditions are
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. Therefore, the
cooperative first-best rules are again given by Equations 21 and 22.
(19) The Samuelson rule for [lambda] [not equal to] 1 is a modified
one in which international transfers are not feasible. The inclusion of
public abatement leads to non-trivial results compared to the case in
which g = [g.sup.*] = 0, as shown in the last section of the paper.
(20) Combining the first two terms in brackets in the numerator of
Equation 23 we obtain [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII], which is positive if [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII] (sufficient but not necessary condition). That is, the total
effect of an increase in capital on its return, direct and indirect
through changes in pollution, is negative.
(21) The general expressions for the Nash pollution taxes when
lump-sum taxes are not chosen optimally are given in Appendix A.
(22) This is the well-known NIMBY (Not In My Back Yard) effect.
That is, in the absence of cross-border pollution, shifting capital away
reduces pollution and raises welfare.
(23) In this case, [t.sup.N] > [P.sub.g] to capture terms of
trade gains in the capital market. That is, the payments to foreign
capital are reduced as a result of the higher t. This is one of the
cases that the government wants to restrict access of firms to the
pollution abatement good.
(24) Case 5 states sufficient conditions for [t.sup.N] >
[P.sub.g] > [t.sup.c], while in case 6 if k is large enough, then
[t.sup.c] > [t.sup.N] > [P.sub.g].
(25) Note that when the two countries are identical [t.sup.N] =
[tsup.c] = [P.sub.g] and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII]. In this case the government can allow private firms to use the
imported pollution abatement good since the private benefit is equal to
the social benefit. In all other cases, the government is better off by
restricting access to this good to capture terms of trade gains.
(26) An interesting extension to this paper is to consider the
strategic adoption of pollution abatement technologies before deciding
on taxes.