Does low education delay structural transformation?
Basu, Parantap ; Guariglia, Alessandra
1. Introduction
What determines the pace of industrialization is a highly debatable topic in the macrodevelopment literature. Hansen and Prescott (2002)
and, subsequently, Gollin, Parente, and Rogerson (2002, 2007a, b)
highlight the role of agricultural productivity in the process of
industrialization. The former develop a model in which the transition
from agriculture to industry is brought about by faster technological
progress in the industrial sector (which ultimately makes this sector
more cost effective) and is slowed by higher productivity in the
agricultural sector. On the other hand, the key point made by Gollin,
Parente, and Rogerson is that most of the late industrializing countries
began the process of industrialization late because of low agricultural
productivity. Their models show that once a society produces the basic
nutritional requirement of food, labor starts moving from agriculture to
industry. From that point onward, agriculture loses its importance
asymptotically, and a Solow technology prevails in the long-run. While
these papers provide useful insights about the process of
industrialization, they remain largely silent about the role of human
capital, knowledge, and skills as factors determining the pace of
industrialization.
We construct a neoclassical growth model that builds on Gollin,
Parente, and Rogerson (2002) and places particular emphasis on the role
of human capital in determining the pace of industrialization.
Specifically, the return to the investment in education drives the
initial human capital and the productivity of raw labor of a
preindustrial society. The model aims to explain why the process of
industrialization is delayed in economies with low initial human capital
and low agricultural productivity.
In a nutshell, our model is characterized both by a food
subsistence constraint and a human capital constraint on the pace of
industrialization of the economy: To industrialize and make a transition
to long-run growth, a society needs to provide the minimum subsistence
level of food to its people, and to invest enough in education to cross
a threshold level of skill. Because a fixed amount of time is assumed to
be allocated to the production of goods and the accumulation of human
capital, a society embarking on the path of industrialization has to
face a painful tradeoff between the food subsistence requirement and the
minimum human capital requirement. We starkly portray this tradeoff in
terms of a belt-tightening strategy of industrialization, whereby agents
consume just the bare subsistence amount of food and invest the surplus
in education until their offspring will have accumulated the threshold
human capital necessary to achieve long-run growth. Industrialization is
therefore the result of a generational belt-tightening strategy. This is
an endeavor the society finds optimal. A lower initial human capital and
a lower agricultural productivity will both lead to a longer
belt-tightening period, which, in turn, will lead to a slower pace of
industrialization. Thus, agricultural productivity and initial human
capital are both important determinants of the pace of structural
transformation of an economy. (1)
We next set up a baseline model calibrated to historical data for
the United Kingdom to trace out the path of gross domestic product (GDP)
during the pre- and postindustrialization phase (1830-2001). Our
interest in this paper is in the Second Industrial Revolution, which
started roughly in the late nineteenth century, following the discovery
of electricity, and which also initiated the era of modernization in
both the United Kingdom and the United States (Devine 1983; Atkeson and
Kehoe 2007). Our calibration exercise suggests that, for empirically
plausible parameter values, a belt-tightening strategy of
industrialization is optimal. Our calibrated model performs well in
replicating actual historical U.K. real GDP per capita series during the
era following the Second Industrial Revolution. The model also has
useful insights about the cross-country correlations between
agricultural productivity, education, and the degree of
industrialization observed in the data. Finally, the same model explains
reasonably well past and recent cross-country variations in per capita
income levels.
Although we do not explicitly model fertility, our model has some
indirect connections with the neo-Malthusian growth literature dealing
with human capital and fertility. A recent wave of this literature
(Becker, Murphy, and Tamura 1990; Galor and Weil 2000) shows that, in
response to technological progress and higher returns to child quality,
the process of industrialization is accompanied by a substitution of
quality for quantity of children. (2) Our model introduces two
investment-specific technology parameters (one for the pre- and the
other for the postindustrialization phase), which characterize the
returns to human capital and may be seen as proxies for the returns to
child quality. Nations with higher returns to human capital carry out
the process of transformation from a preindustrial to an industrial
state faster. (3)
The rest of the paper is laid out as follows: In the following
section, we present some stylized facts aimed at providing empirical
support for our hypothesis that both agricultural productivity and
initial schooling are important determinants of the pace of
industrialization of countries. In section 3, we lay out our theoretical
model. Section 4 calibrates the model to the structural transformation
of the United Kingdom over the period 1830-2001. Section 5 illustrates
the model's predictions about the role of differences in initial
human capital in explaining past and recent variations in cross-country
levels of per capita income. Section 6 concludes.
2. Some Stylized Facts
In this section we report some stylized facts about the time path
of cross-country human capital and some cross-country correlations
between global human capital, agricultural productivity, and the rate of
industrialization. This exercise is motivated by our hypothesis that a
combination of agricultural productivity and initial level of human
capital may determine the pace of industrialization of countries.
We measure the degree of industrialization of a country using its
share of agriculture in GDP (i.e., its ratio of value added coming from
agriculture to GDP): More industrialized countries (or countries that
have industrialized earlier) will display lower shares of agriculture.
Agricultural productivity is measured by the agriculture value added per
worker. Both agricultural productivity and share of agriculture to GDP
data are taken from the World Bank Development Indicators (2002). Human
capital for a given country is proxied by average total schooling years
(including primary, secondary, and higher education) of the population
aged 15 and over in that country. (4) These data are taken from the
Barro and Lee (2000) data set, which covers the period 1960-1999.
We average our data over nonoverlapping five-year periods, so that,
data permitting, there are eight observations per country (1960-1964,
1965-1969, 1970-1974, 1975-1979, 1980-1984, 1985-1989, 1990-1994,
1995-1999). We take five-year averages of all our variables because the
schooling years variable is available only at such intervals. Our data
set is, therefore, a panel made up of 90 countries over eight time
periods. A full list of the 90 countries can be found in Appendix 1.
An important clarification is in order here. Given that
industrialization is a prolonged process dating back to the eighteenth
century, one needs to be cautious in interpreting the available data,
which start from 1960. We do not claim that all the countries in our
sample started industrializing in or after the common reference year of
1960. Nor do we claim that the forces that drive the change in the share
of agriculture or schooling are identical for all countries in the
sample. In the same spirit as Lucas (2003), we perform our statistical
exercise with a 40-year span of data assuming that the initial year in
the sample (1960) is just a part of the period of transition from
preindustrial to industrial growth, which started a long time ago.
Table 1 reports the cross-country average human capital and the
cross-country average share of agriculture for our eight time periods.
These numbers provide a broad measure of the level of global human
capital and the degree of global industrialization (based on our
sample). The table suggests that, over our 40-year time span, both the
global knowledge and the global rate of industrialization have risen.
(5)
Table 2 reports cross-country correlations between the time average
of the share of agriculture, the time average of agricultural
productivity, and the initial (start of period) human capital level. It
appears that countries with lower initial human capital and lower
average agricultural productivity exhibit higher shares of agriculture
to GDP and are therefore less industrialized. This lower level of
industrialization suggests that these countries have started the
industrialization process late.
Although not necessarily indicators of any cause-effect
relationship, these stylized facts are consistent with our hypothesis
that both agricultural productivity and initial human capital can
determine the pace of industrialization of countries. In the following
section, we develop a model that broadly accords with these stylized
facts.
3. The Model
The Basic Framework
Preferences
There are two types of goods in the economy: agricultural goods
(denoted with the subscript a), which can be intended as food, and
manufacturing goods (denoted with the subscript m). Following Gollin,
Parente, and Rogerson (2007b), the instantaneous utility function for
agents is given by
U([c.sub.a], [c.sub.m]) = [c.sub.a] when [omega] [less than or
equal to] [c.sub.a] < [bar.a]
= [bar.a] + [c.sup.1 - [gamma].sub.m] - 1/1 - [gamma] when
[c.sub.a] [greater than or equal to] [bar.a], (1)
where [c.sub.a] and [c.sub.m] denote consumption of agricultural
and manufacturing goods, respectively, and [gamma] [greater than or
equal to] 0. Here [omega] represents the minimum subsistence level of
consumption below which agents fail to survive, and [bar.a] is a
saturation level of agricultural consumption; once that level is
reached, agents start caring about manufacturing goods.
Agents maximize the following lifetime utility function
[[infinity].summation over (t = 0)] [[beta].sup.t]U([c.sub.at],
[c.sub.mt]), (2)
where [beta] is the subjective discount factor.
Production
The production structure builds on Basu and Guariglia (2007). (6)
There are two distinct stages of development: a preindustrial stage
(stage 1. indexed with 1) and an industrial stage (stage 2, indexed with
2). There is a single reproducible input called human capital (or
effective labor), which is used for the production of the two types of
goods (food and manufacturing goods). Investment takes the form of human
capital accumulation. There is a representative agent who has one unit
of time, which she allocates between the production of goods and human
capital formation (i.e., education). This kind of time allocation gives
rise to endogenous growth in a similar spirit as in Lucas (1988).
During the preindustrial stage, the economy has poor
infrastructures. There are institutional barriers to the diffusion of
knowledge, such as a poor public school system or a lack of Internet
access. (7) These impediments are reflected in diminishing returns to
education or knowledge. During the industrial stage, because of the
absence of these barriers, the return to education is no longer
diminishing. We assume that the modern investment technology is subject
to constant returns. In addition, we assume that there is a nonconvexity
in the industrial technology: To access it, one requires a minimum
amount of human capital, [h.sub.min].
Let us denote with [h.sub.t] human capital at time t; with
[N.sub.at] and [N.sub.mt] the time spent at time t on the production of
food and manufacturing goods, respectively; with [delta] the rate of
depreciation; and with z and A the investment-specific technology (IST)
parameters characterizing the returns to human capital during the
preindustrial and industrial stages, respectively. (8)
The preindustrial and industrial technologies are, therefore, the
following: First, preindustrial technology (operating when [h.sub.t]
< [h.sub.min]):
[c.sup.(1).sub.at] = [N.sup.(1).sub.at][h.sup.(1).sub.t], (3)
[h.sup.(1).sub.t + 1] = (1 - [delta])[h.sup.(1).sub.t] + z[(1 -
[N.sup.(1).sub.at]).sup.[alpha]][h.sup.(1)[alpha].sub.t], where 0 <
[alpha] < 1. (4)
In stage 1, because the initial human capital stock is lower than
[h.sub.min], the country produces food only with the technology given by
Equation 3. At time t the agent allocates [N.sup.(1).sub.at] units of
her time to the production of food, and (1 - [Na.sup.(1).sub.at]) units
to education, which is augmented through the IST parameter z. (9)
Second, industrial technology (operating when [h.sub.t] [greater
than or equal to] [h.sub.min]):
[bar.a] = [N.sup.(2).sub.at][h.sup.(2).sub.t], (5)
[c.sup.(2).sub.mt] = [N.sup.(2).sub.mt][h.sup.(2).sub.t], (6)
[h.sup.(2).sub.t + 1] = (1 - [delta])[h.sup.(2).sub.t] + A(1 -
[N.sup.(2).sub.at] - [N.sup.(2).sub.mt])[h.sup.(2).sub.t]. (7)
In stage 2 the country produces both food and manufacturing goods
because it can operate the technologies illustrated in Equations 5 and
6. During this industrialized phase, the agent derives utility from both
food and manufacturing goods. Because of the utility function (1), the
agent just produces and consumes [bar.a] units of food and invests
resources just sufficient to sustain this saturation level of food.
Specifically, at time t, [N.sup.(2).sub.at] units of the agent's
time are allocated to the production of food; [N.sup.(2).sub.mt] units,
to the production of manufacturing goods; and (1 - [N.sup.(2).sub.at] -
[N.sup.(2).sub.mt]) units, to education, which is augmented through the
IST parameter A.
Initial Stock of Human Capital
A preindustrial economy starts off with a low level of human
capital, [h.sup.(1).sub.0], which is insufficient to access the modern
technology. In other words, we assume that [h.sup.(1).sub.0] <
[h.sub.min].
Resource Constraints
For stage 1, combining Equations 3 and 4 yields the following human
capital accumulation equation:
[h.sup.(1).sub.t + 1] = (1 - [delta])[h.sup.(1).sub.t] +
z[([h.sup.(1).sub.t] - [c.sub.at]).sup.[alpha]]. (8)
Similarly, for stage 2, combining Equations 5, 6, and 7, one gets
the following sequential resource constraint:
[bar.a] + [c.sub.mt] + [h.sup.*(2).sub.t + 1] - (1 -
[delta])[h.sup.*(2).sub.t] = A[h.sup.*(2).sub.t], where
[h.sup.*(2).sub.t] = [h.sup.(2).sub.t] / A. (9)
Growth in the Industrial Stage
We first characterize the equilibrium growth during the stage 2
phase of industrialization. In this case the country has attained the
minimum human capital, [h.sub.min], and has access to the technologies
illustrated in Equations 5 and 6. The industrial agent thus maximizes
Equation 2 subject to Equation 9. Given this structure, we have the
following proposition:
PROPOSITION 1. For a sufficiently large [h.sub.min] (i.e.,
[h.sub.min] > A[bar.a]/(A - [delta])), the human capital of the
industrial agent grows and reaches an asymptotic rate given by
[[[beta](A + 1 - [delta])].sup.1/[gamma]].
PROOF. The intertemporal first-order condition of the industrial
agent is given by
[c.sup.(2).sub.mt + 1]/[c.sup.(2).sub.mt] = G, (10)
where G = [[[beta](A + 1 - [delta])].sup.1/[gamma]]. Plugging
Equation 9 into Equation 10, we obtain the following second-order
difference equation in [h.sup.(2).sub.t]:
[h.sup.(2).sub.t + 2] - (B + G)[h.sup.(2).sub.t + 1] +
BG[h.sup.(2).sub.t] = (G - 1)A[bar.a], (11)
where B = A + 1 - [delta]. The general solution to this difference
equation is given by
[h.sup.(2).sub.t] = [A.sub.1][B.sup.t] + [A.sub.2][G.sup.t] +
A[bar.a]/A - [delta], (12)
where [A.sub.1] and [A.sub.2] are determined by the initial and
terminal conditions. (10) The initial condition is characterized by
[h.sub.min]. The terminal condition is given by the transversality condition (TVC) as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] (13)
We next show that the TVC requires that [A.sub.1] in Equation 12
must equal zero. We prove this by contradiction. If not, then
[h.sup.(2).sub.t] grows at a rate B because B > [beta]B. On the other
hand, [c.sup.(2).sub.mt] grows at a rate G as in Equation 10. Thus, the
left-hand side of Equation 13 inside the limit operator reduces to
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (14)
which does not converge to zero as T approaches infinity if [gamma]
[greater than or equal to] 1. Consequently, if [h.sup.(2).sub.t] grows
at rate (A + 1 - [delta]), the TVC is violated.
We have thus established that the optimal solution for
[h.sup.(2).sub.t] must be
[h.sup.(2).sub.t] = [A.sub.2][(G).sup.t] + A[bar.a]/A - [delta],
(15)
where [A.sub.2] is characterized by the initial stock of human
capital as follows:
[A.sub.2] = [h.sup.(2).sub.0] - A[bar.a]/A - [delta]. (16)
Next, note that [h.sup.(2).sub.0] = [h.sub.min], because the
industrial country starts its trajectory when it achieves [h.sub.min].
As long as [h.sub.min] > A[bar.a]/(A - [delta]), human capital in the
modern sector will grow and eventually reach an asymptotic rate G. QED.
In order to grow, the country must have initial human capital in
excess of the amount necessary to sustain the agricultural production of
[bar.a]. This explains why [h.sup.(2).sub.0] must exceed A[bar.a]/(A -
[delta]).
Preindustrial Stage: A Belt-Tightening Strategy of
Industrialization
We now analyze the time path of human capital during the
preindustrial phase. What conditions will ensure that a country will
industrialize starting from a preindustrial phase with low human capital
[h.sup.(1).sub.0]? In order to industrialize, the country must invest
sufficiently in human capital to attain [h.sub.min]. We will now analyze
two alternative scenarios: one in which industrialization is not
achieved and one in which it takes place.
No Industrialization
We first analyze a scenario in which no industrialization takes
place. The following lemma characterizes this scenario:
LEMMA 1. For a sufficiently large [h.sub.min] or a sufficiently low
agricultural IST parameter z, a country cannot industrialize simply by
maximizing lifetime utility from food consumption.
PROOF. If the preindustrial agent just maximizes lifetime utility
from food consumption, that is, maximizes Equation 2 subject to
Equations 3 and 4, the first-order condition is
[M.sub.t] = [alpha][beta][z.sup.1/[alpha] + [beta](1 -
[delta])[M.sub.t + 1], (17)
where
[M.sub.t] = [[h.sup.(1).sub.t + 1] - (1 -
[delta])[h.sup.(1).sub.t]].sup.(1 - [alpha])/[alpha]]. (18)
Solving Equation 17 recursively forward, one gets the following
optimal time path for human capital:
[h.sup.(1).sub.t + 1] = (1 - [delta])[h.sup.(1).sub.t] +
[delta][h.sup.*(1)], (19)
where
[h.sup.*(1)] = 1/[delta] [([alpha][beta]).sup.[alpha]/(1 -
[alpha])][z.sup.1/(1 - [alpha])]/[[1 - [beta](1 -
[delta])].sup.[alpha]/(1 - [alpha])]. (20)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Figure 1 draws the phase diagram illustrating the dynamics of the
preindustrial economy. If z is sufficiently low or [h.sub.min] is
sufficiently high in the sense that [h.sub.min] > [h.sup.*(1)], then
the preindustrial economy will never acquire the minimum skill by just
specializing in food production. QED.
The upshot of this lemma is that a country with a low agricultural
IST parameter (z) will not be able to attain the minimum human capital
[h.sub.min] necessary to access modern technology simply by maximizing
the lifetime utility from food consumption. The country may therefore
need a different strategy of industrialization.
A Belt-Tightening Strategy of Industrialization
Let us now consider an alternative strategy of industrialization,
which consists of agents consuming just the subsistence level, [omega],
for several generations and accumulating human capital until their
offspring reach the [h.sub.min] units of human capital necessary to
operate the modern technology. We call such a strategy a belt-tightening
strategy. Is this generational belt-tightening a feasible strategy for
industrialization? We have the following lemma:
LEMMA 2. Let the agent set the consumption plan [c.sup.(1).sub.at]
= [omega], where [omega] is a small quantity. For a sufficiently large
value of [h.sup.(1).sub.0] or for a sufficiently small [h.sub.min], such
a belt-tightening strategy is feasible.
PROOF. For [c.sup.(1).sub.at] = [omega], the time path of human
capital in the preindustrial stage based on Equation 8 is given by the
following difference equation:
[h.sup.(1).sub.t + 1] = (1 - [delta])[h.sup.(1).sub.t] +
z[([h.sup.(1).sub.t]) - [omega]).sup.[alpha]]. (21)
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Figure 2 plots the phase diagram for Equation 21. For this
belt-tightening strategy to be feasible, it is necessary that
[h.sup.(1).sub.0] > [bar.h] and [h.sub.min] < [??]. QED.
Is Belt-Tightening Optimal?
We hereafter assume that the feasibility conditions for
industrialization set forth in Lemma 2 hold. Let us now pose the
question: Given that this belt-tightening industrialization strategy is
feasible, is it optimal for a country to follow such a strategy?
We answer this question in two steps. First, we determine the value
function ([V.sub.NI]) of the country if it does not industrialize. Next,
we determine the corresponding value function ([V.sub.I](T)) if it
industrializes at some arbitrary date T by following a belt-tightening
strategy. Comparing [V.sub.NI] and [V.sub.I], we determine whether a
belt-tightening strategy is optimal.
We have the following lemma:
LEMMA 3. The life-time utility of not industrializing ([V.sub.NI])
is given by
[V.sub.NI] = ([h.sup.(1).sub.0] - [h.sup.*(1)])/1 - [beta](1 -
[delta]) + 1/(1 - [beta]) [[h.sup.*(1)] -
[([delta][h.sup.*(1)]/z).sup.1/[alpha]]. (22)
PROOF. Note that
[V.sub.NI]([h.sup.(1).sub.0] = [[infinity].summation over (t = 0)]
[[beta].sup.t][c.sub.at]. (23)
Plugging Equation 19 into Equation 8, we obtain the following
optimal consumption policy of the preindustrial agent:
[c.sub.at] = [h.sup.(1).sub.t] - [[[alpha][beta]z/1 - [beta](1 -
[delta])].sup.1/(1 - [alpha])]. (24)
Plugging Equation 24 into Equation 23 and solving the difference
Equation 19, we obtain
[V.sub.NI] ([h.sup.(1).sub.0]) = [[infinity].summation over (t =
0)] [[beta].sup.t] [([h.sup.(1).sub.0] - [h.sup.*(1)]) [(1 -
[delta].sup.t] + [[h.sup.*(1)] - [[alpha][beta]z/1 - [beta](1 -
[delta])].sup.1/(1 - [alpha])]],
which, after simplification, yields Equation 22. QED.
We now characterize the value function when the country adopts a
belt-tightening strategy of industrialization. If the country follows
such a strategy, a time T comes when the human capital [h.sub.min]
necessary for industrialization is attained. Until date T, the
preindustrial agent just consumes the subsistence level [omega]. Beyond
T, she consumes the saturation level of food [bar.a] and makes a
transition to the growing manufacturing sector. The value function
associated with such a belt-tightening strategy, which makes the agent
transform from a preindustrial to an industrial state at some arbitrary
date T, is given by
[V.sub.I](T) = [1 - [[beta].sup.T]/1 - [beta]] [omega] +
[[infinity].summation over (s = T)] [[beta].sup.s] [[bar.a] + [c.sup.1 -
[gamma].sub.ms] - 1/1 - [gamma]]. (25)
From date T onwards, the manufacturing consumption grows at the
rate G, as in Equation 10. We thus have the following lemma:
LEMMA 4. The value function for industrialization at date T is
given by
[V.sub.I](T) = [omega]/1 - [beta] + [[beta].sup.T]/1 - [beta]
{[bar.a] - [omega]}
+ [[beta].sup.T]/1 - [beta][G.sup.1 - [gamma]] [[(c.sup.1 -
[gamma].sub.mT] - 1)/1 - [gamma]] + ([beta]/1 - [beta]) ([G.sup.1 -
[gamma]] - 1)/1 - [gamma]], (26)
where,
[c.sup.(2).sub.mT] = (A + 1 - [delta] - G) [([h.sub.min]/A) -
([bar.a]/A - [delta])]. (11)
From Equation 26, it is straightforward to verify that if [gamma]
is close to unity, [V.sub.I] is monotonically decreasing in T. (12)
Based on Lemmas 3 and 4, and on the monotonicity of [V.sub.I], the
immediate implication is that there exists a [T.sup.*] for which the
country residents are indifferent between industrializing and not
industrializing (i.e., [V.sub.I] = [V.sub.NI]). Figure 3 characterizes
[T.sup.*] as the point where the downward sloping [V.sub.I] schedule
intersects [V.sub.NI].
We are now in a position to determine whether it is optimal for a
country to follow a belt-tightening strategy of industrialization.
Suppose the belt-tightening strategy of industrialization is feasible.
Based on Equation 26, it follows that there exists a time [??] such that
the country achieves [h.sub.min]. (13) Plugging T = [??] into Equation
26, one can easily calculate the value of industrializing at date [??].
In other words, let us define [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII]. Note that belt-tightening is optimal up to [??] if
[[??].sub.I] > [V.sub.NI]. Given that [V.sub.I] is monotonically
decreasing in T, using Figure 3, one can easily verify the following
proposition:
PROPOSITION 2. If [??] < [T.sup.*], a belt-tightening strategy
of industrialization is optimal.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
In the section that follows, we calibrate the model to the
experience of the United Kingdom over the period 1830-2001 and show that
the model reasonably predicts the long-run historical behavior of U.K.
real GDP per capita during the postindustrial revolution era, following
a takeoff. We then use the calibrated structure to examine how the model
performs in predicting the cross-country correlations between
agricultural productivity, education, and the degree of
industrialization, as well as past and recent cross-country income
differences.
4. Model Calibration
Our first task is to calibrate the model parameters in such a way
that the model broadly matches the pre- and postindustrial history of
the United Kingdom. This will form our baseline model, which we will
then use to predict cross-country income differences.
Identifying the Date of Industrialization for the United Kingdom
We first identify the date at which the United Kingdom
industrialized. To do so, we focus on the Second Industrial Revolution,
which occurred sometime between 1860 and 1900 and was characterized by
the invention of a large number of technologies based on electricity,
which ultimately led to an economy characterized by a faster
productivity growth (Devine 1983; Atkeson and Kehoe 2007). It is not
entirely clear exactly when this transformation took place in the United
Kingdom. We set 1880 as the date of this transformation, as this was the
date in which education was made compulsory throughout the United
Kingdom for children aged 5 to 10, establishing, for the first time, a
formal schooling system and therefore fostering human capital formation
and technical progress.
The establishment of a compulsory formal schooling system in the
United Kingdom in 1880 can be interpreted as the establishment of a main
channel of human capital formation, replacing the informal acquisition
of skills, which previously took place mainly through on-the-job
training. This was an important breakthrough in the United Kingdom,
where the development of a national public system of education lagged
behind that of the Continental countries (Sanderson 1995). We use 1880
as our proxy for [??] because we feel that making education compulsory
played a fundamental role in fostering human capital formation and
technical progress in the United Kingdom. (14)
Schooling Years: Human Capital Technology
We next face the challenge that there is no empirical counterpart of the broadly measured human capital stock, [h.sub.t], used in our
model. Conventionally, average years of schooling are used as a proxy
for human capital (see, e.g., Bils and Klenow 2000). However, the
problem in using such a proxy arises from the fact that the human
capital state variable is unbounded in our model; whereas, the schooling
years are upward bounded. One thus needs to convert bounded schooling
years ([s.sub.t]) into unbounded human capital stock ([h.sub.t]),
consistent with our semi-endogenous growth model. To this end, we posit
the following functional form for our human capital technology:
[h.sub.t] = Q [[bar.s].sup.[theta]]/[([bar.s] -
[s.sub.t]).sup.[theta]], (27)
where 0 [less than or equal to] [s.sub.t] [less than or equal to]
[bar.s], [bar.s] > 1, [theta] > 0, and Q > 0. Here [bar.s] is
the upper bound for schooling years, which is fixed at 18 years,
encompassing postgraduate education. The parameters Q and [theta]
represent the quality of schooling: Both impact the marginal
contribution of schooling to human capital in different ways. Given Q
and [theta], as [s.sub.t] approaches its upper bound [bar.s], human
capital approaches infinity. The parameter [theta] determines how fast
human capital approaches infinity, while Q is just a scale parameter.
(15) We next calibrate the baseline parameters of our model.
Choice of Baseline Parameters
The next step is to calibrate the model parameters on the basis of
some observables. There are four preference parameters ([beta], [gamma],
[bar.a], and [omega]); four technology parameters ([alpha], [delta], z,
A); and four human capital parameters ([h.sub.0], [h.sub.min], Q, and
[theta]).
Calibrating the Preference Parameters
Consistent with a real interest rate of 5% as in Gollin, Parente,
and Rogerson (2002), and noting that the economy is stationary during
the preindustrial phase, we fix [beta] at 0.95. We set the value of
[gamma] at 1.01, which approximates logarithmic preferences. (16)
Regarding the other two preference parameters, [bar.a] and [omega], only
one of them can be normalized. We choose to normalize [bar.a] to unity
and then find the value of [omega], which is consistent with the minimum
nutritional requirement of an individual of average height, weight, and
age. Numerous nutritional studies (see, e.g., Somer 2004) and
consultations with U.K. National Health Service practitioners suggest
that the ratio of minimum to maximum calorie intake of such an average
individual is about 1/2. We therefore fix [omega] at 0.5. (17)
Calibrating the Technology Parameters
We have four technology parameters: [alpha], [beta], A, and z.
Ideally, one would like to find an observable corresponding to each of
these parameters. This is not always possible in the context of our
model. We therefore adopted the following strategy. We searched for
values of [alpha] and [delta], which kept the belt-tightening strategy
just feasible. Doing so, we arrived at [alpha] equal to 0.69 and [delta]
equal to 0.01. The parameter [alpha] is conceptually close to the value
of output elasticity of human capital in Bandyopadhyay and Basu (2005).
Regarding the depreciation parameter, note that (1 - [delta]) can be
interpreted as the rate of intergenerational spillover of knowledge in
the tradition of Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992) and Benabou (2000). A
low value of [delta] means that the rate of intergenerational spillover
of knowledge is high. When calibrating cross-country growth-inequality
correlations, Bandyopadhyay and Basu (2005) use a value of [delta]
similar to ours.
Coming to the IST parameters, we fix A consistently with the
post-1880 average annual GDP growth rate of 1.4% documented in Maddison
(2003). (18) The IST parameters z and A are closely related to labor
productivities in the agriculture and manufacturing sectors,
respectively. Using Mitchell (1992), we observe that the relative labor
productivity of manufacturing with respect to agriculture was 1.229 in
1880. Given the close link between labor productivities and IST
parameters, we take this relative productivity as a proxy for the ratio
of A to z. The year 1880 is chosen because, according to our model, from
this year onwards, both pre- and postindustrial technologies became
accessible to the U.K. economy. In this way, we obtain a value of z
equal to 0.063.
Calibrating the Human Capital Parameters
The next task is to fix the values of the initial human capital,
[h.sup.(1).sub.0], and the threshold human capital, [h.sub.min]. The
value of [h.sup.(1).sub.0] is fixed at the preindustrial steady state
level, [h.sup.*(1)]. Using Equation 20, this leads to a value of 2.87.
Regarding the calibration of [h.sub.min], we first fix the terminal
human capital stock in 2001 using the share of agriculture in GDP, which
is equal to 1% in that year (World Bank Development Indicators 2005).
This gives us a terminal human capital stock equal to 100. (19) In the
next step we iterate the optimal investment policy rule (Eqn. 15)
backwards until we hit 1880, which is our proposed date of second
industrialization in the United Kingdom. The stock of human capital in
1880 obtained in this way is our [h.sub.min], which, given the other
baseline parameter values, is found to be 19.78.
Since the United Kingdom is our baseline model, we compute the
schooling technology parameters Q and [theta] based on the minimum
schooling years in the United Kingdom in 1880 (five years), which are
associated with human capital equal to [h.sub.min], and the recent
minimum schooling years (11 years), which are associated with our
terminal human capital stock. (20) Based on Equation 27, and given that
[h.sub.min] is equal to 19.78, and the terminal human capital stock to
100, we obtain two equations, one for [s.sub.t] = 5, and the other for
[s.sub.t] = 11, which we solve for the two unknown parameters Q and
[theta]. This implies a value for Q of 8.44 and a value for [theta] of
2.62. Table 3 summarizes these baseline parameter values.
Baseline Calibration Results
Using the calibrated parameter values and assuming that the initial
stock of human capital is fixed at the preindustrial steady state, we
use the model to estimate the year in which the United Kingdom started
to belt-tighten. We find that the time to industrialize is 92 years for
the U.K. economy, meaning that in order to acquire [h.sub.min] in 1880,
the United Kingdom started its belt-tightening in 1788. For the same set
of parameter values, we also find that [T.sup.*] is equal to 110 years,
which means that the optimality condition set forth in Proposition 2
holds.
Figure 4 plots the GDP index, based on the baseline model, and
compares it with the corresponding real data for the U.K. economy over
the period 1830-2001. (21) By construction of the model, output
experiences a discrete jump in 1880, when the critical minimum human
capital [h.sub.min] is attained, and then merges with the long-run
growth path in 1881. (22) This discrete jump in output is due to the
stylized nature of the model. Despite its stylized nature, the baseline
model performs well in matching the historical post-1880 U.K. GDP
series.
On other fronts the model also performs reasonably well. For
example, it predicts a secular decline in the share of agriculture in
GDP. Figure 5 plots the U.K. share of agriculture in GDP predicted by
the model since 1801 and compares it with the actual data taken from
Mitchell (1992). Because of the stylized nature of the model, the
predicted share of agriculture is significantly higher than the actual
share before the industrialization date. This happens because the model
economy is primarily an agrarian economy during the preindustrial phase:
GDP mainly consists of food production. The model predicts the
agriculture share much better during the post-1880 phase after the
economy catches up with the modern technology. The sharp drop in the
share of agriculture right after 1880 basically mirrors the upward drift
in GDP in 1880 reported in Figure 4.
The model also predicts a secular rise in the share of expenditure
on education in GDP from 1% in the preindustrial steady state to 3.41%
in the industrial state. (23) This compares reasonably with the actual
share of expenditure on education in GDP, which, according to Carpentier
(2003), rose from 0.01% in 1833 to 4.31% in 1999.
It should be noted that, because of its stylized nature, the model
does not always succeed in quantitatively reproducing some of the
stylized facts observed in the economy. However, it qualitatively
predicts the secular movement in those key variables reflecting the
structural transformation of the economy.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
5. Taking the Baseline Model to Cross-Country Data
How does the baseline model accord with the cross-country data? We
approach this issue in two steps. First, we investigate whether the
model has any useful insights about the cross-country correlations
between agricultural productivity, education, and the degree of
industrialization documented in section 2. Second, we examine how the
baseline model performs in predicting past and recent cross-country
income differences.
Agricultural Productivity, Education, and Time to Industrialize
The model can rationalize the cross-country correlations between
agricultural productivity, initial human capital, and the extent of
industrialization documented in Table 2. To see this, note from
Equations 3 and 20 that the steady state level of human capital in
Equation 20 is nothing but the agricultural labor productivity
([c.sub.a]/[N.sub.a]), which, in the preindustrial economy, crucially
depends on the IST parameter z. Given their dependence on the IST
variable z, both the agricultural labor productivity,
[c.sub.a]/[N.sub.a], and the initial human capital stock
[h.sup.(1).sub.0] (which is assumed to be equal to [h.sup.*(1)]) are
endogenous. A lower agricultural IST parameter lowers labor
productivity. This results in a lower initial human capital and delayed
industrialization, which is reflected by a higher share of agriculture
in GDP, as shown in Footnote 19.
Table 4 summarizes how a change in z impacts the time to
industrialize via its effects on agricultural productivity. The time to
industrialize is sensitive to the IST parameter: A 10% increase in z
starting from the baseline level raises the agricultural productivity by
about 22% and speeds up the time to industrialize by 20 years. This
broadly accords with the stylized facts presented in Table 2, according
to which countries with lower agricultural productivity and low initial
human capital are less industrialized.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
The model has some indirect implications for fertility and time to
industrialize. Although fertility is not explicitly modeled, nations
with a lower fertility can be envisaged as those with higher returns to
child quality (following the quality-quantity tradeoff discussed in
Becker, Murphy, and Tamura 1990), that is, a higher z. The model
predicts that nations with higher returns to child quality industrialize
faster.
Predictions about Past and Recent Cross-Country Income Differences
We now analyze the extent to which our baseline model calibrated to
the U.K. economy helps predict past and recent cross-country income
differences. A key implication of the baseline model is that the U.K.
economy industrialized early because it started belt-tightening early.
If all countries shared the same preferences and technology, the model
would imply that the reason why some countries are laggards in terms of
growth and per capita income is that they did not begin belt-tightening
early enough. In this section we use cross-country schooling years data
to predict the cross-country difference in the initial belt-tightening
years and the resulting effects on past and recent cross-country income
differences.
Sample Selection Issues
Cross-country data for schooling years are limited and do not date
back too far: The Barro and Lee (2000) data set contains schooling years
that go back only to 1960. In this section we focus on those countries
whose schooling years in 1960 are less than the critical threshold necessary to attain the U.K. [h.sub.min] (5 years). According to our
baseline model, these countries were not fully industrialized at that
time.
We then omit a number of outliers from our sample. For 1960 these
include Greece, Italy, Spain, Trinidad and Tobago, and Venezuela (for
which the average actual scaled per capita real income is equal to 3.44,
compared to 0.64 for the other countries). For 2005 the outliers that we
omit include Greece, Italy, Spain, Portugal, Trinidad and Tobago,
Singapore, Korea, and Mexico (for which the average actual scaled per
capita real income is equal to 6.75, compared to 0.77 for the other
countries); and Mali, Nepal, Niger, and Togo (for which the average
scaled GDP predicted by the model is equal to 0.11, compared to 1.19 for
the other countries). This leaves us with a sample made up of 43
countries in 1960 and 47 countries in 2005. (24)
Inferring the Date at which Countries Started Belt-Tightening
For each of the countries, we plug the respective average schooling
years in 1960 into Equation 27 and obtain an estimate of the
corresponding human capital in 1960. Given such human capital in 1960
and assuming that all countries start from the same preindustrial U.K.
baseline steady state [h.sup.*(1)], we then infer when each of these
countries started belt-tightening by simulating the belt-tightening path
given in Equation 21. These initial years of belt-tightening for our
countries are summarized in Table 5. Not surprisingly countries whose
schooling years in 1960 are closer to the minimum level of five years
necessary to attain [h.sub.min] started the belt-tightening early. For
example, a country like Panama that has the highest average schooling
years of 4.64 in the sample started its belt-tightening in 1872, as
opposed to Togo, which has average schooling years of 0.22 and started
its belt-tightening only in 1914. (25)
Comparing the Model Predictions with the Actual Data for Real GDP
per Capita in 1960 and 2005
In a similar spirit as in Gollin, Parente, and Rogerson (2007b), we
let the model predict the level of per capita income of our countries,
which are assumed to differ only in terms of the initial belt-tightening
year. (26) The countries' per capita income predicted by the model
for 1960 and 2005 is then compared with the actual per capita income of
these countries in the same years. Figure 6 presents the scatter plot of
the model predictions against the actual scaled per capita real GDP in
1960, and Figure 7 presents the corresponding scatter plot for 2005. The
correlation coefficient between the model and the actual data is 0.47
for 1960 and 0.42 for 2005. Given that the cross-country income
variation still perplexes growth economists, this correlation between
the model and actual per capita income is reasonable.
This exercise of cross-country income predictions using a stylized
model of U.K. industrialization has to be interpreted with caution
because of inherent country heterogeneity. In addition to human capital
and agricultural productivity, there are numerous other economic and
institutional factors at work in determining cross-country income
differences. (27) Because the central focus of this paper is on
education as an important determinant of the pace of industrialization,
we abstract from these factors.
6. Conclusion
In this paper we have analyzed whether, in addition to differences
in agricultural productivity, differences in initial years of schooling
can explain why some countries industrialize later than others. We have
constructed a neoclassical growth model, which predicts that countries
with a greater initial knowledge gap industrialize later. We have used
this model as a baseline and calibrated it to U.K. historical data. We
found that our baseline model performs well in replicating actual
historical U.K. real GDP per capita series during the era following the
Second Industrial Revolution. Moreover, we found that the model has
useful insights about the cross-country correlations between
agricultural productivity, education, and the degree of
industrialization observed in the data. Finally, assuming that the
countries in the sample start belt-tightening at different dates, we
have shown that our model performs reasonably well in predicting
cross-country income variations.
Better predictions of recent cross-country income differences could
be obtained by including in our model other economic and institutional
factors. Furthermore, our model could be extended by making population
size endogenous. This would allow a comprehensive understanding of the
complex interactions between fertility, human capital, agricultural
productivity, and the pace of industrialization. These extensions to our
model are on the agenda for future research.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
Appendix 1: List of Countries Used in Section 2 (All Countries) and
Section 5 (Countries in Bold; Outliers Are in Italics; Countries for
which Observations Were not Available in 1960 Are Underlined)
1. Algeria# *
2. Argentina#
3. Australia#
4. Austria#
5. Bahrain#
6. Bangladesh# *
7. Barbados#
8. Bolivia#
9. Botswana# *
10. Brazil# *
11. Cameroon# *
12. Canada#
13. Central African Republic# *
14. Chile#
15. Colombia# *
16. Costa Rica# *
17. Cyprus#
18. Denmark#
19. Dominican Republic# *
20. Ecuador# *
21. El Salvador# *
22. Fiji#
23. Finland#
24. France#
25. Germany#
26. Ghana# *
27. Greece# * @
28. Guatemala# *
29. Guyana# *
30. Haiti# *
31. Honduras# *
32. Hong Kong, China#
33. Hungary#
34. Iceland#
35. India# *
36. Indonesia# *
37. Iran# * **
38. Ireland#
39. Israel#
40. Italy# * @
41. Jamaica# * **
42. Japan#
43. Jordan# * **
44. Kenya# *
45. Korea, Republic of# * @
46. Kuwait#
47. Lesotho# *
48. Malawi# *
49. Malaysia# *
50. Mali# * @ **
51. Mauritius# * **
52. Mexico# * @
53. Mozambique# * **
54. Nepal# * @
55. The Netherlands#
56. New Zealand#
57. Nicaragua# *
58. Niger# * @
59. Norway#
60. Pakistan# *
61. Panama# *
62. Papua New Guinea# *
63. Paraguay# *
64. Peru# *
65. Philippines# *
66. Poland#
67. Portugal# * @
68. Senegal# *
69. Sierra Leone# *
70. Singapore# * @
71. South Africa# *
72. Spain# * @
73. Sri Lanka# *
74. Swaziland# * **
75. Sweden#
76. Switzerland#
77. Syria# *
78. Tanzania# * **
79. Thailand# *
80. Togo# * @
81. Trinidad and Tobago# * @
82. Tunisia# * **
83. Turkey# * **
84. Uganda# * **
85. United Kingdom#
86. United States#
87. Uruguay#
88. Venezuela# * @
89. Zambia# *
90. Zimbabwe#
Note:
List of Countries Used in Section 2 (All Countries) is indicated
with #.
List of Countries Used in Section 5 (Countries in Bold) is
indicated with *.
List of Countries Outliers in italics is indicated with @.
Underlined countries for which Observations were not available in
1960 is indicated with **.
Appendix 2: Derivation of Equation 12
The solution of Equation 11 consists of two parts: the solution for
the nonhomogenous part (particular integral) and the solution for the
homogenous part (complementary solution).
We initially conjecture a solution:
[h.sup.(2).sub.t] = Q for all t. (A1)
We then plug Equation A1 into Equation 11 and solve for Q to obtain
Q = A[bar.a] / A - [delta]' (A2)
which solves the particular integral part. The homogenous part of
Equation 12 is given by
[h.sup.(2).sub.t+2] - (A + 1 - [delta] + G)[h.sup.(2).sub.t+1] + (A
+ 1 - [delta])G[h.sup.(2).sub.t] = 0. (A3)
The two characteristic roots of Equation A3 are given by
[[lambda].sub.1], [[lambda].sub.2] = (A + 1 - [lambda]), G. (A4)
The general solution, which is the sum of the solutions for the
nonhomogenous and homogenous parts, is thus given by Equation 12. QED.
We wish to thank two anonymous referees, Roy Bailey, Debajyoti
Chakraborty, Douglas Gollin, Kent Kimbrough, Les Reinhorn, Udayan Roy,
Kunal Sen, Gary Shea, and the participants in the 2004 Midwest
Macroeconomics Conference, the 2004 Centre for Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis Conference, and the 2005 Royal Economic Society Conference for
useful feedback. We also thank Giovanni Baiocchi for providing some key
technical assistance. We alone are responsible for errors.
Received March 2006; accepted September 2007.
References
Atkeson, A., and P. Kehoe. 2007. Modeling the transition to a new
economy: Lessons from two technological revolutions. American Economic
Review 97:64-88.
Bandyopadhyay, D., and P. Basu. 2005. What drives the cross-country
growth-inequality correlation? Canadian Journal of Economics 38:1272-97.
Barro, R. J., and J. W. Lee. 2000. International data on
educational attainment updates and implications. National Bureau of
Economic Research Working Paper No. 7911.
Basu, P., and A. Guariglia. 2007. Foreign direct investment,
inequality, and growth. Journal of Macroeconomics 29:824-839.
Becker, G. S., K. Murphy, and R. M. Tamura. 1990. Human capital,
fertility and economic growth. Journal of Political Economy 98:S12-S37.
Benabou, R. 2000. Unequal societies: Income distribution and the
social contract. American Economic Review 90:96-129.
Bils, M., and P. Klenow. 2000. Does schooling cause growth?
American Economic Review 90:1160-83.
Birke, S., and A. Browne. 2007. Children belong at school. The
Times, of London, 12 January, p. 14.
Carpentier, V. 2003. Public expenditure on education and economic
growth in the UK, 1833-2000. History of Education 32:1-15.
Cummins, J., and G. Violante. 2002. Investment-specific technical
change in the U.S. (1947-2000): Measurement and macroeconomic
consequences. Review of Economic Dynamics 5:243-84.
Devine, W. D., Jr. 1983. From shafts to wires: Historical
perspective on electrification. Journal of Economic History 43:347-72.
Doepke, M. 2004. Accounting for fertility decline during the
transition to growth. Journal of Economic Growth 9:347-83.
Fisher, J. D. M. 2006. The dynamic effects of neutral and
investment specific technology shocks. Journal of Political Economy
114:413-50.
Galor, O. 2005. From stagnation to growth: Unified growth theory.
In Handbook of economic growth, edited by P. Aghion and S. Durlauf.
Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, North-Holland, pp. 171-293.
Galor, O., and O. Moav. 2004. From physical to human capital:
Inequality in the process of development. Review of Economic Studies
71:1001-26.
Galor, O., and D. Weil. 2000. Population, technology and growth:
From the Malthusian regime to the demographic transition and beyond.
American Economic Review 90:806-28.
Gollin, D., S. Parente, and R. Rogerson. 2002. The role of
agriculture in development. American Economic Review 92:160-4.
Gollin, D., S. Parente, and R. Rogerson. 2007a. The food problem
and the evolution of international income levels. Journal of Monetary
Economics 54:1230-55.
Gollin, D., S. Parente, and R. Rogerson. 2007b. Miracle economies
and miracle seeds: Quantifying agricultural sources of economic growth.
Williams College, Williamstown, MA, mimeo.
Gollin, D., S. Parente, and R. Rogerson. 2004. Farm work, home work
and international productivity differences. Review of Economic Dynamics
7:827-850.
Green, A. 1990. Education and state formation. New York: St.
Martin's Press.
Hansen, G. D., and E. C. Prescott. 2002. Malthus to Solow. American
Economic Review 92:1205-17.
Lucas, R. 1988. On the mechanics of economic development. Journal
of Monetary Economics 22:3-42.
Lucas, R. 2003. The industrial revolution: Past and future.
Minneapolis, MN: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Annual Report, pp.
1-14.
Maddison, A. 2003. The world economy: Historical statistics. Paris:
OECD.
Mankiw, G. N., D. Romer, and D. Weil. 1992. A contribution to the
empirics of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107:407-37.
Mitchell, B. R. 1992. International historical statistics: Europe
1750-1988. New York: Stockton Press.
Sanderson, M. 1995. Education, economic change and society in
England 1780-1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Somer, E. 2004. Ten things you must know about calories. Shape.
Available at http://findarticles.com/p/articles/
mi_m0846/is_11_23/ai_n6143167.
World Bank Development Indicators. Various issues. Washington, DC:
World Bank.
(1) According to our model, countries with higher initial human
capital industrialize earlier. Thus, initial between- country
educational inequality matters, but eventually, in the long-run, all
countries attain a balanced growth rate and inequality disappears. A
similar outcome is obtained by Galor and Moav (2004), who construct a
model in which inequality permits the advancement of the process of
industrialization in early stages of development, and only in later
stages of development does equality dominate.
(2) Going one step further, Doepke (2004) assesses whether
education subsidies and child labor restrictions impact the fertility
decline that accompanies the transition to growth. See Galor (2005) for
a full account of the literature analyzing the factors that trigger the
transition from an agricultural to an industrial economy.
(3) Our model differs fundamentally from Hansen and Prescott's
(2002). In Hansen and Prescott, total factor productivity in the Solow
sector (industry) is the prime mover; whereas, in our model, the
investment-specific technology in the preindustrial sector is the
kingpin of transformation, as it impacts both the initial human capital
and agricultural productivity.
(4) In section 4, we posit a human capital-schooling years
technology, which establishes a connection between schooling years and
human capital.
(5) The latter fact is reflected by the decline in the world
average share of agriculture.
(6) While Basu and Guariglia (2007) examine the effect of foreign
direct investment on inequality, the scope of the present paper is to
understand different stages of industrialization in terms of human
capital endowments.
(7) Sanderson (1995) and Carpentier (2003) describe the inadequacy
of public schooling in the United Kingdom during the mid-nineteenth
century. Carpentier documents that only 0.01% of GDP was spent on
education in 1833.
(8) We borrow the term IST from Cummins and Violante (2002) and
Fisher (2006), who use parameters similar to our z and A in the context
of physical capital accumulation. Gollin, Parente, and Rogerson (2004)
also use a similar parameter in the context of physical capital
formation. In our model the only reproducible capital is human capital.
(9) The parameter z basically determines the cost of human capital
formation relative to food production, and, through this channel, it
impacts the pace of investment-specific technological change. A variety
of factors, such as returns to child quality and fiscal policies (tax
policies and educational subsidies), could influence z.
(10) See Appendix 2 for a derivation of Equation 12.
(11) The algebraic derivation of Equation 26 is available from the
authors on request. The expression for [c.sup.(2).sub.mT] is obtained by
plugging Equation 15 into Equation 9 and noting that as soon as the
country transforms itself, [h.sup.(2).sub.0] = [h.sub.min]. We also
assume that the convergence condition ([beta][G.sup.1 - [gamma]] < 1)
holds.
(12) To see this, note that for [gamma] close to unity, the
expression in the last square bracket in Equation 26 approaches [ln
[c.sub.mT] + ([beta]/(1 - [beta]))ln G], which is positive for plausible
parameter values.
(13) [??] can be seen as the smallest possible time period
necessary to attain [h.sub.min].
(14) Alternatively, we could have chosen 1870 as a measure for
[??]. The year 1870 was when the government assumed responsibility for
ensuring universal elementary education (Green 1990). Another
alternative could have been to choose 1890, the year in which education
was made free for children under the age of 10. Finally, we could have
chosen 1893 as a measure for [??], which corresponds to the year in
which the compulsory years of education rose from five to six (Birke and
Browne 2007). Our predictions about the relevant macroeconomic
aggregates are robust to using these alternative dates.
(15) This functional form is borrowed from Basu and Guariglia
(2007). Bils and Klenow (2000) posit a more general human capital
production function, which includes cohort and experience effects. Ours
is a simplified version of their technology, which shows a direct
relationship between schooling years and human capital, excluding cohort
and experience effects. Note that our schooling technology does not
alter the internal working of the model. Once the time path of human
capital is determined, using technology (Eqn. 27) allows us to trace out
the time path of schooling years. This schooling technology is needed
only for the purpose of obtaining our cross-country income differences
predictions reported in section 5.
(16) Changing the value of [gamma] in the vicinity of 1 does not
significantly alter the main baseline calibration results.
(17) Changing the value of [omega] in the vicinity of 0.5 does not
significantly alter the main baseline calibration results.
(18) Specifically, given the values of [beta], [delta], and
[gamma], we fix A such that the long-run growth rate of [[[beta](A + 1 -
[delta])].sup.1/[gamma]] equals 1.4% (see Proposition 2). This implies a
value for A of 0.0775.
(19) GDP is defined as consumption plus investment. In the context
of our model, it is given by [bar.a] + [c.sub.mt] + [h.sup.(2).sub.t +
1] - (1 - [delta])[h.sup.(2).sub.t], i.e., consumption of agricultural
and manufacturing goods plus investment in schooling. Using the resource
constraint (Eqn. 9), the share of agriculture in GDP is equal to
[bar.a]/[h.sup.(2).sub.t]. After equating this expression to its 2001
value (1%), we obtain a terminal capital stock equal to 100 in 2001.
(20) Information on the minimum schooling years in the United
Kingdom was taken from Birke and Browne (2007).
(21) The GDP index in year x is defined as the ratio between real
per capita GDP in year x and real per capita GDP in 1900. We chose the
period 1830-2001, as this is the period for which the Maddison (2003)
series for U.K. real per capita GDP are available.
(22) The discrete jump in output is due to the absence of
adjustment cost of capital in our model.
(23) According to the model in the preindustrial steady state, the
share of expenditure on education in GDP is given by [delta][h.sup.*(1)]
/ ([c.sup.*.sub.a] + [delta][h.sup.*(1)]), which is the replacement
human capital investment divided by the steady state GDP. Using Equation
3, this reduces to [delta]/([N.sub.a] + [delta]).
(24) For each country, both the actual and the predicted real per
capita GDP figures are scaled by the corresponding figures for Algeria.
Actual real per capita GDP figures are taken from the World Bank
Development Indicators (2005). Note that the sample used in this section
contains fewer countries than the sample used in section 2, as out of
the initial 90 countries, only 59 had information for years of schooling
in 1960 (i.e., for the initial years of schooling) and had less than
five initial years of schooling. These 59 countries are highlighted in
bold in Appendix 1 (the 13 outliers mentioned above are in bold and
italics). Data for cross-country per capita GDP in 1960 were not
available for the underlined countries in Appendix 1. All stylized facts
illustrated in section 2 also hold for the restricted samples of 59 or
43/47 (excluding the outliers) countries used in this section.
(25) Since we use the same baseline parameters for all the
countries in the sample, by default, the belt-tightening strategy is
optimal for these countries. The countries in our sample are
characterized by schooling years in 1960. which are less than the
critical threshold necessary to attain the U.K. [h.sub.min] (five
years): their belt-tightening years are therefore less than the U.K.
belt-tightening period of 92 years.
(26) An alternative hypothesis could be that the countries'
initial belt-tightening years are the same, but each country started off
from a different steady state [h.sup.*(1)]. This could be attributed to
different values of the preindustrial IST parameter z in different
countries. Our cross-country predictions do not change much if we allow
z to change across countries.
(27) Bandyopadhyay and Basu (2005) explore other determinants of
cross-country differences in growth and inequality.
Parantap Basu * and Alessandra Guariglia ([dagger])
* Department of Economics and Finance, Durham University, 23-26 Old
Elvet, Durham DH1 3HY, United Kingdom; E-mail
parantap.basu@durham.ac.uk.
([dagger]) School of Economics, University of Nottingham,
University Park, Nottingham, NG7 2RD, United Kingdom; E-mail
alessandra.guariglia@nottingham.ac.uk; corresponding author.
Table 1. Time Paths of Human Capital and the Share of Agriculture in
GDP
Year 1960-1964 1965-1969 1970-1974 1975-1979
Average human 3.70 3.81 4.17 4.40
capital
Average share 0.32 0.27 0.25 0.23
of agriculture
Year 1980-1984 1985-1989 1990-1994 1995-1999
Average human 4.88 5.21 5.64 6.05
capital
Average share 0.20 0.19 0.18 0.17
of agriculture
Average human capital is measured in terms of average total years of
schooling (including primary, secondary, and higher education) and is
taken from the Barro and Lee (2000) data set. The average share of
agriculture represents the share of the value added coming from
agriculture and is taken from the World Bank Development
Indicators (2002).
Table 2. Cross-Country Correlations between Initial Human Capital,
Agricultural Produc-tivity, and the Share of Agriculture in GDP
Average Share of Average Initial
Agriculture Agricultural Human
in GDP Productivity Capital
Average share of 1.00
agriculture in GDP
Average agricultural -0.583 1.00
productivity
Initial human capital -0.661 0.699 1.00
Human capital is measured in terms of average total years of schooling
(including primary, secondary, and higher education) and is taken from
the Barro and Lee (2000) data set. The share of agriculture in GDP
represents the share of the value added coming from agriculture to GDP
and is taken from the World Bank Development Indicators (2002).
Agricultural productivity is given by the agriculture value added per
worker and is also taken from the World Bank Development
Indicators (2002).
Table 3. Baseline Parameters
Parameters Value Comments
Preference parameters:
[beta]: discount factor 0.95 Consistent with a 5% real
interest rate
[gamma]: utility function 1.01 Conventional level,
curvature parameter approximating logarithmic
preferences
[bar.a]: saturation level 1 Normalization
of food
[omega]: subsistence 0.50 Based on nutritional studies
such as Somer (2004)
Technology parameters:
[alpha]: labor share in 0.69 Chosen to ensure the
agriculture feasibility of the
belt-tightening strategy.
Close to the estimate in
Bandyopadhyay and
Basu (2005).
[delta]: depreciation rate 0.01 Chosen to ensure the
feasibility of the
belt-tightening strategy.
Close to the estimate in
Bandyopadhyay and Basu
(2005).
A: IST parameter in 0.0775 Chosen to reproduce the 1.4%
manufacturing annual average growth
rate of U.K. GDP during
the post-1880 period.
z: IST parameter in 0.063 Chosen to replicate the
agriculture relative productivity of
manufacturing with
respect to agriculture,
equal to 1.229 in 1880
(Mitchell 1992).
Human capital parameters:
[h.sup.(1).sub.0]: initial 2.87 Fixed at the preindustrial
human capital steady state [h.sup.*(1)]
(see Eqn. 20)
[h.sub.min]: minimum level 19.78 Consistent with a 1% share
of human capital of agriculture in GDP
necessary to enter the in 2000
industrial stage
Schooling-human capital Q Q = 8.44; Consistent with the observed
technology [theta] = minimum schooling years
parameters 2.62 in 1880 and 2001
Table 4. Agricultural IST Parameter (z), Agricultural Productivity,
and Time to Industrialize (T)
z 0.063 0.069 0.077 0.081
Agricultural productivity 2.79 3.74 5.34 6.28
T 92 72 51 49
Other parameters are fixed at the same level as in Table 3. For all
these z values, the belt-tightening strategy was found to be optimal.
Table 5. Initial Year of Belt-Tightening Inferred from Schooling Years
in 1960
Initial Year of
Country s Belt-Tightening
Algeria 0.982 1909
Bangladesh 0.612 1911
Botswana 1.719 1903
Brazil 2.852 1892
Cameroon 1.739 1902
Central African Republic 0.565 1912
Colombia 3.197 1889
Costa Rica 4.035 1879
Dominican Republic 2.696 1894
Ecuador 3.225 1888
El Salvador 1.995 1900
Ghana 0.966 1909
Guatemala 1.498 1904
Guyana 4.484 1874
Haiti 0.780 1910
Honduras 1.872 1901
India 1.684 1903
Indonesia 1.553 1904
Iran 0.796 1910
Jamaica 2.540 1895
Jordan 2.333 1897
Kenya 1.531 1904
Korea, Republic of 4.246 1877
Lesotho 3.483 1886
Malawi 1.910 1901
Malaysia 2.879 1892
Mauritius 3.128 1889
Mexico 2.756 1893
Mozambique 0.478 1912
Nepal 0.116 1915
Nicaragua 2.257 1898
Niger 0.278 1914
Pakistan 0.740 1910
Panama 4.643 1872
Papua New Guinea 1.146 1907
Paraguay 3.640 1884
Peru 3.302 1888
Philippines 4.237 1877
Portugal 1.859 1901
Senegal 1.742 1902
Sierra Leone 0.656 1911
Singapore 4.298 1876
South Africa 4.286 1876
Sri Lanka 3.938 1880
Swaziland 2.132 1899
Syria 1.351 1906
Tanzania 3.510 1885
Thailand 4.297 1876
Togo 0.225 1914
Tunisia 0.605 1911
Turkey 1.915 1901
Uganda 1.149 1907
Venezuela 2.905 1892
Zambia 2.520 1895
s denotes total schooling years (including primary, secondary, and
higher education) in 1960 and is taken from the Barro and Lee (2000)
data set.