Gambling in America.
Walker, Douglas M.
Gambling in America By Earl Grinols. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press, 2004. Pp. 232. $45.00. ISBN 0521830133.
Professor Grinols has been involved in the casino gambling debate
in the United States since the early 1990s. Even before much empirical
data were available, Grinols was a staunch opponent of legalized
casinos. His recent book, which discusses casino gambling only, builds
on his previous publications and continues his antigambling tradition.
In the introductory chapters, Grinols provides a history of
gambling in the United States, noting that most states had
constitutional bans on gambling in 1900. Only 100 years later, the ban
on gambling has been reversed in most states. Grinols discusses the
development of the casino industry, the politics behind it (chapter 3),
and notes that the industry would be ordinary were it not for the fact
that casino gambling, particularly by problem or pathological gamblers,
may cause externalities.
Beginning in chapter 4, Grinols discusses various economic aspects
of the casino industry. Since gambling began spreading in the United
States outside of Nevada and New Jersey (1991-present), there have been
a variety of "economic impact studies." Grinols correctly
notes that many of these have been seriously flawed. The studies, which
are frequently funded by the casino industry, often argue that the
number of jobs provided by the casino industry is a proxy for the
economic benefits of casinos. (Tax revenue is the other major selling
point for politicians considering legalizing casinos.) Grinols correctly
points out that more jobs do not necessarily imply that economic
development follows. In many cases, the new casino jobs may just
"cannibalize" other jobs in the community. The effect of new
casinos on labor markets is an issue that has not received adequate
attention in the literature.
Grinols makes the argument that casinos act like
"restaurants" and do not attract outside dollars to the
community. As a result, casinos cannibalize other industries.
Furthermore, if the casino's corporate headquarters is outside the
community, this money leaves the local economy, thus providing no
economic benefit to the community. If instead, casinos acted like
"factories," where outsiders came and spent their money, and
the money remained in the local economy, there could be an economic
growth effect from casinos, like in Las Vegas. This argument is
reminiscent of mercantilism, which focuses on the inflow of money.
Obviously, tourism can play an important part of an economy, but exports
are not necessary for economic development to occur.
In chapter 5, Grinols develops a formal cost-benefit model of
gambling. Items included on the benefits side of the ledger include net
increase in profits measured across all businesses, net increase in
taxes measured across all taxpayers, consumer surplus, distance consumer
surplus, capital gains to consumers induced by the activity, and gains
from relaxation or elimination of nonprice constraints on consumer
choices (p. 97). Only the item "real resources consumed to deal
with harmful externalities" appears on the cost side.
Grinols simply drops consumer surplus from the analysis, and
explains "a reasonable first approximation is that the net effect
of a casino on capital gains and consumer surplus considerations is
small. If firm and household prices are invariant to the amount of
gambling ..., capital gains on endowments and consumer surplus drop
out" (p. 107). This treatment of consumer surplus seems odd.
Grinols argues that the only benefit from having new casinos in a state
is a "distance consumer surplus;" because the gambler does not
have to travel as far to a casino, their costs of consumption are lower.
Should not the first casino in Mississippi, for example, be treated as a
new product or "brand" of entertainment in that market? There
is an entire literature (e.g., Lancaster, Hausman, Scherer) on the
effects of increased variety for consumers. Certainly there are benefits
to having Amazon.com, other than the fact that consumers do not have to
drive as far to buy things. Increased product variety is beneficial, but
Grinols completely ignores this.
It is also unclear why Grinols thinks casinos do not create any
significant traditional consumer surplus. Casinos are often coupled with
other products, usually restaurants and hotels. To the extent these put
downward pressure on prices in the restaurant and hotel markets,
consumer surplus would be created by a new casino. Even on the casino
games themselves, there is price competition. For example, casinos will
advertise that their slots payout a greater percentage, or that craps players can bet 10x odds rather than the standard 2x odds. Such
competition could result in potentially significant consumer surplus.
The chapter on social costs has very serious problems. Although
Grinols addresses most of the standard social cost issues that have been
examined in the literature (e.g., crime, employment and productivity
losses, bankruptcy, suicide, social services costs, and regulatory
costs), he completely ignores the tremendous level of controversy
surrounding the handling of these issues. He goes on to summarize the
findings of several cost-benefit studies that were performed during the
1990s, and estimates the annual cost to society per pathological gambler
to be $10,330 (p. 171). This estimate is seriously flawed because it is
composed mostly of wealth transfers or costs to the individual gamblers.
Indeed, the studies relied on by Grinols have been criticized in the
literature, and their credibility has been questioned (Walker 2003). (1)
The National Research Council (1999, p. 185) explains:
In most of the impact analyses of gambling and pathological and
problem gambling, the methods used are so inadequate as to
invalidate the conclusions. Researchers in this area have struggled
with the absence of systematic data that could inform their analysis
and consequently have substituted assumptions for the missing data.
The assumptions adopted for specific studies were rarely examined or
tested to ensure they were appropriate for the specific research
being conducted. There is always the risk that such assumptions and
resulting estimates may reflect the bias of the analyst rather than
the best-informed judgment. Critical estimates have been frequently
taken from one study and haphazardly applied in different
circumstances.
Grinols simply ignores the controversy over social cost studies in
the literature.
Finally, the social cost chapter includes a full twenty pages of
examples of newspaper clips of the personal and economic damage caused
by casino gambling. Similar antigambling stories and statements are
peppered throughout the book. Rarely does Grinols hint that there is a
legitimate argument that casinos may create a net benefit, for example,
by providing jobs, price competition, "variety benefits" to
consumers, or economic development. Indeed, Grinols ignores any
literature that might suggest such benefits. Even though Grinols
indicates that he has no moral objection to gambling (p. 11), the reader
may suspect that he sees casino gambling as a "merit bad."
Overall, Grinols underestimates the potential consumer benefits
from casinos. His reliance on flawed studies to estimate social costs
results in an overestimation of the social costs of gambling.
Unfortunately, the reader who is not already familiar with the
"economics of gambling" literature will be left with an
incomplete picture of the debate. Grinols generally does not cite the
relevant economics literature in justifying his methodology, nor does he
make any reference to gambling research that does not agree with his
conclusions. As a result, it is important for the reader interested in
alternative perspectives on the economics of gambling to seek resources
not cited by Grinols. All things considered, Gambling in America is
probably a book worth reading--if you are interested in an antigambling
perspective on casinos in the United States.
Douglas M. Walker
Georgia College
References
National Research Council. 1999. Pathological gambling: A critical
review Washington, DC: National Academy Press. Accessed 26 July 2006.
Available at http://www.nap.edu/books/03090657121html/index.html.
Thompson, W., and F. Quinn. 2000. The video gaming machines of
South Carolina: Disappearing soon? Good riddance or bad news? A
socio-economic analysis. Paper presented at the 11th International
Conference on Gambling and Risk-Taking. Las Vegas, NV (14 June 2000).
Walker, Douglas M. 2003. Methodological issues in the social cost
of gambling studies. Journal of Gambling Studies 19(2): 149-84.
(1) For example, in an updated version of one of the studies cited
by Grinols, the authors write, "Gaming establishments need many
supplies. Many of these are purchased from sources outside of the area.
This is money lost. So, too, are profits that go to outside owners"
(Thompson and Quinn 2000, p. 4). They go on to estimate a social cost to
South Carolina in the amount of $46 million because of the purchase of
video gaming machines from out-of-state manufacturers (pp. 10-11). This
clearly illustrates confusion about the win-win nature of market
transactions (even transactions with casinos). If Grinols' cost
estimate is based on studies such as this one, clearly it should be
taken with a healthy skepticism.