Comment on "the diffusion of a medical innovation: is success in the stars?".
Huesch, Marco D.
JEL Classification: UO, UI, O33
1. Introduction
Burke, Fournier, and Prasad (2007), henceforth BFP, recently
presented in these pages an important and path-breaking exploration of
social learning models, noting potential welfare consequences of
heterogeneous diffusions of innovations in medicine.
Unfortunately, while I am broadly sympathetic to the central
hypothesis of social learning in medical practice, there remains a
series of questions regarding the conceptual model of BFP. (1)
Establishing the claim that social influences may significantly affect
the timing and rate of technological adoption among physicians would be
easier if these key issues were addressed differently. Most prominent of
these issues is the possibility of omitting key variables that might
independently explain diffusion of medical innovations.
In this light, it is instructive to consider the backstory to the
classic study of Coleman, Katz, and Menzel (1966), which investigated
the dynamics of physician adoption of tetracycline antibiotics. As BFP
point out, Coleman, Katz, and Menzel found that peer effects mediated by
influential physicians drove adoption. Unfortunately, when Van den Bulte
and Lilien (2001) reanalyzed Coleman's data and controlled for
pharmaceutical company marketing mix variables, the conclusion was that
peer effects were no longer significant drivers of adoption.
Notwithstanding these comments, I conjecture that the heterogeneous
adoption observed in practice is' due to serious structural issues
(principally the unequal distribution of higher volume teaching and
for-profit hospitals, rather than unequal distributions of particular
star physicians). BFP's central conclusion on the resultant unequal
adoption/utilization entailing welfare costs is thus likely to remain an
important and urgent one, albeit one even less amenable to policy
changes.
2. A Series of Model Questions
In BFP's conceptual model, star physicians (defined as having
completed residency at top medical schools) systematically influence the
adoption hazard and utilization rate (conditional on adoption) of
nonstar physicians. But several difficulties underlie this prima facie
natural hypothesis of social influence. These may be summarized as (i)
the proposed mechanism of influence; (ii) the absence of hospital
time-based effects; (iii) the discarding of the distinction between
attending and operating physician; and (iv) the inclusion of nonadopting
stars in the model.
First, it is unfortunately not made clear, nor is it intuitive, how
a star's residency school prestige might actually drive opinion
leadership and social influence. Moreover, no other potential locus of
social influence, apart from residency school (on average, a dozen years
antecedent in the study's sample, and up to 25 years distant),
seems to have been considered by BFP. (2) Incorporating age (closely
correlated with tenure and hierarchical status within a hospital, and
inferable from graduation year, though unlikely to survive fixed
effects), cumulative angioplasty volume (inferable, though top censored,
from the panel), and periodic performance, such as mortality and
morbidity rates (available from the discharge status data), as well as
their interactions with residency status, ought to strengthen their
social influence model. (3)
In a related vein, one wonders how much or how little residency
status is correlated with other possible mediators of social influence.
If star status were correlated with, say, a position as chief of
cardiology in a large hospital, then might that position and place not
be the actual mechanism of influence? If not correlated, what would such
positional authority add in terms of model predictive power?
The second area in which the model ought to be strengthened is by
incorporating the time-varying influence of the overarching institution
embedding the physicians--the hospital. This is restricted by the
authors to a time-invariant fixed effect. In Burke, Fournier, and Prasad
(2007), it is pointed out that "if hospitals implement updated
practice guidelines for stent usage at irregular intervals, fixed
effects for hospitals are not sufficient" (Burke, Fournier, and
Prasad 2007, p. 601). Interestingly, they do include quarterly time
dummies, "[which] may proxy for the influence of the lagged
statewide adoption rate" (Burke, Fournier, and Prasad 2007 p. 594).
An additional highly plausible time-based effect is cumulative
collocated total hospital experience with stents and angioplasties in
general. As the whole operating room team and the hospital's
various departments become more comfortable with stent use, local
spillover dynamics becomes a very feasible mechanism driving increased
adoption and utilization. Analogously, in Huckman and Pisano (2006) it
is shown that the mortality benefits of experience gained by a physician
through current volume in one hospital are not portable to her work
elsewhere: The institution matters.
Of course, as Ho (2002) pointed out in a related analysis of stent
diffusion, the autocollinearity occasioned by the positive serial
correlation in some of these data series can be serious. For example,
time series of hospital stent caseloads (period or cumulative) will
necessarily display strong positive serial correlation. Nonetheless,
even point estimates and upper bounds on confidence intervals may still
serve the authors well.
A third and closely related conceptual issue is the distinction
between the two types and roles of the physician delivering treatment:
the "operating physician" and the "attending
physician." The latter has complete legal and clinical
responsibility for the patient's care during the admission, while
the former performs the intervention in the catheterization lab. The
latter is moreover obliged to marshal the hospital's entire
resources in support of the patient's care, and thus would appear
to be sensitive to the hospital's experience and preferences in
regard to stent usage. BFP apparently used just the operating physician
as the unit of analysis; although, approximately half of all stent
admissions have different physicians in the two roles, and the relative
social influences of these two roles are thus important. Since the
dataset will contain both data fields, it would be instructive to
understand the magnitude and direction of the attending physician's
social influence, especially given her overarching legal responsibility
for her admitted patient.
A final conceptual problem is that BFP acknowledge that star
physicians neither adopt earlier nor utilize the stent innovation more
than nonstars. (4) Indeed BFP hypothesize simply that
"...innovation will spread faster among nonstars in places where
influential physicians [stars] operate" (Burke, Fournier, and
Prasad 2007, p. 597). On the one hand, if this implies that stars who
don't adopt stents somehow contemporaneously influence nonstars to
adopt, then a deeper problem of logic seems to exist in this model. (5)
On the other hand, if such nonadopting stars do not have such an
unlikely type of influence, why are they part of the right-hand side
variable [[S.sub.rt]] in the model's equations 1 and 2?
Shouldn't such relatively dull stars have been isolated and removed
from their brighter star peers in the adoption model (as they seem to
have been from the utilization model)? The presence of these nonadopting
stars in [S.sub.rt] risks biasing the coefficient on the focal
variable--the impact of the number of stars encountered upward.
3. Conclusions
BFP deserve recognition and praise for venturing into an important
and underresearched area. The conceptual questions raised here do,
however, impinge on the overall persuasiveness of their study and may
render some of their more marginal results more likely to be due to
chance alone. Further investigations are necessary to buttress such
important social influence results. Even more unfortunately (if it turns
out to be the unequal distribution of large hospitals that drives
heterogeneity in the diffusion of such innovations, as opposed to
unequal distributions of stars), it is again likely that ensuing
aggregate social welfare costs are highly resistant to easy policy
fixes.
References
Burke, Mary A., Gary M. Fournier, and Kislaya Prasad. 2007. The
diffusion of a medical innovation: Is success in the stars? Southern
Economic Journal 73:588-603.
Coleman, James S., Elihu Katz, and Herbert Menzel. 1966. Medical
innovation: A diffusion study. Indianapolis, IN: Bobbs-Merrill.
Ho, Vivian. 2002. Learning and the evolution of medical
technologies: The diffusion of coronary angioplasty. Journal of Health
Economics 21:873-85.
Huckman, Rob, and Gary Pisano. 2006. The firm-specificity of
individual performance: Evidence from cardiac surgery. Management
Science 52:473-88.
Van den Bulte, Cristophe, and Gary L. Lilien. 2001. Medical
innovation revisited: Social contagion versus marketing effort. The
American Journal of Sociology 106:1409-35.
(1) My experience as a practicing hospital physician leads me to be
biased toward the acceptance of the importance of social learning and
peer influence in hospital delivery of medical and surgical services.
(2) Consider our own academic sources of influence: number of
papers, endowment budgets, and teaching ratings position. Anecdotally,
the earned doctorate often figures more in negative analyses of the form
"despite coming from a top school, she is not publishing
enough."
(3) In a hospital's monthly Mortality and Morbidity meetings,
caseload, outcomes, and summaries of performance are available for all
gathered cardiologists. Similar interactions between status and realized
performance would be observed in cardiologist practice groups because
these physicians prefer to practice in groups.
(4) An open question, tangentially related: The stars' impact
on the profound adoption decision is only marginally significant, while
the impact on utilization is considerably less likely to be due to
chance alone. But changes in utilization could be much more a continuous
function of individual skill and cumulative experience (i.e., own
learning), and arguably less susceptible to peer influence.
(5) Because "Do as I say, not as I do" seems a
particularly unlikely summary of a mechanism of opinion leadership.
I thank the referee and the coeditor for valuable comments and
suggestions, l am also grateful to Mary Burke for helpful answers to
earlier questions. Usual caveats apply.
Marco D. Huesch, The Anderson School of Management at UCLA
Anderson, D513, 110 Westwood Plaza, Los Angeles, CA 90095, USA; E-mail
mhuesch@anderson.ucla.edu.
Received August 2007; accepted April 2008.