Trade, social values, and the generalized trust.
Chan, Kenneth S.
The present paper investigates, empirically, whether global
economic integration can lead to national social disintegration, as
proclaimed by Rodrik. One can perhaps conjecture that a drop in the
generalized trust in a country may signal a rise in social
disintegration. Using the survey data on the generalized trust provided
by the World Values Surveys, the present paper finds that, in general,
there is a positive openness-trust relationship. However, when
globalization undermines domestic income distribution, it will weaken
this openness-trust relationship. There is also evidence of a threshold
inequality above which the openness-trust relationship turns negative.
JEL Classification: F02, F10, F13, Z10
1. Introduction
The present paper investigates, empirically, whether global
economic integration can lead to national social disintegration, as
proclaimed by Rodrik (1997). By social disintegration, Rodrik refers to
the uprooting of social values of a nation without a suitable
replacement. "Nations do have legitimate reasons for worrying about
what globalization does to their norms and social arrangement,"
says Rodrik (1997). Rodrik's pronouncement is closely akin to, if
not part of, those contentious trade issues arising from differences in
national labor and environmental standards, cultural practices, and
child labor, for example.
To tackle this problem, the present paper chooses the concept of
social capital (the stock of norms, rules, shared understandings, and
expectations, etc.) in the literature as the basis of evaluation. The
choice of this particular framework is discussed in Section 1. A useful
function of social capital is to foster collective actions of the
community. The latter can be measured by the trust among members of the
community. One can perhaps conjecture that a drop in trust may signal a
rise in social disintegration. Using the survey data on generalized
trust provided by the World Values Surveys, various predictions on trade
and generalized trust, reported in Section 2, can be tested. The present
paper finds that the openness of a economy, ceteris paribus, does not
always lead to a decrease in generalized trust. Income distribution is
found to play an important role in this openness-trust relationship.
Maldistribution of income reduces the positive impact of openness on
generalized trust. Hence, when a more open economy raises the income
inequality of a divided nation, the chance of social disintegration may
increase. Section 3 concludes with a discussion of results.
2. Theoretical Analysis and Predictions
Rather than using the conventional utility or social welfare
function to evaluate the aforementioned issues, the present paper uses
output performance as a criterion to evaluate the impacts of different
social values. In other words, social values are considered here as part
of the so-called social capital, discussed further, that aids
production. (1)
Literature Survey
Recently, it is increasingly common for social scientists to use
the term "social capital"-the stock of norms, values, civic
traditions, conventions, etc., that constrain a person's
actions--to explain collective action in a community. Coleman (1988)
defines social capital as "people's capacity to work
voluntarily together." Similar to the concept of capital, the stock
of social capital is productive because it reduces market transactions
cost. (2) Most researchers (e.g., Stiglitz 2000) agree that this kind of
civic cooperation is the foundation of the nation's informal
institution that governs market exchanges and "glues" the
community together. The previous discussion can be summarized by the
following function:
V = [upsilon](K,[alpha]); [[upsilon].sub.1] > 0, (1)
where V is voluntary cooperation, K is social capital, and [alpha]
is a country specific variable.
In the literature, Fukuyama (1995) and Dasgupta (2000) ascribe the
ability to cooperate voluntarily to the trust among the people. Fukuyama
and Dasgupta define trust as the common expectation of individuals that
others' behavior in the community will be cooperative. Indeed, as
argued by Paldam (2000), trust and the ease of voluntary cooperation
should be two highly interlinked, if not almost identical, concepts.
Without trust, cooperation will be limited only to activities that can
be easily monitored or enforced. Paldam (2000) also shows that the two
concepts imply each other. Elsewhere, Putnam (1993, p. 171) makes a
similar argument: "Trust lubricates cooperation. The greater the
level of trust within a community, the greater the likelihood of
cooperation." In the same vein, Zak and Knack (2001) define trust
as, "the resources that agents spend in production rather than in
verifying or monitoring the actions of others, which is identical to the
defined amount of cooperation in the community." The two concepts
are, therefore, equivalent to the definition used by Zak and Knack. The
argument in the literature can be summarized as:
T = T(V) = T([upsilon](K,[alpha])) T' > 0, (2)
where T is the generalized trust and is directly related to, if not
identical to, voluntary cooperation, V. (3)
To support Rodrik's argument emphatically, one has to show
that a drop in the generalized trust in a society leads to social
disintegration. This theoretical link is tenuous at best. Although a low
level of generalized trust can lead to a lack of social cohesion, it
does not automatically imply social disintegration. Moreover, it is
difficult to define the normative concept of social disintegration, let
alone finding data that measures it. Because of this difficulty, this
paper only examines the impact of trade on the generalized trust. This,
by itself, is a positive and interesting research question, somewhat
different from, but close enough to shed light on, the research question
posted by Rodrik. There is no need to enlarge the research focus to
include social disintegration or to generalize to such level of
abstraction. There are two views on the impact of globalization on the
social values of a nation:
The Pessimistic View
According to this view, globalization weakens the social cohesion
within a country, which eventually leads to social disintegration (see
Rodrik 1997). There are two channels through which this can happen:
(i) When conflicted with the social norms and traditional values of
other nations, domestic norms and values (including workplace practices,
rules, social insurance, etc.), which confine how domestic goods are
produced, could be eradicated through the forces of trade. In terms of
Equation 1, if some of the K is destroyed from trade, there will be less
trust and cooperation. This will weaken the social cohesion of a nation.
(ii) Globalization exacerbates tension among groups and pushes the
less fortunate into despair. With increasing resentment and insecurity from those who fall victim to globalization, social order and solidarity
decline (Rodrik 1997). (4) Moreover, the tax base of welfare states is
steadily eroding away as capital and skilled workers become
internationally mobile. Funding for social insurance and redistributive
programs are weakening considerably (see De Grauwe and Polan 2005 for an
update). The retreat of welfare states everywhere aggravates social
divisiveness. Hence, globalization weakens the social cohesion or trust
within a country.
Rodrik's more elegant and updated argument echos Karl
Polanyi's, that integration with the global market economy tended
to destroy domestic social relationships that held human society
together. "To separate labor from other activities of life and to
subject it to the laws of the market was to annihilate all organic forms
of existence and to replace them by a different type of organization, an
atomistic and individualistic one," said Polanyi (1944, chapter 14,
p. 163), and "such a scheme of destruction was best served by the
application of the principle of freedom of contract. In practice this
meant that the noncontractual organizations of kinship, neighborhood,
profession, and creed were to be liquidated, since they claimed the
allegiance of the individual and, thus, restrained his freedom." In
the long run, by freeing social constraints, Polanyi argued, the market
economy undermined social order and threatened to destroy the social
institution upon which the market economy is based.
The Optimistic View
According to this view, globalization integrates national cultures,
resulting in a better mix of pluralistic cultures. Although there is a
clear loss of national cultural autonomy in a more open regime, it does
not mean national cultures and values are dysfunctional. On the
contrary, a better mix of pluralistic culture improves the functioning
of domestic social capital, leading to a gain in social cohesion.
Sen argues (1999, p. 241), "When an economic adjustment takes
place, few tears are shed for the superseded methods of production and
for the overtaken technology. There may be some nostalgia for
specialized and elegant objects (such as an ancient steam engine or an
old-fashioned clock), but, in general, old and discarded machinery is
not particularly wanted. In the case of culture, however, lost
traditions may be greatly missed. The demise of old ways of living can
cause anguish, and a deep sense of loss ... but it is up to the society
to determine what, if anything, it wants to do to preserve old forms of
living, perhaps even at significant economic cost. Ways of life can be
preserved if the society decides to do just that, and it is a question
of balancing the costs of such preservation with the value that the
society attaches to the objects and the lifestyles preserved."
Although there are clear circumstances in which Sen's argument is
incorrect, (5) one can perhaps think of his argument as correct for most
situations, rather than correct unequivocally.
In a similar vein, Bhagwati (2004, chapter 9) argues that trade may
spread useful values that improve domestic social conditions.
"Trade is the friend, not the foe, of social agendas .... " he
says (2001), "Trade means cultural as well as economic interchange
... It is the traditional elites who are most affected by globalization.
And it is they who are most likely to react against social change."
According to the optimistic view, although globalization may
eliminate some form of domestic social capital that is no longer useful,
it may add other forms of foreign social capital that are more
appropriate. There should be more of a choice of global norms and values
in a more open regime than in a less open one.
An Analytical Framework
There is a general concern that the term "social capital"
is just another "buzz word" for something we do not know
rather than a precise and operational concept. In response to this
concern, I adopt in this paper a definition of social capital by Lin
(2001): "Social capital can be defined as the stock of rules,
norms, values, traditions, etc., embedded in a social network, which can
be mobilized by agents in the social network for collective
action." This definition will be useful for the framework described
further on.
A change in domestic prices from liberal trade may provide an
impetus for change in social values. Learning useful foreign values is
similar to acquiring useful foreign technologies. As contracts are
renegotiated, the old norms or informal rules in which contracts are
nested may need improvements in light of the new foreign values.
Restructuring the higher set of dated rules and norms may improve
renegotiations that raise productivity and competitiveness. When the old
values are to be restructured, facilitated through the social network
and the stock of social capital, groups that stand to benefit will
devote resources to restructure the rules and norms at a higher level
and may even compensate the groups that stand to lose from
restructuring. But, similar to the trade in commodities, interest groups
in a fractional society could block trade liberalization and could
distort the domestic economy to the extent that the benefits from trade
could be lowered. In a fragile social network plagued by opportunism,
the exchange of national values could also be blocked by interests who
are threatened by the slow erosion of old social patterns and
traditional ways of life. There may be powerful domestic elites who
depend upon traditional values for their legitimacy. These interest
groups usually wrap themselves in nationalistic cultural identity.
Therefore, in a fractional society, in which the gainers could not
compensate the losers under the improved hybridized values, those who
are threatened by the disappearance of the old and less productive
social values would either block the adoption of the more productive
foreign value or break away from the existing social network. In either
case, the fragile social network would be weakened further, and
subsequently, the generalized trust would be lowered. Therefore, a
fractional society must affect the marginal impact of openness on the
improvement of domestic social capital (i.e., affecting the partial
derivative [partial derivative]K/[partial derivative] O, where O is
openness; see Equation 4 later).
The analytical impact of income inequality on trust is in the
literature. It is much easier for a homogenous group, in which members
have similar interests, to achieve collective actions than a
heterogenous group with diverse interests, argued Olson (1982). For one
thing, it is easier for a homogenous group to achieve consensus. And for
another, it is less costly to develop social incentive mechanisms to
deter opportunism in a homogeneous group that is socially more
interactive. Social capital and social networks are the basis upon which
these informal incentive mechanisms are built. Olson's analytical
framework should be applicable to communities with low income inequality
as well.
Zak and Knack (2001) have also modeled the impact of income
inequality on trust. They argue that production and supervision of
transactions are alternative uses of time. When trust in the society is
low, more time is spent in supervising transactions than in production.
High income individuals, therefore, spend less time supervising in
contrast to the choice of low income individuals who spend more time
supervising. Zak and Knack (2001) assume that adjustments in supervision
for low wage individuals are more sensitive to changes in wage than
those of high wage individuals. Therefore, high wage inequality,
hypothetically generated from a mean preserving spread on a distribution
of wages, reduces trust, where Zak and Knack define trust as the sum of
supervision time of the high and low wage individuals.
Following Zak and Knack's work on a closed economy, one can
further argue that beneficial foreign values improve the technology of
supervision. Hence, less time is spent on supervision and more on
production. This improves the generalized trust. But, if globalization
raises the income inequality of a country, it can lower the generalized
trust and offset some of its initial improvements.
Elsewhere in the literature, Jackson and Wolinsky (1996) examine
network stability. Their framework can be extended to the current
problem. The Jackson and Wolinsky social network model introduces a very
small amount of cooperation among agents into an otherwise
noncooperative environment and finds that small amounts of cooperation
can go a long way because agents are tied together into a social
network. Although agents develop limited cooperative links among
themselves, the transitive nature of links means that weak cooperation
among agents can generate strong cooperation within the network. Jackson
and Wolinsky also introduce the notion of stability of network, in which
agents would neither sever an existing link nor create new links. The
stability of a network, therefore, depends critically on other network
or subnetwork options of the participants. The most efficient social
networks may not be stable. One of their main findings is that an equal
allocation of gains among participants within the network increases
stability. (6) For a homogeneous group, there is no intuitive reason why
an encompassing social network is not beneficial in terms of cost and
benefit of participation [(see Burt (2001) for a similar argument on
"structural holes" of networks]. But for a heterogenous group,
a weak link may exist at which participating in the network no longer
yields benefit to those with a weak link. Forming an encompassing social
network is, therefore, difficult. The society may break into small
subnetworks that can better serve the more homogeneous subgroups. This
multitude of subnetworks and interests can be detrimental to the
society. As cautioned in the literature [see Putnam (1993), among
others], social capital can also facilitate small collusions that are
malicious to the society. Easy examples of this are cults, and criminal
and racist organizations. When each sector in the economy has its own
self-contained social network and social capital, each sector will
exploit its monopoly position. (7) Jackson and Wolinsky's work
clearly concludes that the stability of a social network can weaken with
income inequality. Their work explains the negative impact of inequality
on the generalized trust. If trade liberalization breaks up the domestic
social network into fragmented selfcontained subnetworks, (8) as warned
by Rodrik, these disjointed subnetworks could be harmful. Another
theoretical link between inequality and generalized trust comes from the
experimental literature. Laboratory results in the past have shown that
the behavior of participants in experiments often deviated widely from
the predictions of conventional game theory models. Inspired by these
confounders, experimental researchers have been calibrating theoretical
models that incorporate non-self-interested components, such as
inequality aversion and fairness, into the agent's objective
function. On the whole, this new objective function is successful in
explaining many of the confounders [see Camerer (2003), chapter 2 and
the references cited]. Camerer (2003), in his review of the experimental
literature on trust and dictatorial games, concludes that a
subject's trustworthiness is mainly motivated by fairness
considerations and inequality aversion. In other words, when payoff
inequality in the laboratory environment is viewed as unfair by
subjects, it destroys trust among them. Based on experimental findings,
one can conjecture that in the field when income inequality is viewed as
unjust, it can destroy generalized trust in the community. The previous
discussion can be summarized by the following equations:
T = T([upsilon](K,[alpha])) = t(K; [alpha]) [t.sub.1] = T'
[[upsilon].sub.1] > 0 (3)
K = K(0, I) [K.sub.1] > 0 [K.sub.2] < 0 [K.sub.12] < 0.
(4)
Equation 3 is the same as Equation 2, reproduced here for
convenience. In Equation 4, I is the index of income inequality, a
higher value of I means higher inequality, and O is the degree of
openness. Equation 4 says that domestic social capital K can be improved
by foreign values,9 transmitted from openness, the marginal impact of
which could be blocked by domestic interest groups (approximated by I)
who stand to lose from adopting new foreign values (hence, [K.sub.12]
< 0). Substitute Equation 4 into Equation 3, we have:
T = t(K(O, I); [alpha]) = H(O, I; [alpha]) [H.sub.1] =
[t.sub.1][k.sub.1] > 0 [H.sub.2] = [t.sub.1] [K.sub,2] < 0
[H.sub.12] = [t.sub1] [K.sub.12] < 0. (5)
Equation 5 suggests that if globalization ultimately worsen the
nation's income distribution, it can lower the generalized trust
via the inequality-trust channel.
From mainstream trade theory, the impact of openness on domestic
inequality is generally indeterminate: Although trade redistributes
factor incomes, it can either improve or worsen the income inequality in
a country. Moreover, the ability and the willingness of domestic
institution to redistribute the gains from trade can play a role. One
can therefore specify:
I = i'[O] [i.sup.>.sub.<]' (6)
However, if one accepts the joint null hypotheses that openness
destroys social values and that openness raises income inequality (that
is, I = i(O) and i' > 0), then the total impact of openness on
trust in Equation 5 must be negative (that is, the derivative dT/dO =
[H.sub.1] + [H.sub.2] i' < 0).
The following predictions summarize the aforementioned discussions:
Prediction I: In a fragmentary society, integration with the global
economy can break up social networks and social capital. Consequently,
an open economy lowers the generalized trust of the nation.
Prediction H: In a homogenous society, an open regime allows
societies to integrate and reshape components of global cultures. Some
new, more useful values and practices are adopted and some old less
useful ones are relinquished. In this respect, an open regime fortifies,
instead of diminishes, the ability of social capital to bind its
citizens together for collective actions. Generalized trust in the more
open economies should therefore be higher.
With help from Equation 5, the predictions can be tested in the
following functional form:
Trust = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1] (Openness) + [a.sub.2](Inequality) +
[a.sub.3](Openness) x (Inequality) + [b.sub.4](Country Specific
Variable). (7)
An interactive term is added to Equation 7 to test for the
interactions between openness and income inequality as proposed in (4)
([H.sub.12] = [t.sub.1][K.sub.12] = [a.sub.3]). Prediction I (II)
suggests that the value of [a.sub.1] + [a.sub.3] X (Inequality), which
is the partial derivative of Trust with respect to Openness in Equation
7, is negative (positive). However, on closer examination, the two
predictions need not be mutually exclusive because Prediction I (II)
refers to the situation where income inequality is high (low). The two
aforementioned views, Rodrik and Polanyi on the one side and Bhagwati
and Sen on the other, are perhaps not as mutually exclusive as they
first appear. The country-specific variable in Equation 7 is the [alpha]
term in Equation 5. I choose either a country's income per capita or the GDP-per-capita growth rate for this variable; a detailed
explanation follows.
Multicollinearity in the estimations is a concern here. For one
thing, the variables Openness and Inequality are correlated from
Equation 6. Because the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimations are
unbiased under multicollinearity, as long as the t-statistics of the
estimated term, [a.sub.1] + [a.sub.3] X (Mean Inequality), is
significant, multicollinearity should not pose a problem.
3. Empirical Analysis
As for the Trust variable, I employ the survey data from the World
Values Surveys (WVS) compiled under the direction of Inglehart (1994).
This is the most systematic global values survey currently available. In
the WVS, generalized trust for each country is computed as the
percentage of respondents who agree that "most people can be
trusted" rather than the alternative that "you can't be
too careful in dealing with people." The WVS data has three waves.
The first one is in 1980; the second and the third are in 1990 and 1995,
respectively. I ignore the first wave and average the country data from
the second and the third wave surveys; the second and the third waves
have more countries than the first wave and the two surveys are five
years apart, reasonably close to each other. (10) A total of 39
countries, excluding only the transition and nonmarket economies, are
chosen for the present study. Inglehart (1994) believes that the urban
areas and better-educated people are overrepresented in the sample.
Accordingly, a weight was constructed to reflect this bias. This weight
is used in the present paper to adjust the "raw" trust values.
The data on generalized trust from the WVS have robust predictive power in growth accounting literature (see Knack and Keefer 1997, Zak and
Knack 2001, La Porta et al. 1997). These findings give confidence to the
present choice of data.
As for the openness variable, I employ the openness index
constructed by Sachs and Warner (1995), OpenSW, which measures the past
years of trade policy openness for a large sample of countries. The
OpenSW index describes past trade policy, an exogenous variable that
gives a sense of causation to the empirical analysis. I also employ a
contemporaneous trade shares index (Open), a five-year average of export
and import share of GDP in the same sampling period as the WVS, as an
alternative test. To capture the historical impact of openness, I
construct another index, [Open.sub.-1], using the average historical
export and import share of GDP. I sample from the years 1970 to 1989,
the same sample period as the Sachs-Warner openness index. Pushing the
starting date of the sample back to earlier than 1970 will result in an
incomplete data series for some countries. The end sample date, 1989, is
the starting date of the second wave of the WVS.
The Gini coefficient, taken from World Development Indicators
published by the World Bank, is employed to capture inequality. An
alternative measure of inequality is the ratio of income shares of the
richest 20% of the population divided by the poorest 20% (income-share
ratio). Another measurement of inequality is the ethnic and linguistic
fragmentation profile in a country. The ethnolinguistic
fractionalization index is taken from Alesina et al. (2002). Although
the ethnolinguistic fractionalization index generates only a subset of
inequality, it remains to be an interesting variable to investigate. The
summary statistics of the aforementioned variables are reported in Table
1.
In the field data, generalized trust and GDP per capita are highly
correlated. Many researchers (see Putnam 1993; Knack and Keefer 1997; La
Porta et al. 1997; Zak and Knack 2001; Beugelsdijk, de Groot, and van
Schaik 2004; among others) have argued that the causality goes from
generalized trust to GDP per capita (or GDP-per-capita growth rate),
although the causality can easily be argued to go both ways. The present
paper investigates how much trade can add beyond this observed trust and
GDP-per-capita relationship. For this reason, I add one more regressor,
either the income per capita or the GDP-per-capita growth rate, into the
regressions.
Adding the per-capita income, or per-capita GDP growth in the
regressions can also facilitate the comparison of generalized trust
across countries. Trust saves resources. Since low income economies may
not need to save the same amount of resources as high income economies,
the amount of trust should be adjusted for the size of the economy.
Moreover, at different stages of social and economic development, the
opportunity cost of governance, which is also part of the marginal
benefit of generalized trust, could be different (see Zak and Knack
2001) and should be accounted for in the regressions. The per-capita
income or GDP growth is a well-established control variable for the
stages of social and economic development in a country. (11)
The problem of using the per-capita income or per-capita GDP growth
as a regressor is that they are endogenous and could correlate with
other regressors. For this reason, I replace the income per capita
variable by a rank variable, the Income-per-capita Category, which uses
the classification of countries by the World Bank into four categories,
low, lower middle, higher middle, and high income per capita. I convert
these categories into ranks, from 0 to 3, with 3 as the high income
category. The Income-per-capita Category variable records this rank
value of countries. This variable cuts down the multicollinearity with
other variables in the regressions. As for the GDP-per-capita Growth
variable, I continue to use this variable in the regressions because the
correlation coefficients of this variable with other regressors are low.
(12)
I first explore how much openness can explain generalized trust
after the Income-per-capita Category or the GDP-per-capita Growth has
been accounted for. Table 2 shows exploratory regressions under various
combination of openness, per-capita income, and per-capita GDP growth.
Regressions (1) and (2) in Table 2 focus on the explanatory power of
per-capita income and per-capita GDP growth on generalized trust. The
value and significance of the coefficients of the per-capita income and
per-capita GDP growth drop substantially when the openness variable
OpenSW is added. The value of the coefficients and the level of
significance of the OpenSW variable, on the other hand, has not changed
much with the inclusion of the per-capita income or the per-capita GDP
growth [regressions (3), (4), and (5)]. That means, a lot of generalized
trust, which had hitherto been explained by per-capita income or
per-capita GDP growth, could be explained by OpenSW. This shows the high
explanatory power of the OpenSW variable. A scatter plot of Trust and
OpenSW is provided in Figure 1, after controlling for the influence of
income per capita [regression (4) in Table 2]. From regressions (4) and
(5) in Table 2, because the total impact of openness on trust is
positive, the hypothesis that openness destroys social values and raises
income inequality can be rejected.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The Open variable does not fare as well as OpenSW. Regression (6)
in Table 2 tests the impact of the Open variable on generalized trust,
the R-square of which is low at 0.11. The value of the coefficients of
Open, Income-per-capita Category, and GDP-per-capita Growth are
reasonably consistent with each other in regressions (6), (7), and (8).
The high R-square in regressions (7) and (8) comes from the influence of
the Income-per-capita Category and GDPper-capita Growth. The explanatory
power of the Open variable on Trust is much weaker than the OpenS W
variable. One plausible explanation is that social capital takes time to
accumulate. Its history is, therefore, important. The OpenSW variable
captures past liberal trade performance of the economy, whereas the Open
variable captures current liberal trade performance. (13) The same
pattern between OpenSW and Open are also observed in subsequent
regressions. As for the [Open.sub.-1] index, which captures past trade
share of GDP, regressions (9), (10), and (11) show that this index
explains generalized trust well.
As to the income inequality variable, Table 3 tests the impact on
generalized trust from various combination of inequality measures,
Income-per-capita Category and GDP-per-capita Growth. Judging from the
consistency of the coefficients and the corresponding t-statistics, the
Gini Coefficient explains Trust very well. Comparing the regressions
(12), (13), and (14) with (1) and (2) in Table 2, one can conclude that
a lot of generalized trust, which was explained by Income-per-capita
Category or GDP-per-capita Growth, can in fact be explained by the Gini
Coefficient. As for the Income-share Ratio, from the consistency of the
coefficients, the t-statistics, and the R-square, comparing regressions
(15), (16), and (17) with (1) and (2), the Income-share Ratio also
appears to explain generalized trust reasonably well. As for the
Ethnolinguistic Fractionalization index, the statistics in regressions
(18), (19), and (20) suggest that the Ethnolinguistic Fractionalization
index does not explain generalized trust as well as the other inequality
indices. This is perhaps not surprising because the ethnolinguistic
fractionalization index represents only a subset of a country's
inequality. (14)
With the exploratory regressions discussed in the previous
paragraph, I can now estimate Equation 7. In Table 4, the impact on
trust from OpenSWand three different inequality indices are presented.
The estimated coefficients of the explanatory variables for a specific
inequality index are by and large consistent with one another. With the
OpenSW and inequality variables in the regression, the Income-per-capita
Category or GDP-per-capita Growth does not seem to play a dominant role
in explaining the generalized trust. With the presence of the
interactive term in Equation 7, the marginal impact of the openness
variable on Trust is: [a.sub.1] + [a.sub.3 x (Inequality). Since the
estimated value of [a.sub.3] is negative and al is positive in all
regressions, evaluating the partial derivative at different values of
the Inequality Index is necessary to gauge its overall impact of
openness. At one standard deviation above (below), the mean is defined
here as a high (low) value of Inequality. This is recorded in the bottom
rows of Table 4 as the marginal impact of Openness at high, mean, or low
(H, M, or L) inequality. Similarly, the marginal impact of Inequality
is: [a.sub.2] + [a.sub.3] x (Openness). Since the estimated values of
[a.sub.2] and [a.sub.3] are negative, evaluating the marginal impact of
Inequality at the Mean of the Openness variable is sufficient. This is
recorded in the bottom row of Table 4.
Several interesting results emerge in Table 4. First and the
foremost, the marginal impact of OpenSW increases with decreasing
inequality, both in terms of magnitude and significance. There is a
threshold level of inequality above (below) which the impact of OpenSW
on trust is significantly positive (can be negative). The threshold
level of inequality is [-a.sub.1]/[a.sub.3]. Second, the marginal impact
of inequality on generalized trust is negative and significant except
when inequality is measured in terms of the Ethnolinguistie
Fractionalization index, where the impact is insignificant but negative.
The next task is to examine regressions based on the Open variable.
The OLS regressions using the Open variable are presented in the
Appendix. From earlier tests presented in Table 2, the trade share (the
Open variable) is only a weak predictor of Trust, because it captures
current liberal trade performance, while generalized trust is built over
time through the accumulation of social capital. Moreover, the Open
variable is an endogenous variable in the system. To overcome the
endogeneity of the Open variable, I use the computed trade shares from
the gravity model, constructed from geographic parameters by Frankel and
Romer (1999), as instrument for the Open variable in two-stage least
squares (2SLS) regressions. The OpenGM variable in Table 5 is computed
from the predicted value of the Open variable regression in the first
stage. The 2SLS regressions are presented in Table 5. From regressions
(J) to (M) in Table 5, the OpenGM variable has no impact on Trust, while
the Inequality variable has maintained a negative significant impact. As
for the regressions (N) and (O), using the Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization index for Inequality, the impact of Inequality on
Trust is insignificant, but the impact of the OpenGM variable
resurfaces: The marginal impact of OpenGM at low Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization is positive and significant. (15) Table 6 reports
regressions using the historical export and import share of GDP (the
[Open.sub.-l] variable). Regression results using the [Open.sub.-1]
index do not support the expected relationship with generalized trust as
well as those using the OpenSW index. But compared with those using the
Open (see the Appendix) and the OpenGM (see Table 5) indices, they are
much more supportive.
Tests for Omitted Variables
As in all empirical works, the possibility of omitted variables
could create biased estimates and spurious relationships. The possible
omitted variables for the present model are those structural variables
that capture cultural, historical, and economic characteristics of
different countries. Since they are difficult to identify, I choose the
following broad set of structural variables, hoping to register some of
these effects: The size of population can capture the size of the
domestic market and polity. The regional dummies (African, East Asian,
and Latin American countries) depict cultural and historical
characteristics. An oil-exporting country dummy catches the most
apparent difference in economic endowment. The democracy variable (taken
from Freedom House) captures a facet of the social and institutional
feature of a country. And finally, religion fractionalization, taken
from Alesina et al. (2002), reflects religious values and beliefs. To
test how these structural variables may bias the estimations, they are
used as regressors, one at a time, to check the consistency of the
estimated coefficients. This is reported in Table 7. From the
regressions in Table 7, the original estimated coefficients in Table 5
look fairly robust. Therefore, the chance of getting a biased result
from omitted variables seems low.
4. Conclusion
Global integration requires nations to make adjustments in some of
their social values and practices or be left behind economically. This
process is deemed to improve or degrade cultural practices, depending on
interests that stand to gain or lose from these practices. This is
similar to free trade where there are winners and losers in spite of an
overall welfare gain. The present paper uses the generalized trust as
criterion to reckon the all-inclusive impact of globalization on
national values. From the present empirical study, openness generally
improves the generalized trust and hence strengthens the informal
institution, the "civic glue" that holds together and governs
the society. Although globalization may eliminate certain dated social
values and may transmit some useful "foreign" values to a
community, its total impact on the community's trust can be
positive. However, there are qualifications. Economic inequality weakens
this positive effect. When globalization worsens domestic income
distribution, it can have a negative impact on a nation's
generalized trust through this channel. There is evidence of a threshold
inequality above which an increase in globalization lowers generalized
trust instead of raising it.
Finally, the two seemingly opposite views, Rodrik and Polanyi on
the one side and Bhagwati and Sen on the other, may not be as
antithetical as they first appear. Drawing from the present findings,
perhaps Rodrik's view is a stern warning to fractional nations that
globalization could lead to social disintegration. Based on a civil and
homogenous society, Bhagwati and Sen, on the other hand, are arguing
that the transmission of foreign values from globalization benefits
national values.
I am indebted to two anonymous referees, Will Coleman, Tom
Crossley, Lonnie Magee, and seminar participants at the City University
of Hong Kong and at the National University of Singapore, for comments
on earlier drafts. The usual disclaimers apply.
Appendix
Dependent Variable: Generalized Trust--OLS Estimation
(V1) (V2) (V3)
Open -0.35 0.00 0.04
(0.81) (0.00) (0.18)
Gini Coefficient -1.13 *** -1.05 ***
(4.25) (3.17)
Open x Gini Coefficient 0.01 0.00
(1.21) (0.31)
Income-Share Ratio -1.60 ***
(3.922)
Open x Income-Share Ratio 0.01
(0.61)
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization
Open x Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization
Income-per- Capita Category 4.67 ** 6.08 ***
(2.42) (3.31)
GDP-per-Capita Growth 0.32
(0.66)
R-square 0.57 0.50 0.52
Marginal impact of Open at 0.30 0.18 0.22
H-inequality (2.67) (0.84) (1.52)
Marginal impact of Open at 0.15 0.14 0.15
M-inequality (1.40) (0.08) (1.26)
Marginal impact of Open at 0.01 0.10 0.08
L-inequality (0.00) (0.25) (0.19)
Marginal impact of inequality -0.75 *** -0.94 *** -1.22 ***
at mean Open (17.68) (24.01) (10.10)
(V4) (V5) (V6)
Open -0.31 0.27 0.37
(1.14) (1.26) (1.47)
Gini Coefficient
Open x Gini Coefficient
Income-Share Ratio -1.00 *
(1.97)
Open x Income-Share Ratio -0.03
(0.99)
Ethnolinguistic -8.42 -14.57
Fractionalization (0.49) (0.80)
Open x Ethnolinguistic -0.01 -0.27
Fractionalization (0.19) (0.51)
Income-per- Capita Category 6.29 **
(2.38)
GDP-per-Capita Growth 0.65 0.47
(1.32) (0.88)
R-square 0.41 0.37 0.26
Marginal impact of Open at -0.04 0.21 0.21
H-inequality (0.03) (1.01) (1.35)
Marginal impact of Open at 0.10 0.24 * 0.28 *
M-inequality (0.04) (2.92) (3.37)
Marginal impact of Open at 0.24 0.27 0.30
L-inequality (1.22) (2.01) (2.48)
Marginal impact of inequality -1.72 *** -11.40 -22.19 **
at mean Open (13.98) (1.34) (5.22)
The values in parentheses for the marginal impacts are F-statistics;
H-, M-, or L- indicates that the marginal impact is evaluated at the
high (one standard deviation above the mean) level of inequality,
at the mean, or at the low (one standard deviation below) level of
inequality, respectively. See footnote to Table 2
Received November 2004; accepted April 2006.
References
Alesina, A., A. Devleeschauwer, W. Easterly, S. Kurlat, and R.
Wacziarg. 2002. Fractionalization. NBER Working Paper No. 9411.
Beugelsdijk, S., H. L. F. de Groot, and A. B. T. M. van Schaik.
2004. Trust and economic growth: A robust analysis. Oxford Economic
Papers 56:118-34.
Bhagwati, J. 2001. IMF Seminar. IMF Survey, April 2, 2001.
Bhagwati, J. 2004. In defense of globalization. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Burt, R. S. 2001. Structural holes versus network closure as social
capital. In Social capital: Theory and research, edited by N. Lin, K.
Cook, and R. S. Burt. New York: Aldine De Gruyter.
Camerer, Colin F. 2003. Behavioral game theory: Experiments in
strategic interaction. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Chenery, H. B., and L. Taylor. 1968. Development patterns: Among
countries and over time. Review of Economics and Statistics 41:391-416.
Coleman, J. S. 1988. Social capital in the creation of human
capital. American Journal of Sociology (Supplement) 94:95-120.
Dasgupta, P. 2000. Introduction. In Social capital: A multifaceted perspective, edited by P. Dasgupta and I. Serageldin. Washington DC: The
World Bank, pp. 3-5.
De Grauwe, P., and M. Polan. 2005. Globalization and social
spending. Pacific Economic Review 10:105-23.
Frankel, J. A., and D. Romer. 1999. Does trade cause growth?
American Economic Review 89:379-99.
Freedom House Publisher. Annual Survey of Freedom Country Scores;
various issues.
Fukuyama, F. 1995. Trust: Social virtues and the creation of
prosperity. New York: New York Free Press.
Inglehart, R. 1994. Codebook for world values surveys. Ann Arbor,
MI: Institute for Social Research.
Jackson, M. O., and A. Wolinsky. 1996. A strategic model of social
and economic networks. Journal of Economic Theory 71:44-74.
Knack, S., and P. Keefer. 1997. Does social capital have an
economic payoff? A cross-country investigation. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 112:1252-88.
La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. W. Vishny.
1997. Trust in large organization. American Economic Review, Papers and
Proceedings 87:333-8.
Lawrence, R. Z. 1991. Efficient or exclusionist? The import
behavior of Japanese corporate groups. Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 11:311-31.
Lin, Nan. 2001. Social capital: A theory of social structure and
action. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Olson, M. 1982. The rise and fall of nations: Economic growth,
stagflation and social rigidities. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.
Paldam, M. 2000. Social capital: One or many? Definition and
measurement. Journal of Economic Surveys 14:629-53.
Polanyi, Karl. 1944. The great transformation: The political and
economic origins of our time. Boston: Beacon Press.
Putnam, R. D. 1993. Making democracy work: Civic traditions in
modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Rodrik, D. 1997. Has globalization gone too far? Washington DC:
Institute for International Economics.
Sachs, J., and A. Warner. 1995. Economic reform and the process of
global integration. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:1-118.
Schiff, M. 1998. Ethnic diversity and economic reform in sub-Sahara
Africa. Journal of African Economies 7:348-62.
Schiff, M. 2002. Love thy neighbor: Trade, migration and social
capital. European Journal of Political Economy 18:87-107.
Sen, A. 1999. Development as freedom. New York: Anchor Books,
Random House.
Solow, R. M. 2000. Notes on social capital and economic
performance. In Social capital: A multifaceted perspective, edited by P.
Dasgupta and I. Serageldin. Washington DC: The World Bank, pp. 6-10.
Stiglitz, J. E. 2000. Formal and informal institutions. In Social
capital: A multifaceted perspective, edited by P. Dasgupta and I.
Serageldin. Washington DC: The World Bank, pp. 59-68.
World Development Indicators, World Bank, various issues.
Zak, P. J., and S. Knack. 2001. Trust and growth. Economic Journal
111:295-321.
(1) There are numerous difficulties with the traditional utility
analysis on national social values. General speaking, social values
should be an integral part of the utility function, often assumed to be
completely autonomous. There is no room for change in social values
within this framework. It is, therefore, difficult to trace how social
values can be transmitted to or uprooted in a country. Moreover,
traditional utility analysis is based on individual rationality while
social values are based on collective rationality.
Coleman (1988, p. 17), proponent of this social capital framework,
argues, "In this paper, I have attempted to introduce into social
theory a concept, 'social capital,' paralleling the concepts
of financial capital, physical capital, and human capital--but embodied in relations among persons. This is part of a theoretical strategy that
involves use of the paradigm of rational action but without the
assumption of atomistic elements stripped of social relationships."
(2) Skeptics question what should be counted as social capital and
how social capital should be measured, let alone the scantiness of
available data (see Solow in Dasgupta and Serageldin 2000). Proponents
of social capital rebut the argument by saying that because social
capital makes the economy more productive, it can be measured from its
output; by adding market value to existing physical assets, the
contribution (value) of social capital can be reckoned (see Stiglitz
2000, p. 60).
(3) For convenience, I will use the terms, trust and generalized
trust, interchangeably in the paper. Generalized trust is the
conventional term and is used in the World Value Surveys.
(4) In an interesting case study by Schiff (1998) on the ethnically
divided sub-Saharan African societies, strong supportive evidence is
provided for Rodrik's argument. Economic and trade reforms in these
countries increase ethnic inequality and tension among ethnic groups.
Since they have a negative impact on interethnic cooperation and
political stability, more resources must be spent on security.
Consequently, trade reforms can be welfare reducing.
(5) For example, Sen's argument may need qualification in the
presence of network externalities. Take language as one element of
culture. Indigenous language, even if it was deemed more useful, may
have to give way to new foreign languages that may be less useful, but
has enjoyed a large global network of users. I am indebted to a referee for pointing this out.
(6) To assure the network is stable, Jackson and Wolinsky argue
that "one is forced to allocate resources to nodes that are not
responsible for any of the production. We characterize one such
allocation rule: the equal split rule, and another rule that arises
naturally from bargaining of the players." (p. 44, 1996).
(7) The keiretsu in Japan provide an interesting illustrative example. Keiretsu is a form of social capital embedded in economic
networks that overlap and pretty much span the entire Japanese economy.
Critics argue that the keiretsu may have used anticompetitive business
practices in reducing foreign imports and direct investments. Supporters
rebut that the keiretsu only lowers the cost of doing business (see
Lawrence 1991).
That fragmented social capital can be socially detrimental means
that the concept of social capital currently used is not just a circular
definition for successful economies because it can predict different
outcomes.
(8) Note that Jackson and Wolinsky's concept of social network
breakup is closely akin to Rodrik's concept of social
disintegration.
(9) Can the home country adopt "unproductive" foreign
values? Under our framework that social capital aids productive
activities, this cannot happen. Adopting unproductive foreign social
capital is unlikely because it would not survive competition with the
productive domestic values. Perhaps without the intense global
competitive pressure, the chance of adopting "unproductive"
foreign social values could be higher than otherwise.
(10) Some countries are in one but not both of the surveys. Also,
in the third survey, some countries complete the survey in 1997-1998
instead of 1995. To adjust for this, I match the data of the other
regressors to the Survey dates.
(11) In the literature, in Chenery and Taylor (1968),
log-GDP-per-capita and log-population are often used to capture the
stages of social and economic development of nations. Some authors (see
Schiff 2002) use the growth rate of GDP per capita as a proxy for
institutional effectiveness.
(12) I have constructed the rank version of GDP-per-capita growth,
where the growth rates are classified by their positions within one
standard deviation. Growth rate that is below (above) one standard
deviation takes a rank of 0 (3), and that between the sample mean and
one standard deviation below (above) the mean takes the rank of 1 (2).
The differences in the regression results between using the rank version
and the value version of GDP-per-capita growth are marginal. The former
gives a slightly higher t-statistic than the latter in most regressions.
(13) Without doubt, the crude qualitative dummy variable used in
the construction of the Sachs Warner index reduces the precision of
measurement and ultimately weakens the inference using this index. But
on the positive side, the imprecision in the Sachs-Warner index also
decreases the correlation between this index and the other regressors.
The present data set has multicollinearity. Hence, there is a trade-off
here. Although better indices increase the statistical significance of
the estimation and improve inference, they may also increase
multicollinearity, which reduces it.
Perhaps the Sachs Warner index can be viewed as a bottom line case.
But, even without good precision regression results using the Sachs
Warner index are reasonable, as shown in Table 2, and later in Table 4.
This only lends credibility to the present results.
(14) Note that the ethnolinguistic fractionalization index captures
the racial, linguistic, and cultural profile in a country. This index
remains unchanged even when a country's racial and cultural tension
has gone up from globalization. For this reason, it might not have
captured fully the rise and fall of racial conflicts in a country. But
on the positive side, this index has little correlation with other
regressors. The multicollinearity problem could be less severe [see
footnote 15 and the two standard least squares (SLS) regressions in
Table 5].
(15) A plausible explanation for the weak t-statistics in the 2SLS
regressions in Table 5 is the presence of multicollinearity in the data.
Since the racial, linguistic, and cultural profile in a country are
exogenous, the Ethnolinguistic Fractionalization index is unaffected by
trade. Therefore, the correlation between OpenGM and Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization index is lower than the correlations between OpenGM
and other measures of inequality. The low correlation could explain why
the estimated marginal impact of openness, in regressions (N) and (O)
are statistically more significant than those from regressions (J) to
(M) in Table 5.
Kenneth S. Chan, Department of Economics and Finance, City
University of Hong Kong, 83 Tat Chee Avenue, Kowloon, Hong Kong; and the
Department of Economics, McMaster University, Hamilton, Ontario, Canada;
E-mail kschan@cityu. edu.hk.
Table 1. Summary Statistics
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation Minimum Maximum
Generalized Trust 31.7546 16.03 4.11 65.21
OpenSW 22.45 15.60 0 45
Open 28.71 13.79 8.02 67.24
[Open.sub.-1] 48.50 25.45 12.63 119.53
Gini Coefficient 37.58 10.72 23.1 59.3
Income-share ratio 8.12 5.43 3.2 24.23
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization 0.32 0.25 0.002 0.85
GDP per-capita Growth 2.32 4.27 -14.8 9.06
Income-per-capita Category 2.15 1.07 0 3
The data on Trust are taken from WVS (1990-1995). OpenSW is
the years of liberal trade policy taken from Sachs
and Warner (1995). Open ([Open.sub.-1],) is the contemporaneous
(past average, 1970-1989) export and import share of GDP.
The Income-per-capita Category (0, 1, 2, 3) represents the low,
lower middle, upper middle, and high income per capita
category, respectively. Income-share ratio equals the income
share of the highest 20% of population over the income
share of the lowest 20%. Ethnolinguistic Fractionalization
(from 0 to 1, where 1 is the most fractional society) is taken
from Alesina et al. (2002). The rest of the data are taken from
World Development Indicator, World Bank (various
years, at PPP).
Table 2. Dependent Variable: Generalized Trust
(1) (2) (3) (4)
OpenSW 0.69 *** 0.71 ***
(5.77) (3.33)
Open
[Open.sub.-1]
GDP-per-capita 1.17 ***
Growth (2.99)
Income-per-capita 8.38 *** -0.37
Category (4.01) (0.10)
R-square 0.1 0.1 0.31 0.44 0.44
(5) (6) (7) (8)
OpenSW 0.64 ***
(2.04)
Open 0.38 ** 0.24 0.29
(2.23) (1.56) (1.57)
[Open.sub.-1]
GDP-per-capita 0.703 0.83 *
Growth (1.34) (1.75)
Income-per-capita 7.65 ***
Category (3.67)
R-square 0.1 0.47 0.11 0.35 0.15
(9) (10) (11)
OpenSW
Open
[Open.sub.-1] 0.31 *** 0.18 ** 0.27 ***
(3.32) (2.09) (2.74)
GDP-per-capita 0.72
Growth (1.49)
Income-per-capita 6.36 ***
Category (3.00)
R-square 0.1 0.24 0.38 0.27
The t-statistics are in parentheses. Regressions are OLS estimation
and are adjusted for heteroscedasticity. Sample size is 38. Values
in parentheses are t-statistics. *, **. and *** are the 10, 5, and
1% level of significance. respectively. The subscript -1 indicates
that the data for the [Open.sub.-1] variable is the average of
export and import share of GDP from 1970 to 1989.
Table 3. Dependent Variable: Generalized Trust
(12) (13) (14) (15)
Gini Coefficient -1.03 *** -0.83 *** -0.97 ***
(6.04) (4.96) (5.14)
Income-share
Ratio -1.76 ***
(5.50)
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization
GDP-per-capita
Growth 0.50
(1.21)
Income-per-capita
Category 4.50 **
(2.45)
R-square 0.47 0.54 0.49 0.35
(16) (17) (18)
Gini Coefficient
Income-share
Ratio -1.40 *** -1.62 ***
(5.16) (4.77)
Ethnolinguistic -26.5 ***
Fractionalization (2.84)
GDP-per-capita
Growth 0.75 *
(1.70)
Income-per-capita
Category 6.12 ***
(3.45)
R-square 0.5 0.39 0.17
(19) (20)
Gini Coefficient
Income-share
Ratio
Ethnolinguistic -11.44 -22.78 **
Fractionalization (1.25) (2.24)
GDP-per-capita
Growth 0.76 *
(1.71)
Income-per-capita
Category 7.02 ***
(3.01)
R-square 0.33 0.21
OILS estimation. See Notes
Table 4. Dependent Variable: Generalized Trust, OLS Estimation
(A) (B) (C)
OpenSW 1.26 ** 1.20 * 1.22 **
(2.142) (1.839) (2.12)
Gini Coefficient -0.25 -0.28 -0.22
(0.90) -0.92 (0.80)
OpenSW x Gini Coefficient -0.02 -0.02 -0.02
(1.50) -1.44 (1.51)
Income-Share Ratio
OpenSW x Income-Share Ratio
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization
OpenSW x Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization 0.42
Income-per-capita Category
-0.134
GDP-per-capita Growth 0.43
(1.01)
R-square 0.57 0.57 0.59
Marginal Impact of 0.10 0.09 0.11
OpenSW at H-Inequality (0.19) -0.09 (0.23)
Marginal Impact of 0.36 ** 0.03 0.344 **
OpenSW at M-Inequality (6.91) -1.96 (7.21)
Marginal Impact of 0.62 *** 0.58 * 0.60 ***
OpenSW at L-Inequality (9.79) -3.83 (9.21)
Marginal Impact of -0.79 *** -0.79 *** -0.74 ***
Inequality at Mean (10.12) -9.69 (9.04)
OpenSW
(D) (E) (F)
OpenSW 0.91 *** 0.81 ** 0.87 ***
(3.24) (2.34) (3.15)
Gini Coefficient
OpenSW x Gini Coefficient
Income-Share Ratio -0.32 -0.41 -0.29
(0.71) (0.87) (0.67)
OpenSW x Income-Share Ratio -0.07 * -0.06 * -0.06 *
(1.73) (1.69) (1.82)
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization
OpenSW x Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization 1.10
Income-per-capita Category (0.34)
GDP-per-capita Growth 0.51
(1.09)
R-square 0.55 0.55 0.57
Marginal Impact of 0.01 -0.04 0.02
OpenSW at H-Inequality (0.00) (0.01) (0.00)
Marginal Impact of 0.37 ** 0.31 0.36 ***
OpenSW at M-Inequality (6.92) (1.46) (7.66)
Marginal Impact of 0.73 *** 0.64 ** 0.70 ***
OpenSW at L-Inequality (14.11) (5.09) (12.54)
Marginal Impact of -1.81 *** -1.81 *** -1.69 ***
Inequality at Mean (7.53) (7.40) (8.27)
OpenSW
(G) (H) (I)
OpenSW 0.84 *** 0.94 *** 0.80 ***
(3.53) (3.51) (3.07)
Gini Coefficient
OpenSW x Gini Coefficient
Income-Share Ratio
OpenSW x Income-Share Ratio
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization 2.42 1.27 3.71
(0.27) (0.14) (0.44)
-0.56 -0.57 (0.49)
OpenSW x Ethnolinguistic (1.14) (1.17) (0.98)
Fractionalization -1.81
Income-per-capita Category (0.54)
GDP-per-capita Growth 0.55
(1.00)
R-square 0.48 0.48 0.5
Marginal Impact of 0.52 *** 0.62 *** 0.52 ***
OpenSW at H-Inequality (11.43) (6.96) (12.97)
Marginal Impact of 0.66 *** 0.76 *** 0.64 ***
OpenSW at M-Inequality (22.99) (13.37) (19.53)
Marginal Impact of 0.80 *** 0.90 *** 0.77 ***
OpenSW at L-Inequality (14.51) (13.22) (11.01)
Marginal Impact of -10.15 -11.52 -7.38
Inequality at Mean (1.43) (1.70) (0.79)
OpenSW
The value in parentheses for the marginal impacts are F-statistics;
H-, M-, or L- indicate that the marginal impact was evaluated at a
high level of inequality (one standard deviation above the mean
level of inequality), at the mean, or at a low (one standard
deviation below) level of inequality, respectively.
See footnote to Table 2.
Table 5. Dependent Variable: Generalized Trust--2SLS Estimation
(J) (K) (L)
OpenGM -0.46 -0.02 0.07
(0.64) (0.03) (0.16)
Gini Coefficient -1.18 -1.01
(2.38) ** (1.82) *
OpenGM x Gini Coefficient 0.02 0.00
(0.72) (0.16)
Income-Share Ratio -1.42
(1.16)
OpenGM x Income-Share 0.00
Ratio (0.07)
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization
OpenGM X Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization
Income-Per-Capita Category 4.67 5.91
(2.39) ** (3.11) ***
GDP per-capita Growth 0.47
-1.12
R-Square 0.55 0.49 0.50
Marginal impact of 0.29 0.16 0.12
OpenGM at H-inequality (0.53) (0.15) (0.06)
Marginal impact of 0.13 0.12 0.10
OpenGM at M-inequality (0.32) (0.23) (0.19)
Marginal impact of -0.04 0.08 0.08
OpenGM at L-inequality (0.04) (0.09) (0.08)
Marginal impact of -0.73 -0.91 -1.3
inequality at mean (9.08) *** (13.64) *** (3.83) *
OpenGM
(M) (N) (O)
OpenGM 0.52 0.74 0.99
(1.09) (2.33) ** (2.63) **
Gini Coefficient
OpenGM x Gini Coefficient
Income-Share Ratio -0.2
(0.15)
OpenGM x Income-Share -0.06
Ratio (0.92)
Ethnolinguistic 21.50 24.36
Fractionalization (0.97) (0.91)
OpenGM X Ethnolinguistic -1.16 -1.15
Fractionalization (1.76) * (1.86) *
Income-Per-Capita Category 5.67
(2.25) **
GDP per-capita Growth 0.70 0.80
-1.64 (1.96) *
R-Square 0.42 0.41 0.35
Marginal impact of -0.29 0.08 0.133
OpenGM at H-inequality (0.30) (0.16) (0.41)
Marginal impact of 0.04 0.37 0.51
OpenGM at M-inequality (0.02) (4.41) ** (7.52) ***
Marginal impact of 0.36 0.66 0.88
OpenGM at L-inequality (1.15) (5.59)** (7.33) **
Marginal impact of -1.91 -11.83 -18.65
inequality at mean (7.06) ** -1.72 (4.29) **
OpenGM
OpenGM is the estimated (predicted) value of Open from regressing
the actual trade share on the constructed trade share from geographic
parameters, the gravity model (from Frankel and Romer). The values in
parentheses for the marginal impacts are F-statistics; H-M-, or
L-indicates that the marginal impact is evaluated at the high (one
standard deviation above the mean) level of inequality, at the mean,
or at the low (one standard deviation below) level of inequality
respectively. See footnote to Table 2.
Table 6. Dependent Variable: Generalized Trust--OLS Estimation
(P) (Q) (R)
[Open.sub.-1] -0.11 -0.3 0.07
(0.36) (0.10) (0.56)
Gini Coefficient -1.02 *** -1.06 ***
(2.90) (2.69)
[Open.sub.-1] x Gini 0.01 0.01
Coefficient (0.73) (0.53)
Income-Share Ratio -1.50 ***
(3.17)
[Open.sub.-1] x Income-Share 0.01
Ratio (0.46)
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization
[Open.sub.-1] x Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization
Income-per- Capita Category 3.85 * 5.19 ***
(1.98) (2.80)
GDP-per-Capita Growth 0.32
(0.64)
R-square 0.56 0.52 0.53
Marginal impact of 0.18 0.20 0.16
[Open.sub.-1] at H-inequality (1.27) (1.81) (2.10)
Marginal impact of 1.11 0.15 0.12
[Open.sub.-1] at M-inequality (1.84) (2.58) (2.45)
Marginal impact of 0.05 0.10 0.09
[Open.sub.-1] at L-inequality (0.26) (0.72) (0.73)
Marginal impact of inequality -0.74 *** -0.84 *** -1.21 ***
at mean [Open.sub.-1] (17.03) (19.72) (12.56)
(S) (T) (U)
[Open.sub.-1] 0.19 0.32 *** 0.37 ***
(1.20) (2.91) (3.03)
Gini Coefficient
[Open.sub.-1] x Gini
Coefficient
Income-Share Ratio -1.30 **
(2.33)
[Open.sub.-1] x Income-Share -0.002
Ratio (0.15)
Ethnolinguistic 11.52 0.80
Fractionalization (0.64) (0.05)
[Open.sub.-1] x Ethnolinguistic -0.47 * -0.4
Fractionalization (1.65) (1.35)
Income-per- Capita Category 5.40 *
(1.97)
GDP-per-Capita Growth 0.512 0.48
(1.00) (1.00)
R-square 0.45 0.42 0.36
Marginal impact of 0.15 0.06 0.14
[Open.sub.-1] at H-inequality (1.29) (0.31) (1.91)
Marginal impact of 0.17* 0.17** 0.24 ***
[Open.sub.-1] at M-inequality (3.31) (6.26) (10.98)
Marginal impact of 0.18 0.29 *** 0.34 ***
[Open.sub.-1] at L-inequality (2.17) (9.12) (10.34)
Marginal impact of inequality -1.41 *** -11.14 -18.48 **
at mean [Open.sub.-1] (11.29) (1.22) -4.17
[Open.sub.-1] is the average exports and imports share of GDP from
1970 to 1989. The values in parentheses for the marginal impacts are
F-statistics; H-, M-, or L-indicates that the marginal impact is
evaluated at the high (one standard deviation above the mean) level
of inequality, at the mean, or at the low (one standard deviation
below) level of inequality, respectively. See footnote to Table 2.
Table 7. Testing for Omitted Variables. Dependent Variable:
Generalized Trust-OLS Estimation
OpenSW 1.25 ** 1.23 ** 1.14 ** 1.08 *
(2.06) (2.07) (2.02) (1.81)
Gini Coefficient -0.29 -0.31 -0.29 -0.24
(0.84) (1.09) (1.07) (0.85)
OpenSW x Gini -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02
Coefficient (1.38) (1.42) (0.60) (1.47)
Income-Share Ratio
OpenSW x Income-
Share Ratio
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization
OpenSW x
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization
Regional dummies YES
Oil exporting 4.93
country dummy (0.89)
Log-population -1.02
(0.60)
Democracy -2.56
(1.24)
Religious
fractionalization
R-square 0.60 0.58 0.58 0.59
OpenSW 1.20 ** 0.90 *** 0.93 *** 0.84 ***
(2.04) (2.94) (3.16) (3.31)
Gini Coefficient -0.31
(1.09)
OpenSW x Gini -0.24
Coefficient (1.50)
Income-Share Ratio -0.35 -0.34 -0.36
(0.72) (0.76) (0.83)
OpenSW x Income- -0.07 -0.07 -0.06
Share Ratio (1.63) (1.69) (1.64)
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization
OpenSW x
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization
Regional dummies YES
Oil exporting 4.14
country dummy (0.80)
Log-population -1.16
(0.68)
Democracy
Religious 7.17
fractionalization (1.02)
R-square 0.58 0.57 0.55 0.56
OpenSW 0.71 ** 0.97 *** 0.64 ** 0.84 ***
(2.44) (2.98) (2.34) (3.48)
Gini Coefficient
OpenSW x Gini
Coefficient
Income-Share Ratio -0.31 -0.41
(0.68) (0.96)
OpenSW x Income- -0.07 -0.07
Share Ratio (1.76) (1.71)
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization -3.67 1.28
OpenSW x (0.44) (0.13)
Ethnolinguistic -0.35 -0.53
Fractionalization (0.72) (1.06)
Regional dummies YES
Oil exporting 1.65
country dummy (0.25)
Log-population
Democracy -2.96
(1.35)
Religious 7.03
fractionalization (0.94)
R-square 0.57 0.56 0.52 0.48
OpenSW 0.81 *** 0.74 *** 0.80 ***
(3.60) (2.74) (2.79)
Gini Coefficient
OpenSW x Gini
Coefficient
Income-Share Ratio
OpenSW x Income-
Share Ratio
Ethnolinguistic
Fractionalization 3.37 18.15 -0.33
OpenSW x (0.33) (1.18) (0.03)
Ethnolinguistic -0.55 -0.9 -0.51
Fractionalization (1.10) (1.54) (0.95)
Regional dummies
Oil exporting
country dummy
Log-population -1.38
(0.71)
Democracy -4.55
(1.47)
Religious 4.44
fractionalization (0.51)
R-square 0.49 0.50 0.48
See footnote to Table 2.